Input to public consultation on ENERGY MARKET DESIGN

Similar documents
EUGINE CONTRIBUTION TO THE EC PUBLIC CONSULTATION ON ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN

We appreciate your feedback

Delivering a flexible, resilient and secure market: IOGP response to the proposal on Power Market Design

RED II Trilogue Negotiations. eurelectric recommendations

Corporate Sourcing of Renewable Energy Cillian O Donoghue, Climate & Energy Manager, Eurometaux - European Non-Ferrous Metals Association

Delivering the internal market in electricity and making the most of public interventions

Vattenfall response to: ACER pre-consultation Energy Regulation: a bridge to 2025

BUSINESSEUROPE views on the review of the Energy Efficiency Directive

European Power sector s perspective on the role of the EU ETS

15 December Message to the Energy Council meeting on 18 December 2017

ERDF s response to ACER s public pre-consultation on «Energy Regulation: A bridge to 2025»

Identification pin : Energy regulation : a bridge to 2025 Answers of GDF SUEZ on the ACER preconsultation

Smart Grids, New Downstream & the New Deal for EU Electricity Consumers

Our position. Corporate power purchasing of renewable energy and the Clean Energy Package

FUTURE-PROOF THE ELECTRICITY MARKET DESIGN

Questions and answers on 2030 framework on climate and energy

EFET proposed amendments to draft instruments within the Clean Energy Package VARIOUS THEMES

An input from the European Solar Thermal Industry Federation (ESTIF) to the consultation on A 2030 framework for climate and energy policies

Mr Dennis Hesseling, Head of Gas Department, ACER Mr Fernando Hernández, Chair, ACER Electricity Working Group

Rethinking state aid for environmental protection. Paul Dawson EFET 12 April 2013

Innovative business models making use of the flexibility of the industrial electricity demand for integrating wind energy

Placing competitiveness at the heart of the Energy Package. 7 March, 2017

To the European Commission EU consultation on State aid for environmental protection

CBI Response to BEIS Call for Evidence

Council conclusions on Energy 2020: A Strategy for competitive, sustainable and secure energy

Energy policy at the crossroads. Finding the road to a competitive, low carbon and energy efficient Europe

CLEAN ENERGY PACKAGE

Energy Norway response to the ERGEG consultation on the Framework guidelines on Capacity Calculation and Congestion Management for Electricity

Responses to: ACER public consultation on the influence of existing bidding zones on electricity markets

Introduction: from regulated to liberalized markets in electricity

Energy and Environmental State aid Guidelines Frequently asked questions

ACER call for comments on the Network Code Emergency and Restoration

The Clean Energy package. Position of the Austrian electricity industry

Presentation based on study for IEA RETD

About Energy UK. Introduction

Better Policies Accelerate Clean Energy Transition

CEOs OF LEADING EUROPEAN ENERGY COMPANIES CONTRIBUTION TO THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL, MARCH 2014

PHOTOVOLTAIC OBSERVATORY POLICY RECOMMENDATIONS 2011

Generation Adequacy. Generation Adequacy. market measures to secure it and methodology for assessment

The French capacity market: lessons learnt and way forward

COMMISSION STAFF WORKING DOCUMENT EXECUTIVE SUMMARY OF THE IMPACT ASSESSMENT. Accompanying the document

What Are the Stakes of the EU beyond COP21?

Market Design Initiative

- Position Paper - Europex reactions to the CEER study on the Future Role of Gas

Driving Efficient Ecological Transformation in Europe

EUROCHAMBRES response to the European Commission s Consultation on the Green Paper on a 2030 framework for climate and energy policies

DEVELOPMENTS IN ELECTRIFICATION AND IMPLICATIONS FOR THE EUROPEAN ELECTRIC INDUSTRY EU PERSPECTIVE

EFET Response to EC Consultation on. Structural Options to Strengthen the EU Emissions Trading System. 28 th February 2013

Mergers: Commission clears proposed merger between Telefónica Deutschland (Telefónica) E-Plus subject to conditions-frequently asked questions

Written Statement by Mark Higson for the German Parliamentary Committee on Economic Affairs and Energy hearing (17 June 2015) on:

Commercialisation of Energy Storage in Europe. Nikolaos Lymperopoulos, Project Manager

POSITION ON GENERATION ADEQUACY, CAPACITY MECHANISMS AND THE INTERNAL MARKET IN ELECTRICITY

Operational and technical challenges for D3: Lessons from FENIX

The EU energy targets leading to 2050, the transition to a low-carbon economy and the role of energy regulation

U N I T E D N A T I O N S. Joint Statement

EWEA response on the CEER consultation on regulatory aspects of the integration of wind generation in European electricity markets

Challenges for Renewable Energy Finance

Energy Regulation: A Bridge to 2025 Conclusions Paper September 2014

Queensland Renewable Energy Expert Panel Issues Paper

CEER workshop on Wind integration. Marcel Cailliau Chairman of TF Integration of RES EURELECTRIC

ENTSO-E RECOMMENDATIONS TO HELP ACHIEVE EUROPE S ENERGY AND CLIMATE POLICY OBJECTIVES

POLICY GUIDELINES by the Energy Community Secretariat

Options for 2030 infrastructure targets

COMMENTS ON ERGEG POSITION PAPER ON SMART GRIDS

Introduction and Key Messages from the DG-GRID project

Fortum s policy messages. April 2015

Business Rules. Incremental Proposal

The Internal Energy Market

Engineering, Economics and Regulation of the Electric Power Sector TERM PAPERS

1. How can Ofgem ensure that sharper Cash Out incentives from the Significant Code Review:

Guidelines for implementation of transitional peak load arrangements. Proposal of Nordel

EURELECTRIC s views on effective capacity allocation and congestion management. Market European Stakeholder Committee Ljubljana, 11 May 2016

Consultation on revision of the EU Emission Trading System (EU ETS) Directive

Electricity Market Design Principles

Consultation on revision of the EU Emission Trading System (EU ETS) Directive

A European Electricity Market Design Fit for the Energy Transition

1. First of all, the CREG analysed the way in which the market operates. Its conclusions are as follows:

Regulatory challenges in developed markets

Regulatory Workshop on Regional Electricity Trade and Market Development Hanoi, Vietnam

Unlocking Investment in a changing Power Sector. Anne Malorie Géron Vice-President European Affairs Third EFORIS event, Stockholm, 23 November 2017

(Non-legislative acts) REGULATIONS

AmCham EU s response to Framework 2030 for Energy and Climate

GEODE Amendments Proposals to the European Commission Directive on the internal market for electricity

ANEC/BEUC JOINT POSITION CONSUMER EXPECTATIONS ON THE ACTION PLANS ON SUSTAINABLE CONSUMPTION AND PRODUCTION AND ON SUSTAINABLE INDUSTRIAL POLICY

EU electricity markets: one of a kind?

BUSINESSEUROPE S VIEWS ON ELECTRICITY MARKET REGULATION

Consultation on the Notice on the notion of State aid. A EURELECTRIC response paper

Integration of Renewable Energy Sources in the Electricity System - Grid Issues -

Concept note: Energy regulators contribution to fight climate change

European transmission tariff structures Cambridge Economic Policy Associates

Efficient regime for the expansion of renewable energies, further development of the energy-only market and preservation of EU-ETS

Quo vadis EU gas market regulatory framework Study on a Gas Market Design for Europe

Seminar on African Electrical Interconnection. Module 7 - Market Operational Structures

The Need for a 2030 Renewable Energy Binding Target

European Commission DG Energy Unit B2: Wholesale markets, electricity & gas Office: DM24, 6th floor Rue De Mot 24 B 1049 Brussels/Belgium

Levelling the Playing Field for Nuclear Make or Break

Recommendations for guiding principles for the development of integrated offshore cross border infrastructure

EUROPEAN COMMISSION Competition DG. Environmental and Energy Aid Guidelines CONSULTATION PAPER

EFFECTIVE REGULATORY REGIMES AS A REQUIREMENT FOR RENEWABLE ENERGY DEVELOPMENT. Zambia Lusaka August 7 to

Clean Energy for all Europeans

Transcription:

Brussels, Oktober 2015 Input to public consultation on ENERGY MARKET DESIGN by Eurometaux, EU Transparency Register n 61650796093-48 Eurometaux supports the Commission's goal to establish a European wide electricity market, in order to facilitate competition between suppliers, unhindered flows of electricity across borders and thus give real choice to, and reduce costs for consumers in particular for electro intensive industries. Future electricity market design should incorporate: One main EU target are affordable energy prices for all. New electricity market design s top priority should be affordable prices ensuring competitiveness sideways with a coherent and consistent holistic climate and energy policy: absolutely essential are policy framework conditions which remain predictable and stable over the longer term. Reinforcing the competitiveness of European industry and securing international competitiveness is of paramount importance. Revision of the Emission Trading System (ETS) should enable a cost-efficient transition towards a low-carbon economy. This is conditional upon improved and predictable pan- European compensation measures for CO2 costs in the electricity prices for globally competing industries, exposed to carbon leakage risk. New electricity market design should follow market-based principles. In this respect regional power markets can play a key role as "stepping stones" in approaching such an EU-wide electricity market (e.g. Nordic electricity market, German-Austrian power market) Subsidies for the deployment of renewable energy production should be temporary, transparent and technology neutral. Any potential future (transitional) renewable support scheme should ensure full exemption to electricity intensive industry competing globally. Capacity mechanisms represent a significant regulatory intervention. As such it is crucial that Member states and the European Commission work to ensure that other options are exhausted before capacity mechanisms are pursued. Non-ferrous metals industries are baseload consumers, with predictable uptake of electricity and therefore not a cause of intermittency in the system. Consequently NFM should be exempted to contribute to any (potential) capacity mechanism.

Market design for demand response must be developed regionally, in close cooperation with stakeholders. Reward must reflect real value of flexibility, and incentivize use of existing capacity which in the long run will give the highest benefit at lowest cost. As seen from the consumer side, there are increased costs and increased risks that have to be compensated. Voluntary long term contracts are one of the appropriate tools to give sufficient incentives to investors. Competition rules should allow all players to conclude this type of contracts and all regulatory barriers should be removed. Long term contracts can be desirable in order to provide investment certainty and financing for new generation capacity (large scale projects). FURTHER ELABORATION ON THE SPECIFIC QUESTIONS: Question 5: Are long-term contracts between generators and consumers required to provide investment certainty for new generation capacity? What barriers, if any, prevent such long-term hedging products from emerging? Is there any role for the public sector in enabling markets for long term contracts? Long term contracts (LTC) are required as they provide predictability of electricity price levels to the consumer and to the power generator: Non-ferrous metals installations are major customers to the power generator. With its single point of delivery, a very high installed capacity, the installations run 24 hours a day and 365 days per year. They absorb a high share of power production units, reducing significantly the generator s exposure to fluctuating consumption on the long run. LTCs also provide predictable income to the generator, with some guarantees. While majority of nonferrous metals commodities are electro-intensive industries, they are also a critical enabler for GHG emissions target reduction (low carbon footprint, high recyclability rates and unique material performance for buildings, automotive, RES and aerospace sectors). Power represents 30% to 50% of the overall operation costs for these installations. Long-term contracts and predictable electricity prices is therefore critical factor for today s and future competitiveness of these sectors. Energy costs are the main localization and investment factor. In our business model, the level of investment is directly linked to the duration and predictability of the power contract. Significant investments are amortized over the long run, typically between 15 and 25 years, just like in the energy sector.

In the current context, some barriers do exist to the conclusion of long term contracts: The electricity wholesale market is too shallow to provide the long term price signal, on the time horizon necessary for these investments to occur and for the volume of electricity at stake for each nonferrous metals producer. Power price forecasts are highly influenced by CO2 price assumptions and other electricity regulated costs such as renewables support schemes and electricityrelated taxes. Uncertainty regarding fragmented and ineffective carbon compensation schemes and other regulatory costs (i.e. levels of payments for grid costs, renewables fees and other taxes) are major barriers in the discussion of long term contracts between smelters and power generators. o Therefore, to ensure the viability and allow major investments in our industry, the public sector has a role to enable long term contracts: The energy market design reform should envisage the possibility to promote voluntary long-term electricity contracts at a competitive price as they make good business sense for the generator and the consumer and facilitate the conditions to promote this practice. Furthermore, for this specific segment, the public sector should provide predictability beyond 15 to 20 years on support mechanisms that enable electrointensive industry remain globally competitive. This reform should also take into account that liquid financial forward markets will improve confidence among market participants, and support mid-term contract negotiations (5 to 10 years). Principle of freedom to negotiate voluntary long-term contracts in any EU wholesale market and alternative pricing based formulas should be encouraged at EU level. Optimal use of transmission network is vital. TSOs should not be encouraged to sell long term transmission rights, and in any case industry consumers must not bear the risk of TSOs potential loss from selling Transmission rights.

Question 8: Which obstacles, if any, would you see to fully integrating renewable energy generators into the market, including into the balancing and intraday markets, as well as regarding dispatch based on the merit order? Specific support schemes (if any) to achieve RES targets should be temporary, transparent and technology-neutral. All types of resources should be subject to the same network connection rules and operational market responsibilities. RES generation should bear the same technical requirements and charges for grid connection and network use as other generators. The European Commission should remove the priority of dispatch for RES technologies and, especially, incentives to produce and charge resulting costs for excess supplies when supply exceeds demand. Production in times of negative prices should not be economically viable for producers. Imbalance costs created by renewables must be borne by these assets. Furthermore, since intermittent renewable electricity is becoming an important part of the electricity supply in most Member states, it is important that renewable electricity is integrated into the electricity market, i.e. that RES-E operators act as much as possible like any other power producer as a market participant and responds to market signals and do not lead to market distortion. Question 10: Where do you see the main obstacles that should be tackled to kickstart demand- response (e.g. insufficient flexible prices, (regulatory) barriers for aggregators / customers, lack of access to smart home technologies, no obligation to offer the possibility for end customers to participate in the balancing market through a demand response scheme, etc.)? We are convinced that demand response will play a key role in the power system in the upcoming years. For this purpose, market rules should allow demand response to participate in all markets. As it should be the case for all technologies, demand response should only be triggered by market incentives. Allowing suppliers to offer cost-reflective, flexible price signals that reward consumers flexible consumption would be a key step forward. In order to ensure that customers can participate in demand response aggregation and do not face undue costs, a robust, transparent and equitable market design should be put in place. Finally, no subsidy should be allocated to explicit demand response programs in order to ensure a level playing field between all demand response providers. Demand response should be based on voluntary market participation. Any obligation to increase or reduce demand is arbitrary and cannot be introduced. The new market design must enable market based demand response through intraday- and balancing markets; or through specialised market mechanisms set

up by the system operators, or through agreements between industry; generators and/or the system operators. There is a need to remove any regulatory or market barriers (e.g disincentives vis-à-vis flexibility in grid tariff schemes). Market design for demand response must be developed regionally, in close cooperation with stakeholders. Reward must reflect real value of flexibility, and incentivize use of existing capacity which in the long run will give the highest benefit at lowest cost. As seen from the consumer side, there is increased cost and increased risk that has to be fully compensated.