A Reality Check on the Labour Market Flexibility Argument in India

Similar documents
Trade Liberalisation and Its Impact on Employment: An Analysis of Indian Experiences (With Special References of Indian Manufacturing Industries)

Labour Regulation in India: Emerging Perspective for Reforms

NATURE AND STRUCTURE OF UNREGISTERED FOOD PROCESSING INDUSTRY IN INDIA

CWP Policy and Procedure Manual

Business Cycle Facts

Advancing Gender Equality in the European Research Area

Business Cycle Facts

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA: AGGREGATE TRENDS AND SECTORAL PATTERNS

FICCI QUARTERLY SURVEY ON INDIAN MANUFACTURING SECTOR

Employer/employee Relations Trade Unions and ACAS

Wages and working hours Guidance note

What might be gained from a more rigorous approach to comparison? There are three common answers to this:

Structural Change in Indian Economy: Changing Composition of Growth

TUAC Comments on the OECD Employment Outlook Making the case for coordinated and multi-employer collective bargaining systems

UNIT 7. Chapter 15 EMPLOYMENT : GROWTH INFORMALISATION AND OTHER ISSUES

Workplace Relations Current Issues and Future Directions. Stephen Smith Head of National Workplace Relations Policy, Ai Group

Downloads from this web forum are for private, non-commercial use only. Consult the copyright and media usage guidelines on

Industrial Relations in Public Sector Learning Objectives The purpose of forming state enterprises in developing countries and in India.

Sales and Operations Planning

The Future of Work in India and Beyond

Editorial Reassessing the OECD Jobs Strategy

Chapter 16: Employment growth, Information and Other issues

Ethics in Human Resource Management

Discussion of Lorenzo Codogno Two Italian Puzzles: Are Productivity Growth and Competitiveness Really so Depressed? by Tito Boeri

As used in this Fair Wage Policy, the following terms have the meaning indicated:

-The Next Leap - From Labour Market Programmes to Active Labour Market Policy SUMMARY REPORT. On behalf of UĦM

Mr. Nigel Dudley Equilibrium Research 47 The Quays Cumberland Road Spike Island Bristol BS1 6UQ UK

There is unanimity amongst scholars that the organised

TORONTO MUNICIPAL CODE CHAPTER 67, FAIR WAGE SCHEDULE A, FAIR WAGE POLICY SCHEDULE A FAIR WAGE POLICY

Meeting of the Employment and Social Affairs Committee at the Ministerial Level. Building More Resilient and Inclusive Labour Markets 15 January, 2016

Introduction 2. Large landholdings in Latin America.

Collective agreements

The EU and the Swedish collective agreement model

Nasdaq Talks to Don Kalfen of Meridian Compensation Partners about Preparing for CEO Pay Ratio Disclosure

Progress and Potential of Horticulture in India

Appendix W.2 Macromonitor Report Forecast of Labour Costs Electricity, Gas, Water And Waste Services Sector September 2011

Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality

EMPLOYEE PARTICIPATION IN THE USA: A LEGAL AND MANAGERIAL CONSIDERATION

DOWNLOAD PDF JOB SEARCH IN A DYNAMIC ECONOMY

Do Skilled Workers Have Decent Jobs?

Policy Note August 2015

The growing informalisation of work: Challenges for labour recent developments to improve the rights of atypical workers

The purpose of the research: the implementation of legislative principles

Governing Body 320th Session, Geneva, March 2014

Tenth Meeting of European Labour Court Judges Stockholm, September 2, The Role of Collective Bargaining. Questionnaire

Growth and Instability in Foodgrains Production in West Bengal

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. What is carbon leakage?

Weekly Closure of Shops and Establishments Under Shops and Establishment Act

Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity?

How much goes to the cause?

PRODUCTIVE AND FAIR WORKPLACE RELATIONS

Growth and Productivity Analysis of Chemical Industry in Tamilnadu

Women and Men Operators of Enterprises in India s Informal Sector

S. Rajendran* and B Gandhimathy**

M.H.R.M. (Previous) DEGREE EXAMINATION, MAY First Year MASTER OF HUMAN RESOURCE MANAGEMENT Paper - I : Perspectives of Management

THE LEGISLATIVE FRAMEWORK, UNIONS - AND COLLECTIVE BARGAINING RIGHTS RESOLUTION ACTU CONGRESS 1997

Three major points that must be kept in mind when dealing with the Working Time Regulations are :

The Code of Excellence Program Developed for Local Union 82, IBEW and the Dayton Division of the Western Ohio Chapter of NECA.

Policy Competition for Foreign Direct Investment A Study of Competition among Governments to Attract FDI

Trade and Inequality. Clausen Conference on Global Economic Issues 2017 Bob Koopman Chief Economist, World Trade Organization

Lecture 11: Real Business Cycles

Employment, Equity and Human Development

The Gender Pay Gap In International Perspective

TIME TO BACK BUSINESS: WA GOVERNMENT S PRESCRIPTION FOR INDUSTRY-LED SKILLS DEVELOPMENT FALLS SHORT

HANDLING PARITY LEGISLATION IN EUROPE

Public Management and Administration

UK RESPONSE TO COMMISSION S KEY ISSUES PAPER ON SOCIAL PROTECTION AND EMPLOYMENT

UNEMPLOYMENT ISSUES IN INDIA

Frédéric Lapeyre Head, Informal Economy Unit Employment Policy Department International Labour Organization

PROPOSAL FOR A DIRECTIVE ON WORKING CONDITIONS FOR TEMPORARY WORKERS (COM (2002) 149 FINAL)

29 March Gender pay gap report (2017 snapshot)

V. Employment and Industrial Relations

In times of uncertainty, where can governments find opportunity?

Co-operative Farming

Registered Redundancy Policy

A Angelakis and N Paranychianakis Institute of Iraklio, National Foundation for Agricultural Research, Iraklio, Greece

Better working conditions for an inclusive growth

Like in many other countries of continental Europe, in Portugal

Business. Management 113. Complete

Regulated Flexibility: Revisiting the LRA and the BCEA

The Concept Note recognises the following initiatives referred to in the SONA as having an impact on job creation and therefore the job summit

Temporary Help Agencies & Legislative Changes

REPUBLIC OF SOUTH AFRICA LABOUR COURT OF SOUTH AFRICA, JOHANNESBURG JUDGEMENT

UNI Europa ICTS position on the European Single Market for electronic communications

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

WAGES AND EMPLOYMENT IN THE INDIAN INDUSTRIAL SECTOR: THEORY AND EVIDENCE

Proposed Framework of Interpretation and Considerations concerning ICANN s Human Rights Bylaw

ABSENCE MANAGEMENT POLICY

Collective Agreement For posted employees. Road Transport and Mechanics

ESSDE Outcome Joint Declaration EFEE/ETUCE on Supporting early career researchers in Higher Education in Europe

Paaritosh Nath* Keywords: Employment growth, Reforms, Labour market, Flexibility, Organised manufacturing

Visa Issues Require New Approach to Transition Plans

The Agricultural Outlook is a collaborative effort of OECD and FAO. It brings

References Other CLC policies relating to this policy. Legislation relating to this policy

TeamLease Services Limited Investor presentation August Putting India to work

Has the Cabinet Manual 2011 begun the process of codifying the UK constitution?

BURBERRY ETHICAL TRADING CODE OF CONDUCT

Introduction. Methodology

Country Paper: Coherent Approach to Trade and Regulation of Services: Lessons from India

A desk audit into the data and research on micro-business profiling in Australia Released July 2010

Transcription:

A Reality Check on the Labour Market Flexibility Argument in India Anamitra Roychowdhury The standard arguments for undertaking labour market flexibility (LMF) in India are well known. With the exception of few misleading media reports, that attribute the aggregate employment slowdown in India (the phenomenon of jobless growth ) to the so called labour market rigidities, it is generally accepted even by the most ardent advocate of LMF that the labour laws could not possibly be the primary reason behind the recent employment debacle. This is simple to understand. Since the vast majority of our workforce (92 per cent) is employed in the unorganised sector, mostly falling outside the ambit of labour laws, it is difficult to argue that the prime reason for aggregate employment stagnation is due to the labour laws. Nonetheless, commentators are quick to point out that the labour laws act as a barrier to quality employment generation in the organised sector. Their basic argument is aptly summarized below: Labour market rigidities constrain growth in employment... In absence of flexible labour markets in the organised sector (less than 8 per cent of the labour force), growth in output does not necessarily lead to an increase in employment, because labour effectively becomes a fixed input. Hence, production becomes artificially capital intensive. In an attempt to protect existing jobs, future and potential jobs are lost. Thus, the system is not in the broader interests of labour either. In addition, labour legislation creates relatively high wage islands in the organised sector and India s comparative advantage in an abundant supply of labour cannot be tapped Conversely, the unorganized sector (92 per cent of the labour force) has virtually no protection (Debroy, 2005). From the foregoing discussion it is clear that labour laws are identified to be the major reason for the slow growth in employment in the organised sector. It is further contemplated that the labour laws contribute to form a dual labour market, producing a minute constituency of labour aristocracy at one end with a vast majority of working paupers at the other. Therefore, to generate quality employment and remove the distinction between formal and informal workers, it is argued that India must introduce LMF. In what follows we shall examine the validity of these claims. Labour laws and the slow growth in organised employment Now the piece of legislation that has drawn maximum attention in the labour flexibility argument is Chapter VB of the Industrial Disputes Act, 1947 (IDA). It stipulates that, if an undertaking (engaged in manufacturing, mine and plantation activity) employing 100 or more permanent workers wants to fire even one permanent worker, then it has to obtain prior permission from the government. This, it is argued, creates unnecessary deterrence in quickly responding to the fluctuations faced in the product market and makes the firm uncompetitive, thus hindering its capacity to generate employment. This sentiment is clearly reflected in the following: In face of

adverse shocks employers have to reduce the workers strength; but they are not able to do so owing to the existence of stringent job security provisions. On the other hand, when the going is good and the economic circumstances are favourable, the firms may want to hire new workers. But they would hire only when they would be able to dispense with workers as and when they need to. Thus, separation benefits accruing to workers become potential hiring costs for the employers. This affects the ability and the willingness of firms to create jobs (Sundar, 2005) Immediately the question arises, is it correct to ascribe the failure of the organised sector as a whole, in generating formal jobs, primarily to the rigid labour laws? A close reading of the domain of application of Chapter VB (IDA, 1947) reveals that it applies to only manufacturing units, mines and plantations and not to firms providing services or, related to agricultural activity. However, firms employing 10 or more workers qualify for the organised sector irrespective of their nature of activity (Indian Labour Year Book, 2007 p.2). As figure 1 shows that the share of organised manufacturing sector workers [where restriction on firing workers applies; data obtained from Annual Survey of Industries (ASI)] in total organised workforce has been persistently below 30 per cent for the whole period under study (except for the last year, 2008-09). Figure: 1 Share of Org. Manufacturing Sector (ASI) in Total Organised Sector Employment Sh. of sectors other than ASI in Org. Sec. Sh. Of ASI in Org. Sec. 100 90 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 1980-81 1982-83 1984-85 1986-87 1988-89 1990-91 1992-93 1994-95 1996-97 1998-99 2000-01 2002-03 2004-05 2006-07 2008-09 in per cent Year Source: Data on Organised Manufacturing Sector from ASI, various years and Total Organised sector employment data from DGET, various years.

However, from the discussion just carried out it is clear that job security regulation applies only to a subset of the total organised sector namely, organised manufacturing sector (constituting less than 30 per cent of total organised workforce) and does not extend to the organised sector as a whole. Therefore, it is patently wrong to identify the labour laws for explaining the slowdown in employment growth of the overall organised sector since employment protection laws apply to less than a third of the total organised workforce, namely organised manufacturing sector. Next we look at the employment trends in different segments of the total organised sector and compare it with the organised manufacturing sector. For this refer to table 1 below. Table: 1 Growth Rate of Employment in different segments of the Organised Sector (in per cent) Period Organised Manufacturing (ASI) ALL Organised Sector Organised Sectors Other than ASI 1980-2008 1.31 0.59 0.34 1980-90 -0.05 1.6 2.08 1991-97 3.17 0.87 0.21 1998-2008 3.48-0.58-1.95 Source: Same as figure 1 The second column depicts the growth rate of employment in the organised manufacturing sector i.e. where labour laws apply. In the third column employment growth of the organised sector as a whole (including organised manufacturing) is calculated. Finally, the last column shows the growth rate of employment in the organised segment (excluding organised manufacturing). It is easy to see from the table that in the long time period [i.e. 1980-2008] the employment growth in organised manufacturing sector (where labour law applies) is greater than both the organised sector as a whole, as well as, the section of organised segment other than organised manufacturing. This holds true for the sub-period analysis except for the sub-period 1980-1990 1. 1 The reason behind the collapse of organised manufacturing employment in the sub-period 1980-1990 is not due to labour laws but the way ASI enumerates workers and the underlying nature of technical progress (notably labour saving variety). For details see Roychowdhury (2013).

Thus, it may be concluded that the organised manufacturing sector (where the law stipulates firms to take prior permission for firing) actually boosted the employment growth in the overall organised sector (other than the sub-period 1980-1990) rather than pulling it down. Thus, there is little evidence to suggest that the slowdown in employment growth in the organised sector as a whole was due to the labour laws. [Sluggish growth in overall organised sector employment is actually explained by the failure of the public sector to generate formal jobs a direct fallout of the conscious policy decision by the State. In fact there is also evidence on employment growth being higher in those segments of organised manufacturing where labour laws apply compared to where it does not apply (for a discussion on these issues see Roychowdhury, 2013)]. Labour laws and duality in the labour market Now we turn to the question, whether labour laws produce duality in the labour market by creating a small group of labour aristocracy located within a vast pool of informal workers. The basic argument is quite simple labour laws by extending protection of employment increases the bargaining power of workers, which in turn is utilized by them to jack up wages. As Ghose (1994) puts it A popular perception in India today is that rising labour costs [i.e. wages], [are] attributable to labour market rigidities generated by inappropriate [labour] regulations. On the other hand, since informal workers are not protected by labour laws their wages remain low. Note that in this argument one section of worker is pitted against another section; with an attempt to deviate our attention from the class distribution of income. Now if workers, armed with employment protective legislation, could raise their wages due to enhanced bargaining power then we would expect the share of wages in total output [gross value added (GVA)] to progressively rise overtime. However, from figure 2 it is clear that the available evidence is at odds to substantiate such a claim. There is almost a secular decline in the share of wages to output in fact the wage share in organised manufacturing has come down to less than 10 per cent in the most recent years. So if wage share is taken as an indicator of the relative bargaining position of labour vis-à-vis capital it is clear that the bargaining of the workers weakened over time, even in a sector where labour is statutorily protected by law. To be sure, workers in the informal sector might have received an even more raw deal, but the whole point is the position of the organised manufacturing workers deteriorated as well. By no means can the organised manufacturing workers (with a wage share of less than 10 per cent of GVA) be demarcated to constitute a labour aristocracy.

Figure: 2 35.0 Share of Wages in GVA 30.0 25.0 in per cent 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 Source: ASI, various issues One can argue a little further. There is evidence of increase in informal employment within the organised manufacturing sector. Remember, the law requiring prior permission from the government for carrying out retrenchment and layoff applies only to permanent workers and not to the workers employed through contractors (contract workers). And yet we find that the share of contract workers in total workers has increased consistently over time (figure 3). By now it is one-third of the organised manufacturing employment precisely the sector where labour law applies. Thus, any claim of labour aristocracy in midst of rising informal employment is premature. Figure: 3 in per cent 35 30 25 20 15 10 12 Proportion of contract workers to total workers - All India 30 28.6 24.6 26.5 23.1 21.8 19.7 20.4 13.2 14.7 14.1 15.3 16.6 15.5 31 31.9 32.8 5 0 1990-91 1993-94 1994-95 1995-96 1996-97 1997-98 1998-99 1999-00 2000-01 Year 2001-02 2002-03 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 2008-09 2009-10 Source: ASI, various issues

Conclusion From the above discussion it follows that none of claims normally advanced in favour of LMF can be logically sustained. Nonetheless, undertaking LMF has far reaching implications. It is easy to see that the demand for labour flexibility, by invoking the labour aristocracy argument is actually a strategy to divide the working population. By inventing the conflict of interest among different segments of the working population, LMF actually wants to further the interests of capital vis-à-vis labour as a whole. In fact to introduce LMF for rapid growth in quality employment is a contradiction in terms; this is so for once LMF is introduced, quality itself is degraded. Similarly, appealing to the labour aristocracy argument is inverted logic; if a small section of working population is better off than the vast majority of the working poor, then in the quest for obtaining a homogeneous workforce, we must search for strategies to improve the conditions of the informal workers rather than worsening the position of the formal workers. References Debroy, Bibek (2005), Issues in Labour Law Reform, in Bibek Debroy and P.D. Kaushik, ed., Reforming The Labour Market (New Delhi: Academic Foundation). Ghose, Ajit K (1994), Employment in Organised Manufacturing in India, The Indian Journal of Labour Economics, Vol. 37 No. 2: 143-162. Indian Labour Year Book (2007), Labour Bureau, Ministry of Labour, Government of India. Roychowdhury, A (2013), Labour Market Flexibility and Conditions of Labour in the Era of Globalisation: The Indian Experience, unpublished Ph.D thesis submitted to Jawaharlal Nehru University, New Delhi. Sundar, K. R. Shyam (2005), Labour Flexibility Debate in India: A Comprehensive Review and Some Suggestions, Economic and Political Weekly, May 28: 2274-2285. * This article was originally published in Vikalp- People s Perspectives for Change on January, 2014.