Market Definition in the Digital Age

Similar documents
Digital Revolution, Disruptive Innovation and Conduct Assessment: New Insights Needed for Enforcement?

Overview. 0. Market definition contested (but not covered here) 1. Dominance 2. Foreclosure

Antitrust Concerns in Digital Markets: A Selection. Integrating Complements, and the Role of Data

Economic analysis of Narrow MFN Clauses. ACE Conference, Madrid 2017

Price signaling. An economic perspective. Raphaël De Coninck

Competition and IP Pierre Régibeau CRA and Imperial College GCLC Brussels

MFN clauses. Competition enforcement in the face of regulatory intervention. EU Competition Law Summit. Spyros Droukopoulos.

Geoblocking in Digital Online Distribution: Unfair? Anticompetitive?

Two-sided platforms and airports

MEASURING MARKET POWER IN MULTI-SIDED MARKETS

Most Favored Nation Clauses: Is It the End of the Road?

CERRE CENTRE ON REGULATION IN EUROPE

Theories of harm. Conception, reliability and selection. Hans Zenger 27/10/2011

Market power in digital platforms

The Information Economy. The Nature of Information Goods

Sasol Fertilizer. An alternative explanation. ACE Conference Bergen, Norway

How Google Maps Platform Helps Ride Sharing Services Improve the Customer and Driver Experience while Increasing Overall Efficiency

EU and German Competition Law II (Abuse of a dominant position, Merger Control)

The Economics of E-commerce and Technology. The Nature of Technology Industries

Global Forum on Competition

ONLINE RESTRAINTS EFFECTS, ANALYSIS AND ENFORCEMENT

Platforms in the Spotlight at the FTC Hearings

Where is Online Distribution Going?

Market Definition in the Digital Era

THE WORLD WANTS SMART MOBILITY

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group

Re: Public consultation on the regulatory environment for platforms, online intermediaries, data and cloud computing and the collaborative economy

Internet Sales and Contractual Restrictions of Competition Law Lessons learnt from the EU e- Commerce Sector Inquiry

Revisiting the hypothetical monopolist test, and the role of common sense market definitions

LOOKING TO DRIVE REVENUE? PARTNER UP. The Mobile Payments Opportunity for Telcos

THE WORLD WANTS SMART MOBILITY

Online Vertical Restraints: divergence of competition policy

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

Comparative Analysis and Urban Public Policies: A methodology for conceptualizing the role of the actors

Vertical Agreements Between Suppliers and Retailers with Horizontal Effects

Oligopolies in electronic communications: more concentration, more regulation?

Net Neutrality An issue for ex ante or ex post intervention?

Zero-rating and net neutrality

Session 6: Market Analysis tools and cases

Get started with your own On Demand Solutions as you need it, reasonable pricing and perfect working solution with Corporate Option

THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION S ANDROID DECISION AND BROADER LESSONS FOR ARTICLE 102 ENFORCEMENT

Vertical Restraints, Exclusive Dealing, and Competition on the Merits

Market Definition in Online Markets: Mission Impossible?

STEP 6: TRACK YOUR IMPACT

Most Favoured Nation clauses and online platforms: competitive effects and EU competition law

Vertical restraints, digital marketplaces, and enforcement tools

Industrial Organization

Market Definition and Market Power in Payment Card Networks

TWO-SIDED PLATFORMS AND ANALYSIS OF SINGLE FIRM CONDUCT

Unscripted drama: vertical issues raised in European pay-tv mergers

Consumer responses: how quick are they?

9 th Annual Baxt Lecture and Panel Discussion WELCOME. Competition Law and Economics Network Melbourne Law School

Vertical Agreements and the Internet: An economic assessment

Quick Guide: Passenger App

Tourism and Digital Marketing

Understanding the Basic Economics of the Internet: Building a Foundation for 21 st Century Public Policy. John W. Mayo

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim

Consumer Behavior on E-commerce. Mobile Apps

Case B9-66/10 HRS Economic assessment of platform MFNs

Session 2: Competition Policy Fundamentals

If you would like to provide us with your thoughts on what ACM should focus on, please get in touch by sending an to

October 2018 Global Product Delivery Highlights C O N F I D E N T I A L

The Social Commerce Revolution. Let s Get Personal TTI Spring 2013

So, why the move from Hotel Beds to Full Service OTA? * * as asked by Martin a few weeks back

10th Meeting of the Advisory Expert Group on National Accounts, April 2016, Paris, France

Reinventing the taxi business model Contribution to the 8 th IRU International Taxi Forum Cologne November 2 nd Prof. Richard Darbéra (CNRS)

Kalibri Labs & Distribution Channel Analysis

Plenary #4: Assessing price parity agreements

Report A closer look at Online video platforms

Behavioural targeting: Can online advertising deliver in 2006?

The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement

Digital Edition Trends and Reporting PPA Breakfast Briefing. By Patrick Knight and Carola York

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

The economic analysis of two-sided markets and its implications for competition law

AIRPLUS. WHAT TRAVEL PAYMENT IS ALL ABOUT.

ETNO Comments on the BEREC report on the impact of premium content on ECS markets and the effect of devices on the open use of the Internet

The 'stickiness' of prices

Ultimate Access. Fully Integrated, Intelligent Hospitality Solutions.

Aditya Bhattacharjea Delhi School of Economics

DRAFT COMMISSION GUIDELINES ON THE ASSESSMENT OF NON- HORIZONTAL MERGERS

Overview of Format and Topic

Cambridge David Newbery Richard Green Karsten Neuhoff Paul Twomey

How to define relevant markets in the tourism sector?

COMPETITION AUTHORITY OF KENYA GUIDELINES ON RELEVANT MARKET DEFINITION I. INTRODUCTION

steel and iron ore Examining the evidence

Response prepared by Augusta Maciuleviciuté, Agustín Reyna and Jean Allix

Public policies in digital markets: reflections from competition enforcement

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition

2008 Year-in-Review Benchmarks

The single source of truth: Data as the basis for successful Destination Management in the future

Business Austan Goolsbee Technology and Policy in the Telecom, Media, and Technology Industries Final Exam Answers

Introduction. Managerial Problem. Solution Approach

TOP 10 Tools To Build Your Business Online. by JupiterTechs

Guide to being online

How to Build Brands Using Online Advertising: Lessons Learned

A GUIDELINE FOR CONDUCTING MARKET REVIEWS

Modelos para o Crescimento Digital nas Comunicações e Media Fórum AICEP das Comunicações Lusófonas

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

What do changing business models in the telecoms industry mean for competition law and regulation in the digital era?

Deadweight Loss of Monopoly

Transcription:

Market Definition in the Digital Age PROS AND CONS OF MARKET DEFINITION ANNUAL KONKURRENSVERKET CONFERENCE STOCKHOLM 3 NOVEMBER 2017 1

Outline Characteristics that complicate market definition in digital settings, and appropriate conceptual framework for defining these markets Default of defining markets by relying on technical characteristics is not appropriate What economic evidence/analysis can be brought to bear to define these markets? Pros and cons of market definition in these settings: do we do away with it? 2

1. Challenges in defining markets and assessing competitive constraints 3

Understanding channels of competition Multiple products/ services sold to consumers in multiple different ways, within a stack of services Search Product information Product sampling Distribution format Consumption formats Bundles Complementary offers with contractual relations not seen before Multiple alternative contract structures with customers and various business models with multiple forms of monetisation Including zero prices for certain services, as paid for by the other side of the platform Measuring substitution is harder, so typical fall-back on narrow separate markets based on the function the user performs on the platform search / compare / social networking / buy 4

Harder to think about substitution in these structures Challenge 1: Substitution in a world with zero prices Challenge 2: Substitution between competing business models Challenge 3: Two-sidedness & competition for platform engagement 5

Challenge 1: Substitution in a world with zero prices Multi-sided business models tend to adopt asymmetric pricing strategies: lower price on the more elastic side to draw in more users that can be monetised on the other side. Combined with practical restrictions to charge negative prices, this means user-side prices have a tendency to bunch at zero. Search engines, social networks, price comparison sites all have zero prices on user side Challenges to applying a SSNIP test when there is no variation in price: how does one measure substitution to relative price changes? How to avoid the Cellophane Fallacy? An equivalent test could be formulated in terms of quality: can a hypothetical monopolist impose a Small but Significant Non-transitory Decline in Quality? SSNDQ test Example: would a monopolist in search find it profitable to change to induce changes to the search engine results page (SERP) that increase monetisation of the page at the expense of showing information less relevant to the users query. Or will that be defeated by consumers switching? 6

The SSNDQ thought experiment is clear, but. Implementation is fraught with difficulties: Avoiding the Cellophane fallacy requires a benchmark for the competitive level of quality difficult when static concentration is high e.g. due to network effects How small is small but significant in quality? What is a 5-10% decrease? Quality is complicated and not easily measured: may be possible to come up with some metric for loss of relevance in search, but what about operating systems, social networks? No clean variation in quality over time. Price shocks and consumers reactions are key in SSNIP tests, but quality shocks? Rarely discrete changes and, when they are, often confounded (e.g. OS updates at same time as hardware changes) 7

Challenge 2: Substitution between competing business models Digital products do not neatly replace one another. Consumers goals may be achieved through combinations of services which differ in their technical characteristics, vertical structure and monetisation strategy Analysis cannot restrict attention ex ante only to competition within a format or at each level of this stack of services Even a monopolist on a single component of the stack is constrained by the alternatives if consumers have very different ways to achieve the same goal (But very broad definitions are not the solution either! *) * e.g. Google have pointed to fact that a large proportion of consumers shopping online begin their search at Amazon, not Google. This does not tell us anything about the substitution patterns of those who do use Google and hence the competitive constraints Google faces 8

Example: separate market for OTAs? Online travel agents = searching + comparing + booking on the same site. Is it a market? OTA search META travel search Germany: OTAs only (no metasearch) France/Sweden: OTAs only Italy: online booking, OTAs main relevance? META travel search Google Hotel Finder Hotel website OTA search Hotel website OTA search Hotel website Google Maps & Search Hotel website Cannot assume integrated offer unconstrained by dis-integrated offers: consumers implicitly multi-home and this changes the competitive interaction

Examples: music, books, audio-visual content Audio-visual Music Books Subscription Download/ transactional Linear (broadcast) Subscription Download In-store Subscription Download In-store Different markets for download vs subscription services? Subscription is priced to compete with download, but again: hard to do substitution analysis around price responses Price structures difficult to compare. Highly non-linear pricing, embedded in complex structures. Zero prices for some products Price variation is not often there to do the analysis properly

How to approach this? (Ideally) Intricate pattern of substitution and complementarities! Might want to create a taxonomy of potential routes for consumers: navigation through this overall process is the product that consumers are interested in Then attempt to trace the substitution patterns in response to a quality reduction at each level of the stack, and form a view on whether a hypothetical monopolist at this level would have enough power to justify a separate market. While this is not a straightforward task, the alternative to grappling with this conceptual framework is likely to be excessively narrow markets 11

Challenge 3: Two-sidedness & competition for platform engagement Ad-funded Platforms set low/zero prices for users with aim to attract eyeballs of interest to advertisers and package them into tradable demographics So even if different platforms do different things for consumers, they all want to generate interest and increase engagement on consumer side to get advertising Competition for advertising. As long as consumers multi-home, even very different services (e.g. Youtube and Facebook) are in competition for advertisers But is there also broader competition for attention? Advertiser-side competition may understate competitive interaction if even v different sites are competing with oneanother for consumer attention/engagement. (David Evans: presumption that attention seekers compete with each other, at least to some degree, across even broadly defined products and service categories ) Don t go overbroad: but still need to understand new type of substitutability that is generated by the interaction of product and platform substitutability 12

2. The wrong default: falling back on functional definitions of markets 13

Functional definitions are simple to apply but misleading Complexity in applying substitutability-based approaches means the default becomes a functionality-based approach: pointing to differences in the set of functions offered and business models as evidence for separate markets Example: horizontal search engines, e.g. Google and Bing, crawl the whole internet for information while vertical search engines, e.g. Tripadvisor, Kelkoo or Yelp, use different approaches to gathering the information they display to users (structured datasets on specific topics). vs Example: meta search services like Trivago don t offer final purchase functionality so OTAs are deemed distinct because they are the only service which provides a single destination to search, compare and book. => Functional differences are a source of differentiation but do not in themselves show lack of substitutability vs 14

Is app-based ride sharing a separate market? Ordering via app Drivers as contractors Aggregator rather than integrated model Is ride sharing a separate market to traditional taxis and public transport? A functionality-based approach to ride sharing will likely lead to a narrow market definition But, this is a case where our price-based toolkit is available and empirical evidence points to broader substitution patterns Introduction of London s all-night subway service led to far fewer Uber trips from central stations Material reduction in the volume of Uber trips beginning at central locations is consistent with consumers substituting from Uber to public transport when the latter is more easily available Consistent with other evidence (e.g. surveys) 15

App-based ride sharing (2) When ridesharing services were launched at Los Angeles s LAX Airport, ridesharing trip volumes increased post entry by substantially more than any reduction in traditional taxi pick-ups No contemporaneous changes in volume of flight or passenger arrivals over the period. Hence the growth in ridesharing relative to the decline in traditional taxis must reflect consumers switching from other transport modes 16

3. What type of evidence can be brought to bear? 17

Possible types of evidence to assess substitution Use of experimental changes in quality Hard to identify clean changes in quality and measure their implications, plus reverse causality problem Sometimes possible to introduce deliberate and measurable distortions e.g. in search results shown to users, and gauge impact on consumer behaviour Indirect quantitative evidence of market power Do consumers tend to be set in their ways, using only a single route to find relevant information rather than habitually using a range of services? Do consumers display habit-forming behaviours so the ability to serve one category of query confers an ability to divert traffic in relation to other queries? Survey evidence based on proxied quality changes Questions on reaction to concrete changes in functionality, or the value users place on certain characteristics 18

4. Pros and Cons : should we give it up? 19

Should we persist with market definition in the digital age, or abandon it in favour of a more holistic approach? Pros Need for legal certainty: requiring a finding of dominance on a specificallydefined market is an important screen Discipline to consider constraints systematically Cons At best a distraction and at worst a straightjacket (analogy: see contortions of welfare assessment in payment cards) Constrains and biases formulation of theories of harm: focus on defining separate markets because this is perceived as a sine qua non for preferred theories of harm e.g. leveraging Rather than focussing on arcane questions of what is in our out better use of time and resources likely to be assessing actual extent of market power and effects 20

Example: Android case and the role of Apple Theory of harm: Google uses market power granted by its app store (Google Play) to make its installation contingent on also setting Google Search as default making it more difficult for others to enter BUT Is Google Play dominant? Complication: next largest app store (Apple s) uses a different business model: not licensed to OEMs but part of Apple s walled garden, access with iphone => INDIRECT CONSTRAINT Does it matter? Binary question of whether Apple is in or out of the market is tangential: ultimate issue is whether Google has enough power to extract concessions from OEMs that result in anticompetitive foreclosure Evidence one would bring to bear is similar, but focussing on TOH seems in many cases more productive. 21

London Tel +44 (0)20 7664 3700 8 Finsbury Circus London EC2M 7EA United Kingdom Brussels Tel +32 (0)2 627 1400 143 Avenue Louise B-1050 Brussels Belgium Lyon Tel +33 1 70 38 52 78 3 place Giovanni Da Verrazzano 69009 Lyon France Munich Tel +49 89 20 18 36 36 0 Palais Leopold, Leopoldstraße 8-12 80802 München Germany Sydney Tel +61 (0)406 820 214 Level 22, Tower 2 101 Grafton Street Bondi Junction NSW 2022 Australia Paris Tel +33 (0)1 70 38 52 78 27 Avenue de l Opéra 75001 Paris France www.crai.com/ecp 22