Job Satisfaction and the Gender Composition of Jobs

Similar documents
Performance Pay, Competitiveness, and the Gender Wage Gap: Evidence from the United States

Ruhm, C. (1990). Do Earnings Increase with Job Seniority? The Review of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 72 (1):

Gender Occupational Segregation in an Equilibrium Search Model

Wage Mobility within and between Jobs

Chapter 12 Gender, Race, and Ethnicity in the Labor Market

Firms often use promotions both to give

Workplace Social Interaction and Wage Premium

Wasted Resources in Germany: the Paucity of Female Supervisors and the Wage Disadvantage of Their Subordinates

Appendix (Additional Materials for Electronic Media of the Journal) I. Variable Definition, Means and Standard Deviations

Restricted Regular Employees and Compensating Wage Differentials: Theory and Evidence *

Journal of Business & Economics Research Volume 2, Number 11

Outline. Human capital theory by C. Echevarria. Investment decision. Outline. Investment decision. Investment decision

Gender Composition of Occupations and Earnings: Why Enter a Female Dominated Occupation?

A Note on Sex, Geographic Mobility, and Career Advancement. By: William T. Markham, Patrick O. Macken, Charles M. Bonjean, Judy Corder

THE DYNAMICS OF SKILL MISMATCHES IN THE DUTCH LABOR MARKET

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WORK HOURS, WAGES, AND VACATION LEAVE. Joseph G. Altonji Emiko Usui. Working Paper

Appendix A: Methodology

The Computer Use Premium and Worker Unobserved Skills: An Empirical Analysis

UNIVERSITY OF WAIKATO. Hamilton. New Zealand. The Public Sector Pay Premium and Compensating Differentials in the New Zealand Labour Market

Review Questions. Defining and Measuring Labor Market Discrimination. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

Distribution of annual earnings for all adults ages 23-62, by sex and race.

Labor Market Segmentation and the Gender Wage Gap Haruhiko Hori

Determinants of the Gender Gap in the Proportion of Managers among White-Collar Regular Workers in Japan

Beyond Signaling and Human Capital: Education and the Revelation of Ability

Wages and Recruitment: Evidence from External Wage Changes

Employer Learning, Job Changes, and Wage Dynamics

Public Sector Pay Premium and Compensating Differentials in the New Zealand Labour Market

IRLE. Do Race, Age, and Gender Differences Affect Manager-Employee Relations? An Analysis of Quits, Dismissals, and Promotions at a Large Retail Firm

II. Human Capital, Returns to Education and Experience. D. Estimating the Returns to Seniority and Specific Human Capital

Job Turnover and Income Mobility

KDI SCHOOL WORKING PAPER SERIES

Employer Learning, Job Changes, and Wage Dynamics

RETAIL TRADE Workforce Demographics

Insecurity of Employment and Work-Life Balance: From the viewpoint of compensating wage differentials

Available through a partnership with

Estimating Earnings Equations and Women Case Evidence

Unpaid Overtime in Germany: Differences between East and West

Male - Female Wage Growth, Occupational Segregation, and Technological Change 1

Employer Learning, Job Changes, and Wage Dynamics

Layoffs and Lemons over the Business Cycle

Multiple job holding, local labor markets, and the business cycle

On-the-Job Search and Wage Dispersion: New Evidence from Time Use Data

Are Shirking and Leisure Substitutable? An Empirical Test of Efficiency Wages Based on Urban Economic Theory

The dynamics of second job holding in Britain

Occupational stereotypes, gender segregation and job satisfaction

More than meets the eye Gender differences in hierarchical positions and in earnings. Lessons from the Finnish metal industry 1

Community Mental Health Journal, Vol. 40, No. 1, February 2004 ( 2004)

Should Workers Care about Firm Size? 1

Earnings of men and women in firms with a female dominated workforce

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Discrimination, Segmentation and Vulnerability in the Labor Market. Luca Flabbi

An Extension of the Blinder-Oaxaca Decomposition to a Continuum of Comparison Groups

Explaining the Wage Gap Between Contingent and Noncontingent Workers

THE NEW WORKER-EMPLOYER CHARACTERISTICS DATABASE 1

MARRIAGE, CHILD BEARING AND THE PROMOTION OF WOMEN TO MANAGERIAL POSITIONS i

Recent Developments in Inequality Research

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

Working Long Hours and Early Career Outcomes in. the High-End Labor Market

The Effects of Gender Segregation at the Occupation, Industry, Establishment, and Job-Cell Levels on the Male-Female Wage Gap

Type of Education and the Gender Wage Gap

Globalization & gender wage gap

working paper department technology massachusetts of economics 50 memorial drive institute of Cambridge, mass

Lecturer: Dr. Joana Salifu Yendork, Department of Psychology Contact Information:

Preliminary Draft: Do Not Cite. Social Skills and Promotions

III. Wage Determination and Labour Market Discrimination

Race, Internet Usage, and E-Commerce. Hiroshi Ono and Madeline Zavodny. Working Paper January Working Paper Series

Did The Minimum Wage Affect the Incidence of Second Job Holding in Britain?

Training and the New Minimum Wage

Three Essays on Self-Employment Transitions, Organizational Capital, and Firm Formation

Transitions of creatives? empirical evidence on occupation and industry specific human capital

Technological Change and Wage Premium in a Small Open Economy: An Inter-Industry Analysis

PAY EQUITY AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE CHEN SONG, PH.D. - JULY 2018

Working from Home: Heterogenous Effects on Hours Worked and Wages

World of Labor. Peter J. Sloane Swansea University, UK, Flinders University, Australia, and IZA, Germany. Cons. Pros

Job Change and Job Stability among Less-Skilled Young Workers

Earnings and Discrimination

Automation and Job Polarization: On the Decline of Middling Occupations in Europe

CEP Discussion Paper No 1446 August Does Rosie Like Riveting? Male and Female Occupational Choices. Grace Lordan Jörn-Steffen Pischke

The Gender Pay Gap In International Perspective

Displacement, Asymmetric Information, and Heterogeneous Human Capital

The Relative Power of Employment-to-Employment Reallocation and Unemployment Exits in Predicting Wage Growth

Structural Change and the Narrowing Gender Gap in Wages: Theory and Evidence from Hong Kong

Working Long Hours and Career Wage Growth

A STUDY OF WORKING CONDITIONS

Topics in Labor Supply

This PDF is a selection from an out-of-print volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research. Volume Title: Distribution of Economic Well-Being

Volume Title: Labor Statistics Measurement Issues. Volume URL:

GENDER AND RACE IN THE LABOR MARKET

Women in the Corporate World: Who Hires and Promotes Them?

Private Returns to Education in Greece: A Review of the Empirical Literature

ECO361: LABOR ECONOMICS FINAL EXAMINATION DECEMBER 17, Prof. Bill Even DIRECTIONS.

Earnings and Percentage Female: A Longitudinal Study

The Instability of Unskilled Earnings

Job satisfaction in Britain: individual and job related factors

Hi-Stat Discussion Paper. Research Unit for Statistical and Empirical Analysis in Social Sciences (Hi-Stat)

WAGE EFFECTS OF FIRM SIZE: EVIDENCE FROM LINKED EMPLOYER-EMPLOYEE PANEL

Unknown Wage Offer Distribution. and Job Search Duration

Women s labor force participation Income and substitution elasticities, and some critical remarks

Union Membership and Job Satisfaction. A Meta-Analysis. Patrice Laroche ESCP Europe (Paris) & Université de Lorraine.

Essays on Multiple Job Holding Across Local Labor Market

Transcription:

Job Satisfaction and the Gender Composition of Jobs Emiko Usui Abstract Using job satisfaction data from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth, I examine whether people who move to predominantly male jobs are fully compensated through their wages for their new jobs disamenities. Estimates from the ordered probit models indicate that women are satisfied with their pay in predominantly male jobs, but dislike the job amenities. In contrast, men appreciate both the pay and the amenities of such jobs. Overall, both sexes prefer predominantly male jobs, but this effect is insignificant for women. This result suggests that, for women, most of the wage premium paid in male jobs is a compensating differential. Keywords: Compensating differentials; Wage and job-amenities; Job satisfaction. JEL: J16; J28; J33. This paper is a revised chapter from my Northwestern University Ph.D. dissertation. I am grateful to Joseph Altonji, Christopher Taber, and Dale Mortensen for their guidance. I thank Gadi Barlevy, Rebecca Blank, Paula England, Luojia Hu, Randal Watson, and an anonymous referee for helpful comments. All errors are my own. Economics Department, Wayne State University, Detroit, MI 48202 USA. Tel:+1-313-577-3349. Fax:+1-313-577-9564. Email: usui@wayne.edu.

2 1 Introduction Many studies report that the proportion of men in an occupation has a significant, positive relation with wages (e.g., Johnson and Solon, 1987; England et al., 1988; Sorensen, 1990; Groshen, 1991; Macpherson and Hirsch, 1995), 1 and researchers offer a variety of explanations for the pay disparity between female- and male-dominated occupations, such as discrimination, job-specific differences in productivity, and compensating differentials. 2 Research indicates that the positive relation between the proportion male in an occupation and wages is reduced, but still persists, when the wage equation controls for the job-characteristics. Such studies conclude that uncompensated pay differences remain for the pay disparity. However, researchers in these studies are unable to control for all of the job-characteristics that influence wages (Brown, 1980). Furthermore, the literature is not very informative regarding whether the estimated relation between the proportion male and wages reflects compensating differentials or uncompensated differences in pay, i.e., whether the wage premium associated with male jobs under-, just-, or over-compensates for the negative characteristics of such jobs. To fill this gap in understanding compensating differentials using wage data, this paper directly examines workers reported satisfaction rates on jobs pecuniary and non-pecuniary aspects. I use the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY), which includes information on individuals overall job satisfaction rate and their satisfaction rates from wages and jobamenities. A simple model of job satisfaction is established for individuals who change jobs to examine the relation between their change in the proportion male in an occupation and the change in their reported job satisfaction rates. Estimates from the ordered probit models indicate that men report greater satisfaction from both the pay and the job-amenities in predominantly male jobs. In contrast, women report higher satisfaction from the pay received, but lower satisfaction from the job-amenities. Specifically,men andwomenholdopposite views about pleasantness of physical surroundings, whether they can do the things they do best, and friendliness of co-workers. Both report dissatisfaction regarding on-the-job dangers and the extent of exposure to unhealthy conditions. Overall, both sexes report that predominantly male jobs are more satisfying. This effect is insignificant for women, however. These 1 These studies estimate the effect of proportion female in occupation on wages. In this paper it is expositionally convenient to estimate the effect of proportion male on wages (the wage premium). 2 See Altonji and Blank (1999) for explanations. One possibility is that societal and labor market discrimination crowd women into traditionally female jobs, lowering wages for these jobs. A second possibility is that skill premium is paid in male jobs. A third possibility is that male jobs pay compensating differentials for the negative job-characteristics (e.g., longer working hours and less-desirable conditions).

3 results suggest that women sacrifice working conditions for higher pay, and that part (but not all) of the wage premium compensates for negative job-characteristics in male jobs. 2 Data TheNLSY,thesourceofdatainthispaper,isbasedonanationallyrepresentativesample of individuals between age 14 and 22 when first interviewed in 1979. Survey members were asked to rate pecuniary and non-pecuniary aspects of their jobs in 1979-82: We would like to know how well or poorly each of the following statements describes your job. The pay is good. You are given a chance to do the things you do best. The physical surroundings are pleasant. Your co-workers are friendly. The job is dangerous. You are exposed to unhealthy conditions. The job security is good. The skills you are learning would be valuable in getting a better job. The response categories were: (1) not at all true, (2) not too true, (3) somewhat true, and (4) very true. The respondents also were questioned about overall job satisfaction: How do you feel about the job you have now? The response categories were: (1) dislike it very much, (2) dislike it somewhat, (3) like it fairly well, and (4) like it very much. The gender composition of an occupation is measured by the proportion of men in the worker s three-digit occupational category (PMALE). It is calculated from the 1980 U.S. Census Public Use Microdata 5-percent Sample. I focus on the trade-off in terms of pay and job-amenities individuals experience when they move to occupations with differentproportionsofmenintheeventofajobseparation. 3 Since some job changes may be associated with school-to-work transitions, the individual sample is limited to those not enrolled in school for at least one year prior to the interview. Appendix Table 1 presents selected sample characteristics. Since the early waves of the NLSY are used, 3 People who stay with current employers are excluded, because they cannot easily change job-characteristics while remaining with the same employer (Altonji and Paxson, 1988). Nearly fifty percent of job stayers do not change their occupations over time, and the variation in PMALE is fairly small among stayers with occupation changes.

4 the labor market experience (years worked since leaving school) is 3.8 years; fifty-six percent of the sample are high school graduates, and there are only a few college graduates. This paper examines the reasons for the early labor market career transitions of non-college workers, whose preferences are less affected by past labor market opportunities. 3 Econometric Model of Job Satisfaction Let the utility of individual i whose gender is g (m for men and f for women) working in a job j at time t be, U ijt = w ijt + C j Ω g, (1) where w ijt is the logarithm of wages of individual i in job j at time t, C j is a vector of amenities in job j, and Ω g measures the preference for the vector of amenities relative to wages for type-g workers. Men and women may value job-amenities differently, and Ω g may vary between them. Consider a linear projection of the index of amenities (C j Ω g ) on the proportion male in an occupation, and define φ g to be the coefficient of the projection. Then, C j Ω g = φ g PMALE j + ξ j, (2) where PMALE j is the proportion male in the individual s occupation, and ξ j is the error term uncorrelated with PMALE j by definition of φ g, but may be correlated with w ijt. I plug Eq.(2) into utility function (1) and obtain a reduced-form utility function, U ijt = w ijt + φ g PMALE j + ξ j, (3) where φ g measures preference for working in male jobs relative to preference for higher wages. Previous studies estimate the effect of PMALE on wages using the following regression, w ijt = θpmale j + Z it Π + ε i + v ijt, (4) where θ is the coefficient of PMALE j, Z it is a vector of an intercept and other observed wage determinants with Π the corresponding coefficient vector, ε i is a fixed individual-specific error component, and v ijt is an error term. These studies first-difference Eq.(4) to eliminate ε i which is correlated with PMALE j. I also take this first-difference approach to eliminate unobserved individual heterogeneity. Whenworkersmovefromajobj (t 1) to a new job j (t), the change in utility is, U ij(t)t U ij(t 1)t = w ij(t)t w ij(t 1)t + Cj(t) Ω g C j(t 1) Ω g. (5)

5 Thechangeinutilityisthesumofthechangesinvalueofwagesandvalueofjob-amenities. Workers can change jobs to acquire higher wages while sacrificing job-amenities, and vice versa. Let Sijg O denote the overall job satisfaction rate for individual i whose gender is g in job j; Sijg W the satisfaction rate of wages; and Sijg A the satisfaction rate of job-amenities. I approximate the changes in utility, value of wages and value of job-amenities as, Sij(t)g O SO ij(t 1)g = b 0 Uij(t)t U ij(t 1)t Sij(t)g W SW ij(t 1)g = b 1 wij(t)t w ij(t 1)t (6) Sij(t)g A SA ij(t 1)g = b 2 Cj(t) Ω g C j(t 1) Ω g, where b 0,b 1,b 2 > 0. 4 First, using wage regression (4), I rewrite the change in value of wages as, 4Sij(t)g W = b 1 θ 4 PMALEj(t) + 4Z it Π + 4v ij(t)t. (7) I estimate the wage premium θ up to scale using Eq.(7). Next, using the reduced-form expression of job-amenities in Eq.(2), I rewrite the change in value of job-amenities as, 5 4S A ij(t)g = b 2 φg 4 PMALE j(t) + 4ξ j(t). (8) Substituting Eq.(8) into the equation for the change in overall job satisfaction, 4S O ij(t)g = b 0 b 1 4 S W ij(t)g + b 0 b 2 4 S A ij(t) = b 0 4 Sij(t)g W + b 0 φ b g 4 PMALE j(t) + b 0 4 ξ j(t). (9) 1 Using Eqs.(8) or (9), the preference parameter φ g is estimated up to scale. Lastly, substituting out 4Sij(t)g W from Eq.(9) by plugging in Eq.(7), 4S O ij(t)g = b 0 θ + φg 4 PMALEj(t) + b 0 4 Z it Π + b 0 4 ξ j(t) + b 0 4 v ij(t)t. (10) I estimate θ + φ g up to scale using Eq.(10). Whenthesignofθ + φ g is positive (negative), the wage premium θ overcompensates (does not compensate) for the negative job-characteristics. When θ+φ g =0, the wage premium perfectly compensates for the negative job-characteristics. 4 Men and women may differ in the ratings of the importance of pay and job-amenities. See Konrad et al. (2000) for a summary of these studies in psychology. This difference implies that the satisfaction metric, b 0, b 1 and b 2,mayvarybygender. 5 Job attributes other than wages and on-the-job amenities also may affect job satisfaction. Commuting time is an example. Such job attributes can be treated as an error term.

6 4 Results Job satisfaction rates are indexed from 1 to 4, and ordered probit models are used for estimation. Table 1 presents the effects of the change in the proportion male on various changes in job satisfaction rates. Women who move to more predominantly male jobs report that: physical surroundings depreciate, co-workers are less friendly, and they are less likely to be given a chance to do the things they do best. Men, however, report opposite views. Both men and women are satisfied with the pay they receive when moving into predominantly male jobs. They also agree that: work becomes more dangerous; and they are exposed to unhealthier conditions. In general, the estimates on the effects of the proportion male on job satisfaction are greater for men than women; and the estimates often have opposite signs for the two groups. Several male-female coefficient differences are significant. This suggests that men and women have different preferences for job-amenities or that job-characteristics conditional on the proportion male in an occupation differ between sexes. 6 The overall job satisfaction rate increases for men and women as they move to more predominantly male jobs. However, this coefficient is significant for men but not for women, suggesting that most of the wage premium paid in male jobs compensates for the negative jobcharacteristics for women. Men and women are less satisfied when they move to more female jobs, implying that their decisions are based on factors other than higher occupational utility (which is determined by wage and on-the-job-amenities). 7 There are at least two possible reasons why they would change jobs. Gladden (2001) argues that if a husband chooses to leave his job to move to a new one, the wife may leave also to accompany her husband (viewed as a quit for the wife). In this case, the wife may accept a less-satisfying, female job. Another possibility is that workers may move take less-satisfying jobs located in more convenient locations. The preference parameter φ g is estimated up to scale using Eq.(9). Using ordered probit models, I estimate the change in overall job satisfaction rate on the change in proportion male, dummies for the change in job satisfaction rate of pay, and demographic variables. The coefficients onthechangeinproportionmaleare.139 (.148) for women and.320 (.124) for men. Women prefer job-amenities in female jobs, but men prefer job-amenities in male jobs. 6 Menandwomeninmalejobsworkindifferent types of jobs. Most women who work in such jobs hold white-collar managerial positions, whereas men do both white-collar and blue-collar work. 7 The results are robust to restricting the sample to quits.

7 5 Conclusion This paper examines the relation between job satisfaction and the proportion male in an occupation. Men and women report higher overall job satisfaction (including better pay) in predominantly male jobs. However, most of the pay premium for women is a compensating differential, because the effect of proportion male on overall job satisfaction is insignificant. References Altonji, J.G. and R.M.Blank. 1999. Race and Gender in the Labor Market. in: O.Ashenfelter and D.Card eds., Handbook of Labor Economics. 3C, (North-Holland, Amsterdam) 3143-259. Altonji, J.G. and C.H.Paxson. 1988. Labor Supply Preferences, Hours Constraints, and Hours-Wage Trade-offs. Journal of Labor Economics 6, 254-76. Brown, C. 1980. Equalizing Differences in the Labor Market. Quarterly Journal of Economics 94, 113-34. England, P., G.Farkas, B.Kilbourne, and T.Dou. 1988. Explaining Occupational Sex Segregation and Wages: Findings from a Model with Fixed-Effects. American Sociological Review 53, 544-58. Gladden, P.L. 2001. Wage Effects of Family Ties and Migration. In Essays on Wage Growth, Diss., Northwestern University. Groshen, E.L. 1991. The Structure of the Female/Male Wage Differential: Is It Who You Are, What You Do, or Where You Work? Journal of Human Resources 26, 457-72. Johnson, G.E., and G.Solon. 1986. Estimates of the Direct EffectsofComparableWorth Policy. American Economic Review 76, 1117-25. Konrad, AM., J.E.Ritchie, P.Lieb, and E.Corrigall. 2000. Sex Differences and Similarities in Job Attribute Preferences: A Meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin 126, 593-641. Macpherson, D.A. and B.T.Hirsch. 1995. Wages and Gender Composition: Why Do Women s Jobs Pay Less? Journal of Labor Economics 13, 426-71. Sorensen, E. 1990. The Crowding Hypothesis and Comparable Worth. Journal of Human Resources 25, 55-89.

Table 1. Ordered Probit Estimates of Proportion Male Effects on Job Satisfaction Rates Dependent Variable Overall job satisfaction Pay is good Can do what you do best Pleasant physical surroundings Friendly co-workers Dangerous job Exposure to unhealthy conditions Good job security Skills valuable in getting better job Men Women Male-Female Difference 0.346 0.040 0.292 (0.116) (0.131) (0.177) 0.407 0.371 0.027 (0.135) (0.139) (0.194) 0.390-0.120 0.512 (0.132) (0.140) (0.191) 0.004-0.249 0.243 (0.118) (0.137) (0.179) 0.125-0.335 0.470 (0.138) (0.159) (0.212) 0.543 0.573 0.065 (0.128) (0.137) (0.181) 0.398 0.115 0.308 (0.116) (0.138) (0.177) 0.167 0.396-0.219 (0.123) (0.145) (0.188) 0.338-0.172 0.510 (0.139) (0.151) (0.204) Models control for a set of demographic characteristics: changes in experience and its square, change in education, change in dummies for marital status, residence in SMSA and region, and calendar years. Robust panel standard errors are in parentheses. Appendix Table 1. Means of Selected Variables Variable Men Women Proportion male (PMALE ) 0.763 0.273 Wage 6.106 4.938 Hours/week 40.96 35.79 Less than high school education 0.374 0.198 High school education 0.512 0.624 Some college education 0.106 0.166 College education 0.007 0.012 Black 0.203 0.124 Experience 3.890 3.787 Married 0.292 0.395 N 1074 751