Making game theory work for managers

Similar documents
Analyze different types of non zero sum games. Hawk vs. Dove game. Advertising problem. Problem of companies polluting the environment.

Chapter 12. A Game Theoretic Approach to Strategic Behavior

Spontaneous Cooperation under Anarchy

Competition in the Long-Distance. Telecommunications Industry

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

Managerial Economics

Markets and Strategy. Topics. Strategic Behavior. Intermediate Microeconomics

Lecture Notes on Entry and Reaction to Entry

STRATEGY. Here we suppose a game with one other player. The other player could be another firm, another person, or the industry.

PERSPECTIVES FOR CORPORATE SOCIAL RESPONSABILITY

Lecture 11 Imperfect Competition

Improved public transport? An evaluation of two reforms. Summary Report 2014:13

Chapter 13 Outline. Challenge: Intel and AMD s Advertising Strategies. An Overview of Game Theory. An Overview of Game Theory

Tobias Spindler, Tomas Voska, David Kiss, Sahar Erfani IDENTIFICATION OF ISSUES AND RECOMMENDATION

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers

Pharma s first-to-market advantage

Chapter 13. Game Theory. Gaming and Strategic Decisions. Noncooperative v. Cooperative Games

Exceptional vs. Average: What Top Leaders Do Best

How to create scenarios for change

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

WHY 97% OF ALL PRICE INCREASES FAIL and what your company needs to do different this year

Managerial Accounting Prof. Dr. Varadraj Bapat Department of School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

CIE Economics A-level

Instructions. AIRBUS A3XX: Developing the World s Largest Commercial Aircraft

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 33 Oligopoly (Contd )

IDEI Report # 12. Rail Transport. June The European Market for Freight Services : Towards A Simulation Model of Competition

Oligopoly C H A P T E R C H E C K L I S T. When you have completed your study of this chapter, you will be able to

Market analytic toolkit For assessing public service markets. Interactive

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

ETNO Comments on the BEREC report on the impact of premium content on ECS markets and the effect of devices on the open use of the Internet

Urban Transportation Planning Prof Dr. V. Thamizh Arasan Department of Civil Engineering Indian Institute Of Technology, Madras

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

Principles of Economics: Seminar 1 - Game Theory

Final Quiz Review: Solutions

AQA Economics A-level

Session 4. Essentials of Planning

Building your future workforce

Strategic Business Planning

The Pharmaceutical Industry s Supply Chain Planning Reliability and Risk Management

Customer Relationship Management Solutions for Vehicle Captive Finance. An Oracle White Paper October 2003

ECO 610: Lecture 9. Oligopoly, Rivalry, and Strategic Behavior

Incentives for Market Research: Preemption and Learning Effects

EconS Asymmetric Information

MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

Impact of Agile on Change Management

2011 Leadership, Collaboration, and Trust Research Report

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S. J. M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture - 27 Monopoly

Nuclear Power A Vital Part of a Balanced Energy Future Platts Nuclear Energy Conference Bethesda, MD February 17, 2011 (11:00 a.m.

Re-Thinking Business Strategy

Price Discrimination. It is important to stress that charging different prices for similar goods is not pure price discrimination.

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Lecture 13(ii) Announcements. 1. Application of Game Theory: Duopoly (The one-shot game case)

STRATEGY. We start with a game with one other player. The other player could be another firm or another person.

3. Value is created when the price the customer is willing to pay for a product exceeds the costs incurred by the firm in supplying the product.

2. PEST analysis is a popular environmental scanning and References: Pages *a. T b. F

Table of Contents. 1. Introduction: Competing on a different playing field The Walmart Factor ... 2

Beyond Survival Thriving on Innovation in a Down Economy

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition. The Dynamics of Pricing Rivalry

MANAGEMENT CASE STUDY May 2018 EXAM ANSWERS. Variant 4. The May 2018 exam can be viewed at

CHANGE MANAGEMENT. A Presentation by Ian Creery - January 30, The environment we re in How does change work?... 2

Econ Microeconomics Notes

WELCOA WELLNESS COUNCILS OF AMERICA ABSOLUTE ADVANTAGE 5

Strategic Gaming. An Introduction to its Application in Oil & Gas and Energy

Economic Profit AC lowest AC point higher Q & lower P MC AC C C M D=AR E E MR D=AR Q SR MR Q LR Q LR Q

Managerial Economics

Munenori SHIBATA Transport Planning and Marketing Laboratory, Signalling and Transport Information Technology Division

Managing Technological Innovation

AP Microeconomics: Test 5 Study Guide


Institute for Transport Studies FACULTY OF EARTH AND ENVIRONMENT

A package full of change: An interview with Ian Andrews of Commonwealth Bank of Australia

Decision Analysis Making the Big Decisions

Organizational Diagnostic for Market Facilitation

Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.

TRACKER TRANSFORMATION

ANALYZING THE COMPETITIVE ADVANTAGE

Microeconomics Exam Notes

Facing up to digital disruption: Reinventing the core with bold business strategy

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

OLIGOPOLY AND DUOPOLY. Asst.. Prof. Dr. Serdar AYAN

Terry College of Business - ECON 7950

Global Emerging Markets

HOW ADVANCED INDUSTRIAL COMPANIES SHOULD APPROACH ARTIFICIAL-INTELLIGENCE STRATEGY

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

A Study on Merchandise Consumption behaviour of Groceries in Coimbatore City

Competition Policy and Human Services. Where Theory Meets Practice

Chapter 3: Evaluating a Company s External Environment

Defining your own sustainable future

Welfare Economics. The Edgeworth Box. The Basic Theorem. Some Basic Assumptions

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

1) Operating costs, such as fuel and labour. 2) Maintenance costs, such as overhaul of engines and spraying.

Market Structure. Monopolistic Oligopoly. By Asst. Prof. Kessara Thanyalakpark, Ph.D.

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Quality Systems Frameworks. RIT Software Engineering

"Solutions" to Non-constant Sum Games

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Transcription:

1 JANUARY 2010 Making game theory work for managers A new model, rejecting solutions optimal only for a single precisely defined future, generates answers representing the best compromise between risks and opportunities in all likely futures. Hagen Lindstädt and Jürgen Müller

2 In times of uncertainty, game theory should come to the forefront as a strategic tool, for it offers perspectives on how players might act under various circumstances, as well as other kinds of valuable information for making decisions. Yet many managers are wary of game theory, suspecting that it s more theoretical than practical. When they do employ this discipline, it s often misused to provide a single, overly precise answer to complex problems. Our work on European passenger rail deregulation and other business issues shows that game theory can provide timely guidance to managers as they tackle difficult and, sometimes, unprecedented situations. The key is to use the discipline to develop a range of outcomes based on decisions by reasonable actors and to present the advantages and disadvantages of each option. Our model shifts game theory from a tool that generates a specific answer to a technique for giving informed support to managerial decisions. Several factors in today s economic environment should propel game theory to a prominent place in corporate strategy. The global downturn and uncertain recovery, of course, have prompted radical shifts in demand, industrial capacity, and market prices. Some companies, emboldened by the crisis, have tried to steal market share. New global competitors from emerging economies, particularly China and India, are disturbing the established industrial order. They use new technologies and business models and even have novel corporate objectives, often with longer-term horizons for achieving success. These uncertainties can paralyze corporate decision making or, perhaps worse, compel managers to base their actions on gut feelings and little else. Game theory can revitalize and contribute clear information to decision making but only if its users choose a set of inputs detailed enough to make the exercise practical and analyze a range of probable scenarios. Decades old and misunderstood Game theory as a management tool has been around for more than 50 years. Today, most university business students are introduced to the idea through the classic prisoner s dilemma. This and similar exercises have instilled the idea that game theory generates a single solution representing the best outcome for reasonable players. In academic settings, game theory focuses on logically deriving predictions of behavior that are rational for all players and seem likely to occur. It does so by seeking some form of equilibrium, or balance, based on a specific set of assumptions: the prisoners aren t aware of each other s actions, can give only one answer, and so on. But the real world is messier than the neat environment of the prisoner s dilemma, and game theory loses some traction when faced with practical, dynamically evolving business

3 problems. Companies using this approach often fail to strike the right balance between simplifying a problem to make it manageable and retaining enough complexity to make it relevant. In addition, decision makers often get a single proposed solution without understanding clearly the assumptions that went into its formulation. This problem is especially troublesome because solutions that seek a universal equilibrium among players in a sequence are sensitive to the initial conditions presented and to the assumptions used in deriving an answer. We have developed a model that addresses these objections. Instead of predicting a single outcome, with all factors balanced, the model first generates a narrow set of strategic options that can be adjusted to account for changes in various assumptions. Instead of solving an individual game, the model automatically involves a sequence of several games, allowing players to adjust their actions after each of them, and finds the best path for different combinations of factors. As one result, it supports executive decisions realistically by presenting managers with the advantages and disadvantages of the strategic options that remain at each stage of the progression. In a second step, the model finds the best robust option, considering its upside potential and downside risks under all likely scenarios, assumptions, and sensitivities as time elapses. This approach is different from attempts to look for equilibrium in an artificially simplified world. Let s say, for example, that two companies in the global machinery market face an attacker from China planning to open its own multipurpose factory. Depending on myriad assumptions about cost structures, customer demand, market growth, and other factors, the best strategy in one scenario could be for the incumbents to cut prices. In a second scenario, using slightly different assumptions, it could be best to wait until the entrant acts and then to secure the greatest value by reacting appropriately. Traditional game theory delivers the best answers and equilibriums, which could be completely different for each scenario. Then it tries to predict the most likely scenario. But you can t analyze uncertainty away, and the traditional approach actually offers management a series of snapshots, not a recommendation based on the overall picture. Our model, in contrast, examines how assumptions and actions might change and looks at possible gains and losses for each player in a dynamic world. In the example of the machinery companies, the best robust option could be to leave room for the entrant in a particular niche, where the incumbents are weakest and there s little risk that the entrant could expand into other segments. Our model seeks to balance simplicity and relevance by considering a likely set of actions and their effect on important metrics such as demand and profit. Experience and an understanding of the various actors sensitivities to different situations guide the analysis. By considering only the most relevant factors, the model manages complexity and, at the

4 same time, creates transparency around important break points for the key drivers. One such break point could be how strongly the market must react to an attacker s move before an incumbent s best strategy shifts from coexistence to counterattack. The best way to understand the model is to examine it in action. Game theory and European rail After years of debate and delay, the deregulation of passenger railways in the European Union appears to be gaining momentum. Cross-border passenger service is to be fully open to competition from January 2010. Some member states, including Germany, Italy, Sweden, and the United Kingdom, have taken the initiative and begun opening domestic long-distance passenger rail service to competition, as well. The experience of other deregulated industries provides rail operators with some lessons, such as the futility of price wars, which generally destroy an industry s profitability. But the unique characteristics of rail make it exceptionally difficult to predict how competition will alter the playing field. In passenger rail service, for instance, network effects are prevalent, as routes connecting passengers to numerous cities and towns tend to be highly interdependent. Certainly, new entrants will try to skim off some of the most profitable point-to-point routes. Despite significant upfront capital expenditures, these challengers will probably try to use lower operating costs to undercut the incumbents fares. Beyond that, it remains to be seen how and where the attackers will attack and how incumbents will defend themselves. Besides mutually destructive price wars, what options do the incumbents have? Should they rewrite their schedules to compete with the attackers timetables head-to-head? Would it make sense for them to emphasize their superior service or to compete on price by stripping away frills? Should they concede some minor routes to the new entrants in hopes of limiting the damage or fight for every passenger? To address these questions, the model we developed uses game theory to understand the dynamics of the emerging competition in long-haul passenger rail routes. It breaks down the complex competitive dynamics into a set of sequential games in which an attacker makes a move and an incumbent responds. From the perspective of the attackers, the range of options available can be distilled into four main choices. The attackers could imitate the incumbents by providing similar or identical service. They could go on the offensive with a more attractive service for instance, one that is cheaper or more frequent. They could specialize by offering a niche

5 service, probably only at peak hours, that isn t intended to compete with the incumbents across the schedule. Finally, they could differentiate by providing a clearly distinctive service, such as a low-cost offer focused on leisure travelers, with suitable timetables and less expensive, slower rolling stock. Likewise, the range of responses available to incumbents on each route under challenge can be broken down to their essence: to ignore the attackers by not reacting at all; to counterattack by contesting the entry through changes in price, frequency of service, and schedules; to coexist by ceding some routes and learning to share them; or to exit a route by stopping service on it. These initial steps in setting up a game theory model are straightforward. The crucial element is to create a list that is both exhaustive and manageable. But the world is dynamic, and the payoffs for each player depend heavily on the details. Four factors, which must also be included in the rail model, can significantly affect the outcome. Total changes in demand. What will happen to demand with each move by an attacker and response by an incumbent? When offered a broader, more comprehensive choice of rail links, passengers could change their behavior for instance, travelling by train instead of car or plane. Cost differences. New players typically have significantly lower operating costs than incumbents, which, however, generally enjoy economies of scale. But a higher degree of complexity and public-service obligations, such as maintaining uneconomical routes, often negate this advantage. Network advantages. Incumbents almost always have a network advantage, since attackers rarely replicate an incumbent s entire system. (Many routes, intrinsically unprofitable by themselves, are valuable only as feeders to the larger network.) Passengers generally prefer seamless connections a preference that plays to the incumbents strengths, especially to and from points beyond the major routes. Price sensitivity. Attackers typically charge lower fares, and the degree of difference needed for passengers to switch lines or modes of transport (from cars to trains, for instance) is critical to the outcome. In the common approach to game theory, analysts look at dozens of permutations of actions and reactions, choosing those they feel are consistent and mutually balanced, as well as most likely to occur. Then they make assumptions about these or other factors. The

6 result is a solution, with one particular set of assumptions, derived from all the interests of all the players. The solution could, for instance, be to fight the new entrant tooth and nail on all fronts. But in looking at the problem, we found several conditions in which the players interests could be seen as consistent and mutually balanced. Just as interesting, the results were sensitive to our initial assumptions: in other words, when we slightly modified an assumption about, say, changes in demand, the results would be very different. From this perspective, our model resembles a business simulator, allowing executives to get a clear understanding of the likely evolution of competition under differing conditions. It helps companies to generate the best option as the moves of competitors become clear. The outcome of the rail analysis What did the model say about European passenger rail? Consider, first, one set of conditions. In this scenario, the incumbent operates a fairly large network and has enjoyed monopoly advantages in particular, relatively high profits. But because of the monopoly legacy, the incumbent suffers from operational inefficiencies and a sizeable cost base. Overall demand is elastic: customers are likely to travel more by rail if service improves and quite likely to accept low-price offers. A new company with a substantially lower cost base considers cherry-picking a few of the more attractive routes by offering improved service. This model suggests that although the attacker enjoys lower costs and seems to have a favorable starting position, it will probably take only a sliver of market share, and that thanks largely to a general increase in rail use. The incumbent will remain dominant. Seeing the likely outcome of the attacker s specialized or niche entry, the incumbent s executives should conclude that a strategy of tolerance would be best. Only a small share of the market is at stake, and the incumbent could lose much more if it engaged in a costly battle for this sliver for instance, by waging a destructive price war or using other expensive tactics. If the attacker is more aggressive, the incumbent s best answer would be to fight back with tactics including aggressive price competition, targeted marketing activities, and more frequent and better service on the routes under attack. Note, however, that this would substantially lower profits for both players. To cover the full range of possibilities, the model can manipulate each variable. Under certain circumstances (if the demand reaction is muted, the incumbent s cost disadvantage high, and its network advantage small) entrants have the inside track and could probably take control of the market. When circumstances favor the incumbent a little more (because its network advantage is stronger or its cost disadvantage smaller) it will probably have strong incentives to lower prices preemptively to prevent a possible attacker s entry.

7 Exhibit 1 Three scenarios Entrant s share of total profit Increase in total demand for rail services 1 Incumbent s cost disadvantage Competitive scenarios 3 Coexistence: incumbent retains market leadership 1 Market takeover by entrant 2 Incumbent actively blocks entrant : Single route/ closed market Medium: Network with one center Relative network advantage of incumbent : Polycentric network 1 Degree of change in rail's share of all travelers (compared with those opting for other forms of transport) as a result of new entrant in market. If conditions are more ambiguous, the incumbent may have to settle for coexistence, although it can probably retain market leadership. The attacker s share of the industry s profits would vary significantly, depending mainly on the incumbent s network advantage (Exhibit 1). When we run the European passenger rail model through an array of different situations, a critical factor appears to be the way demand reacts to liberalization. Will the new offerings seduce travelers to take trains rather than cars or jetliners, or will overall demand remain stagnant, leaving rail companies to battle for an unchanged pool of customers (Exhibit 2)? If the attacker s entry doesn t stimulate demand, two operators cannot profitably share most routes: high fixed costs make many of them natural monopolies supporting only a certain level of capacity. A weak incumbent for instance, one with major cost disadvantages or few network benefits could be squeezed out by an agile attacker. A strong incumbent could cut fares before the attacker committed itself to any investment, dissuading it from making the challenge. In the end, the competitors will face a winnertakes-all situation, with only one left in the market. When rail demand can be stimulated, players will probably coexist profitably. But the model suggests that even when the attacker enjoys the best conditions, the incumbent is

8 Exhibit 2 The influence of pricing Increase in total demand for rail services 1 Incumbent s cost disadvantage Competitive scenarios Entrant s share of total profit Changes resulting from very high price sensitivity of passengers 3 Coexistence: incumbent retains market leadership 1a Market takeover by entrant 1 Market takeover by entrant 2 Incumbent actively blocks entrant 2a Captive market for incumbent : Single route/ closed market Medium: Network with one center Relative network advantage of incumbent : Polycentric network 1 Degree of change in rail's share of all travelers (compared with those opting for other forms of transport) as a result of new entrant in market. likely to retain market leadership. Reasonable attackers will have an incentive to enter only on a small scale that the incumbent can usually tolerate. More aggressive moves from either side would trigger ruinous price wars or service expansions, destroying the industry s overall profitability. Finally, at each moment, incumbents almost always have one best robust option that conserves much more of their profits than any other course. Quite often, deviating from that option reduces the entire industry s profits significantly. But unlike a solution based on traditional game theory a solution optimal only for a single precisely defined future our model generates an answer that represents the best compromise between risks and opportunities across all likely futures. Unlike the answers suggested by traditional game theory, this one does not require all competitors to behave according to a narrowly defined rational equilibrium at each moment. The transparency of our approach helps executives understand the break points of a strategy: how much reality must differ from its assumptions before a new strategy is needed. Although we focus here on European passenger rail, our model shows how game theory can be applied to many complex environments and produce results informing many strategic decisions. We ve applied the model to other problems, with similarly enlightening

9 Related articles Games managers should play Getting into your competitor s head Beating the odds in market entry results. In health care, for example, we examined the dynamics of the commoditization of certain drugs in particular, after Asian manufacturers offered higher-quality versions of them. We also looked at the strategic options of companies in the chemical industry in the wake of recent overcapacity and reduced demand. Game theory is a powerful framework that enables managers to analyze systematically the ties among interactions between actors in a market and to develop appropriate competitive strategies. But it s helpful only if executives expect a tool that helps them make informed decisions based on a range of market actions by each player, not a single answer that solves the whole riddle. Hagen Lindstädt is the head of the Institute for Management at Karlsruhe University, and Jürgen Müller is a principal in McKinsey s Stockholm office. Copyright 2010 McKinsey & Company. All rights reserved.