Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality

Similar documents
FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

Perfectly competitive markets: Efficiency and distribution

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Economics 101 Section 5

Introduction to Economic Institutions

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

AP Microeconomics Chapter 10 Outline

EconS Asymmetric Information

Module 6: Mergers in a Dynamic World

Competitive Markets. Jeffrey Ely. January 13, This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License.

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology. Dynamic Pricing

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Demand curve - using Game Results How much customers will buy at a given price Downward sloping - more demand at lower prices

Notes from Tirole, ch. 2 Product Selection, Quality, and Advertising

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

ECON 4550 (Fall 2011) Exam 1

Economics 101 Section 5

After studying this chapter you will be able to

Search markets: Introduction

INTRODUCTION ECONOMIC PROFITS

VIII 1 TOPIC VIII: MONOPOLY AND OTHER INDUSTRY STRUCTURES. I. Monopoly - Single Firm With No Threat of Close Competition. Other Industry Structures

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2004

CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

Contents. Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand- Demand and Elasticity. I) Markets and Prices. II) Demand Side. III) The Supply Side

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Quiz #4 Week 04/05/2009 to 04/11/2009

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

Ryan Oprea. Economics 176

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

If the industry s short-run supply curve equals the horizontal sum of individual firms short-run supply curves, which of the following may we infer?

Market Concentration and Power

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Economics 101 Section 5

Industrial Organization- micro : Price discrimination in oligopoly

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

Perfect competition the competitive firm s supply decision. Microeconomics

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 13 Sections 13.1, 13.2, 13.3 and 13.6 continued

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Professor Mike Conlin. Advanced Topics

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

2007 Thomson South-Western

Econ 111 2nd MT 16 17

You will find more complete answers to some of these questions in the lecture notes.

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Economics for Business. Lecture 1- The Market Forces of Supply and Demand

The Four Main Market Structures

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

= AFC + AVC = (FC + VC)

Competitive Strategy: Week 6. Dynamic Pricing

EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Ch. 9 LECTURE NOTES 9-1

Game Theory Exam, June 2015

Economics 323 Microeconomic Theory Fall 2016

Hidden Information and Self-Selection. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

AE 503 IMPERFECT INFORMATION AND PRODUCT QUALITY. Professor Ian Sheldon

microeconomics II first module

Monopoly. Monopoly 4: Durable Goods. Allan Collard-Wexler Econ 465 Market Power and Public Policy September 16, / 14

Lecture 10: Competition, Producer Surplus and Economic Efficiency

COMPETITION AND MARKETS BEFORE YOU BEGIN. Market Structures. Looking at the Chapter. Date Period. Chapter

Economics of Information and Communication Technology

Chapter 14 Perfectly competitive Market

Sample Exam Questions/Chapter 12. Use the following to answer question 1: Figure: Short-Run Costs

Managerial Economics ECO404 SUPPLY ANALYSIS

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 7, 2017 Version 01

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 7, 2017 Version 04

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

Introduction to Monopolistic Competition

Economics 101 Section 5

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 and 11) Exam #1B

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 and 11) Exam #1A

ECO 2023 Principles of Microeconomics Fall 2013 Practice Test #2. 1. Which of the following are factors of production?

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 5, 2015 Version

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 5

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

MARKET STRUCTURES. Economics Marshall High School Mr. Cline Unit Two FB

Microeconomics (Spring 2015) Final Exam Study Guide

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

Outline. Introduction. ciency. Excise Tax. Subsidy 2/29

- pure monopoly: only one seller of a good/service with no close substitutes

Exam #2 Time: 1h 15m Date: 10 July Instructor: Brian B. Young. Multiple Choice. 2 points each

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

JANUARY EXAMINATIONS 2008

Lecture 19: Imperfect Competition and Monopoly

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2012

Perfectly Competitive Markets

Transcription:

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality Information Economics (Ec 515) George Georgiadis Consider a firm that sells an experience good. Experience good: product or service where quality is di cult to observe in advance, but it can be ascertained upon consumption. Examples: restaurant, bottle of wine, etc. Firm decides how much to invest product quality. Investments are unobservable, but consumers can learn the quality by purchasing the good. Model N homogenous consumers. Each consumer has utility u = s p Outside option 0. So if a consumer expects quality s, then he will buy at price p i u = s p 0. The firm chooses price p and level of quality s. Two possible levels of quality: s =1ors =0. Production cost of a good of quality s is c s, where 0 <c 0 apple c 1 <.(c 1 < implies that it is always e cient to choose s = 1.) If the firm sells to (all) consumers at price p and produces a good of quality s, then its profits are N(p c s ). Otherwise, makes no sales, and its profits are 0. 1

Timing: 1. Seller chooses product quality s, which is unobservable to consumers. 2. Seller sets price p. 3. Consumers decide whether to buy or not at price p. 4. Payo s are realized for all parties. Benchmark: First best Assume consumers observe quality. Case 1: Firm chooses s = 0. Then: Consumers won t be willing to pay a positive price. And so the firm s profit apple 0. Case 2: Firm chooses s = 1. Then: Consumers will buy i u = p 0. So the firm will charge p = and make profit N ( c 1 ) > 0. Moral Hazard Now assume that consumers cannot observe quality. Suppose there is an equilibrium in which the firm provides a high quality product. If consumers expect quality s = 1, then they will be willing to pay any p apple. But what will the firm do? Given price p>0, it is optimal to cut quality and set s =0. By doing this, the firm saves quality costs c 1 c 0. Thus, there exists no equilibrium in which firm provides high quality goods. Consumers anticipate this, and so the firm can charge at most p =0. If p = 0, then the firm s profit = the market shuts down. Nc 0 < 0, so the firm prefers to not make sales; i.e., 2

Can we do better? So far, the model assumed that consumers cannot learn quality before buying. In most cases, some consumers can learn quality in advance (e.g., by reading consumer reviews). We will show that informed consumers exert a positive externality on the uninformed ones. i.e., they drive up the quality of the firm s product. Assume that M<Nconsumers are perfectly informed: They learn the quality of the good before buying. Simplifying assumption: Ideas would still go through if they observed a signal of product quality. Informed consumers are willing to pay: p = if quality is high, and p = 0 if quality is low. The remaining N M consumers observe product quality after they buy the good. Suppose that the monopolist charges p 2 (0, ]. Informed consumers buy only if quality is high; otherwise, they don t buy. If firm chooses s = 1, then it obtains profit M(p c 1 ) from informed buyers. Otherwise, firm earns zero profits from informed buyers. What would uninformed consumers do? Suppose they don t buy, so that demand only comes from the informed consumers. In this case, the firm s optimal strategy is to choose s = 1 (provided p>c 1 ). Hence, if p 2 (c 1, ], the uninformed consumers should buy. 3

Suppose next that uninformed consumers buy. Then the firm s profit is N(p c 1 ) if it chooses s =1(i.e., high quality). (N M)(p c 0 ) if it chooses s =0(i.e., low quality). Therefore, the firm will provide high quality if and only if N (p c 1 ) (N M)(p c 0 ) () p Nc 1 (N M) c 0 M If this inequality doesn t hold, there cannot be an equilibrium with high quality. There is an equilibrium with high quality if and only if Nc 1 (N M) c 0 M apple If the price is high, then the firm is afraid of losing a large profit margin on informed buyers, which makes low quality less attractive. Same is true if the number of informed consumers (i.e., M) is large. Increasing the number of informed consumers favors high quality (and e ciency). Repeated Game Consider now an infinitely repeated version of the model above. In each period t =0, 1, 2,..., the firm chooses product quality s t 2{0, 1}. Assume that product quality is not observable by any consumers. After choosing quality s t, the firms sets a price p t. Consumers choose in each period t whether to buy or not. Let 2 (0, 1) be the common discount factor. Consumers who bought in period t learn the quality that the seller chose (after buying). As we saw before, in a static model the seller will not choose high quality. 4

We will show that the seller may sell a high quality good in this setting with repeated interaction. We look for an equilibrium of the following type: Consumers base their expectations of quality on the firm s reputation. The firm s reputation at t is measured by quality at previous periods. At t = 0, consumers expect quality to be high. At t>0, consumers expect quality to be high only if quality was high at all prior periods. If quality is low at some period t, then consumers expect quality to be low forever. After observing low quality, consumers are not willing to pay a price higher than 0. Strategy: At t = 0 firm provides high quality and charges price p 1 > 0. Firm keeps on providing high quality (and charging price p 1 ) if it has provided high quality in all previous periods. After a deviation, it provides low quality and charges p 0 =0. Note: The firm s payo s after a deviation are zero forever. If firm never deviates, then its discounted profit is 1X t=0 t N (p 1 c 1 ) = N (p 1 c 1 ). 1 If firm instead deviates in period t, then its discounted profit is N (p 1 c 0 )+ 0 It earns N (p 1 c 0 ) in the period that it deviates, and 0 forever after. 5

Therefore, deviation is not profitable if N (p 1 c 1 ) 1 N(p 1 c 0 ) () p 1 c 1 (1 )(c 1 c 0 ) Profit margin that firm gets must be large enough. If inequality holds, future profits are more valuable than short term gain from deviating. Inequality more likely to hold if is large and when p 1 c 1 is large. In this equilibrium, reputation only matters because the consumers believe that it matters. If they believed that the firm would produce low quality regardless of the previous history, the firm would have no incentive to produce high quality. Hence, the consumers expectations would be fulfilled. References Ortner J., (2013), Lecture Notes. 6