Empirical Evidence on the Demand for Money

Similar documents
Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1

MONEY, CREDIT, AND FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY: REPLY TO PORTER AND OFFENBACHER

Reply to the Referees John J. Seater 15 April 2008

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

Supply of Money. William A. Barnett University of Kansas. July 14, 2006

Spring Macroeconomics, sixth edition, Andrew B. Abel and Ben S. Bernanke, Pearson/Addison- Wesley 2005.

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Supply of Money. William A. Barnett. 14. July 2006

Stylised monetary facts

Business Cycle Theory Revised: March 25, 2009

Has there been a structural improvement in US productivity?

Lecture 20 Phillips Curve Price Stickiness. Noah Williams

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Chapter 2--Observing and Explaining the Economy

DO CONSUMER CONFIDENCE INDEXES HELP FORECAST CONSUMER SPENDING IN REAL TIME? Dean Croushore. University of Richmond. January 2005

Learning Outcomes for Economics 332 Instructor: Thomas Dalton Term: Fall Overview of Expected Learning Outcomes:

New Zealand Economics Competition

RECENT EVIDENCE ON IMPROVED INVENTORY CONTROL: A QUARTERLY MODEL OF THE U.S. ECONOMY FOR THE PERIOD Sweidan, Osama D. *

UNIVERSITY OF MALTA THE MATRICULATION EXAMINATION ADVANCED LEVEL

Business Analysis for Engineers Prof. S. Vaidhyasubramaniam Adjunct Professor, School of Law SASTRA University-Thanjavur

On Macroeconomic Theories and Modeist

Fundamentals of Economics. 2 September Exam Paper. Time: 2.5 hours

ECON4100 ADVANCED ECONOMIC ANALYSIS Session 1

The Australian Business Cycle: A New View by Don Harding The Melbourne Institute. Comments by David Gruen * Reserve Bank of Australia

Oil Price Rise and the Great Recession of 2008

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory, 01/07/2003. A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

Commentary: Causes of Changing Earnings Inequality

THE RESPONSE OF FINANCIAL AND GOODS MARKETS TO VELOCITY INNOVATIONS: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION FOR THE US*

Forecasting Components of Consumption With Components of Consumer Sentiment

Business Cycle Facts

Volume URL: Chapter Title: Part One: Definition of Money, Introduction

Introductory Macroeconomics for Policy Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

File: Ch05; Chapter 5: Factor Endowments and the Heckscher-Ohlin Theory. Multiple Choice

Can Consumer Economic Sentiment Indicator Predict Consumption Expenditure in the Eurozone?

Lecture 18 The Keynesian Model. Noah Williams

ECO-401 Economics Online Quiz 5

A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

Revival of Legacy of Tooke and Gibson: Further Evidence and Implications for Monetary Policy

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

LESSON 9. Economic Fluctuations: Balancing Aggregate Demand and Supply

Behavioural Economics

THE CYCLICAL BEHAVIOR OF PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM SEVEN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Chapter 8. Business Cycles. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Business Cycle Facts

REPORT ON CANDIDATES WORK IN THE CARIBBEAN ADVANCED PROFICIENCY EXAMINATION MAY/JUNE 2008 ECONOMICS (REGION EXCLUDING TRINIDAD AND TOBAGO)

Money Demand Forecasting in Kenya: An Empirical Study of a Developing Sub-Saharan Economy.

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

AP Macroeconomics UNIT 1: WHAT IS ECONOMICS? LESSON 1: WHAT IS ECONOMICS?

Lecture 11: Real Business Cycles

UNIT 1: WHAT IS ECONOMICS?

Accounting Concept and Conventions

Consumer Confidence Surveys: Can They Help Us Forecast Consumer Spending in Real Time?

Literature Review: Long-Run Economic Growth

Current Inventory- Sales Relations

Cambridge International Examinations Cambridge International Advanced Subsidiary and Advanced Level. Published

Growth, Productivity, and Wealth in the Long Run

Imperfect Knowledge Expectations, Uncertainty Adjusted UIP and Exchange Rate Dynamics: A Comment

Fixed and flexible prices

Topics in Monetary Economics

Comments on Labor Market Flows in the Cross Section and Over Time

GE105 Engineering Economics and Cost Analysis

Volume Title: American Exports During Business Cycles, Volume URL:

CHAPTER 3. Economic Challenges Facing Contemporary Business

Part One. What Is Economics?

WHAT ABOUT MUNICIPAL STRATEGIC MANAGEMENT AND PERFORMANCE MEASUREMENT

Gross Domestic Product

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

web page: : Economics and Statistics, The Hebrew University

MERCHANDISING TRANSACTIONS: INTRODUCTION TO INVENTORIES AND CLASSIFIED INCOME STATEMENT

Agenda. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis, Part 3. Disequilibrium in the AD-AS model

Indicate whether the sentence or statement is True or False. Mark "A" if the statement is True or "B" if it is False.

THINKING LIKE AN ECONOMIST

Study Questions for George Reisman's Capitalism: A Treatise on Economics

DISSERTATION ABSTRACT. Essays on Economic Growth and Development: New Perspectives from Health, Education, and Wealth. Kei Hosoya

Government Debt and Demand for Money: A Cointegration Approach

Review Questions. The Own-Wage Elasticity of Labor Demand. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

The True Cause of Business Cycle

Copyright 2017 by the UBC Real Estate Division

ACCTG 533: Module 11: Performance Evaluation. [Slide Content]: Performance Evaluation. [Jeanne H. Yamamura]: Performance Evaluation.

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2012 series 9708 ECONOMICS

Chapter 1. Introduction

Successful marketing typically makes a product new and old at the same

The Influence of Monetary and Fiscal Policy on Aggregate Demand. Chapter 32

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

The Rational Expectations Hypothesis

Economics. Synopsis. 1. Economic Concepts, Issues and Tools. 2. An Overview of Economics. Sections. Learning Summary. Sections

SAMPLE. Table of Contents Higher Altitudes. in Economics. Unit 1: Introduction Chapter 1: What is Economics?

Was the Deflation of the Depression Anticipated? An Inference Using Real-time Data. Gabriel Mathy, American University 1

September 2006 REAL RIGIDITIES * David Romer University of California, Berkeley

Secular stagnation in historical perspective. Roger E. Backhouse and Mauro Boianovsky

INVESTIGATING THE STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND IN GHANA

Criticism of Indifference Curve Theory

Economic Resources. Chapter 19, Section 1. For use with textbook pages

ADVANCED SUBSIDIARY (AS) General Certificate of Education Economics Assessment Unit AS 2. The National Economy [AE121]

CASH FLOW IS KING WHITE PAPER

Transcription:

Appendix 2 to Chapter 19 Empirical Evidence on the Demand for Money Here we examine the empirical evidence on the two primary issues that distinguish the different theories of money demand and affect their conclusions about whether the quantity of money is the primary determinant of aggregate spending: Is the demand for money sensitive to changes in interest rates, and is the demand for money function stable over time? INTEREST RATES AND MONEY DEMAND James Tobin conducted one of the earliest studies on the link between interest rates and money demand using U.S. data. 1 Tobin separated out transactions balances from other money balances, which he called idle balances, assuming that transactions balances were proportional to income only, and idle balances were related to interest rates only. He then looked at whether his measure of idle balances was inversely related to interest rates in the period 1922 1941 by plotting the average level of idle balances each year against the average interest rate on commercial paper that year. When he found a clear-cut inverse relationship between interest rates and idle balances, Tobin concluded that the demand for money is sensitive to interest rates. 2 Additional empirical evidence on the demand for money strongly confirms Tobin s finding. 3 Does this sensitivity ever become so high that we approach the case of the liquidity trap in which monetary policy is ineffective? The answer is almost certainly no. Keynes suggested in The General Theory that a liquidity trap might occur when interest rates are extremely low. (However, he did state that he had never yet seen an occurrence of a liquidity trap.) 1 James Tobin, Liquidity Preference and Monetary Policy, Review of Economics and Statistics 29 (1947): 124 131. 2 A problem with Tobin s procedure is that idle balances are not really distinguishable from transactions balances. As the Baumol-Tobin model of transactions demand for money makes clear, transactions balances will be related to both income and interest rates, just like idle balances. 3 See David E. W. Laidler, The Demand for Money: Theories and Evidence, 4th ed. (New York: HarperCollins, 1993). Only one major study has found that the demand for money is insensitive to interest rates: Milton Friedman, The Demand for Money: Some Theoretical and Empirical Results, Journal of Political Economy 67 (1959): 327 351. He concluded that the demand for money is not sensitive to interest-rate movements, but as later work by David Laidler (using the same data as Friedman) demonstrated, Friedman used a faulty statistical procedure that biased his results: David E. W. Laidler, The Rate of Interest and the Demand for Money: Some Empirical Evidence, Journal of Political Economy 74 (1966): 545 555. When Laidler employed the correct statistical procedure, he found the usual result that the demand for money is sensitive to interest rates. In later work, Friedman has also concluded that the demand for money is sensitive to interest rates. 79

80 Appendix 2 to Chapter 19 Typical of the evidence demonstrating that the liquidity trap has never occurred is that of David Laidler, Karl Brunner, and Allan Meltzer, who looked at whether the interest sensitivity of money demand increased in periods when interest rates were very low. 4 Laidler and Meltzer looked at this question by seeing whether the interest sensitivity of money demand differed across periods, especially in periods such as the 1930s when interest rates were particularly low. 5 They found that there was no tendency for interest sensitivity to increase as interest rates fell in fact, interest sensitivity did not change from period to period. Brunner and Meltzer explored this question by recognizing that higher interest sensitivity in the 1930s as a result of a liquidity trap implies that a money demand function estimated for this period should not predict well in more normal periods. What Brunner and Meltzer found was that a money demand function, estimated mostly with data from the 1930s, accurately predicted the demand for money in the 1950s. This result provided little evidence in favor of the existence of a liquidity trap during the Great Depression period. The evidence on the interest sensitivity of the demand for money found by different researchers is remarkably consistent. Neither extreme case is supported by the data: The demand for money is sensitive to interest rates, but there is little evidence that a liquidity trap has ever existed. STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND If the money demand function, like Equation 4 or 6 in Chapter 19, is unstable and undergoes substantial unpredictable shifts, as Keynes thought, then velocity is unpredictable, and the quantity of money may not be tightly linked to aggregate spending, as it is in the modern quantity theory. The stability of the money demand function is also crucial to whether the Federal Reserve should target interest rates or the money supply (see Chapters 16 and 21). Thus it is important to look at the question of whether the money demand function is stable, because it has important implications for how monetary policy should be conducted. As our discussion of the Brunner and Meltzer article indicates, evidence on the stability of the demand for money function is related to the evidence on the existence of a liquidity trap. Brunner and Meltzer s finding that a money demand function estimated using data mostly from the 1930s predicted the demand for money well in the postwar period not only suggests that a liquidity trap did not exist in the 1930s, but also indicates that the money demand function has been stable over long periods of time. The evidence that the interest sensitivity of the demand for money did not change from period to period also suggests that the money demand function is stable, since a changing interest sensitivity would mean that the demand for money function estimated in one period would not be able to predict well in another period. By the early 1970s, the evidence using quarterly data from the postwar period strongly supported the stability of the money demand function when M1 was used as 4 David E. W. Laidler, Some Evidence on the Demand for Money, Journal of Political Economy 74 (1966): 55 68; Allan H. Meltzer, The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the Time Series, Journal of Political Economy 71 (1963): 219 246; Karl Brunner and Allan H. Meltzer, Predicting Velocity: Implications for Theory and Policy, Journal of Finance 18 (1963): 319 354. 5 Interest sensitivity is measured by the interest elasticity of money demand, which is defined as the percentage change in the demand for money divided by the percentage change in the interest rate.

Empirical Evidence on the Demand for Money 81 the definition of the money supply. For example, a well-known study by Stephen Goldfeld published in 1973 found not only that the interest sensitivity of M1 money demand did not undergo changes in the postwar period, but also that the M1 money demand function predicted extremely well throughout the postwar period. 6 As a result of this evidence, the M1 money demand function became the conventional money demand function used by economists. The Case of the Missing Money The stability of the demand for money, then, was a well-established fact when, starting in 1974, the conventional M1 money demand function began to severely overpredict the demand for money. Stephen Goldfeld labeled this phenomenon of instability in the demand for money function the case of the missing money. 7 It presented a serious challenge to the usefulness of the money demand function as a tool for understanding how monetary policy affects aggregate economic activity. In addition, it had important implications for how monetary policy should be conducted. As a result, the instability of the M1 money demand function stimulated an intense search for a solution to the mystery of the missing money so that a stable money demand function could be resurrected. The search for a stable money demand function took two directions. The first direction focused on whether an incorrect definition of money could be the reason why the demand for money function had become so unstable. Inflation, high nominal interest rates, and advances in computer technology caused the payments mechanism and cash management techniques to undergo rapid changes after 1974. In addition, many new financial instruments emerged and have grown in importance. This has led some researchers to suspect that the rapid pace of financial innovation since 1974 has meant that the conventional definitions of the money supply no longer apply. They searched for a stable money demand function by actually looking directly for the missing money; that is, they looked for financial instruments that have been incorrectly left out of the definition of money used in the money demand function. Overnight repurchase agreements (RPs) are one example. These are one-day loans with little default risk because they are structured to provide Treasury bills as collateral. (Chapter 2 gives a more detailed discussion of the structure of this type of loan.) Corporations with demand deposit accounts at commercial banks frequently lend out substantial amounts of their account balances overnight with these RPs, lowering the measures of the money supply. However, the amounts lent out are very close substitutes for money, since a corporation can quickly make a decision to decrease these loans if it needs more money in its demand deposit account to pay its bills. Gillian Garcia and Simon Pak, for example, found that including overnight RPs in measures of the money supply substantially reduced the degree to which money demand functions overpredicted the money supply. 8 More recent evidence using later data cast some doubt on whether including overnight RPs and other highly liquid assets in measures of the money supply produces money demand functions that are stable. 9 6 Stephen M. Goldfeld, The Demand for Money Revisited, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3 (1973): 577 638. 7 Stephen M. Goldfeld, The Case of the Missing Money, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 3 (1976): 683 730. 8 Gillian Garcia and Simon Pak, Some Clues in the Case of the Missing Money, American Economic Review 69 (1979): 330 334. 9 See the survey in John P. Judd and John L. Scadding, The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function, Journal of Economic Literature 20 (1982): 993 1023.

82 Appendix 2 to Chapter 19 The second direction of search for a stable money demand function was to look for new variables to include in the money demand function that will make it stable. Michael Hamburger, for example, found that including the average dividend price ratio on common stocks (average dividends divided by average price) as a measure of their interest rate resulted in a money demand function that is stable. 10 Other researchers, such as Heller and Khan, added the entire term structure of interest rates to their money demand function and found that this produces a stable money demand function. 11 These attempts to produce a stable money demand function have been criticized on the grounds that these additional variables do not accurately measure the opportunity cost of holding money, and so the theoretical justification for including them in the money demand function is weak. 12 Also, later research questions whether these alterations to the money demand function will lead to continuing stability in the future. 13 Velocity Slowdown in the 1980s The woes of conventional money demand functions increased in the 1980s. We have seen that they overpredicted money demand in the middle and late 1970s; that is, they underpredicted velocity (PY/M), which rose faster than expected. The tables turned beginning in 1982; as can be seen in Figure 1 in Chapter 19, economists now faced a surprising slowdown in M1 velocity, which conventional money demand functions also could not predict. Although researchers have tried to explain this velocity slowdown, they have not been entirely successful. 14 M2 to the Rescue? As we saw in Figure 1, M2 velocity remained far more stable than M1 velocity in the 1980s. The relative stability of M2 velocity suggests that money demand functions in which the money supply is defined as M2 might perform substantially better than those in which the money supply is defined as M1. Researchers at the Federal Reserve found that M2 money demand functions performed well in the 1980s, with M2 velocity moving quite closely with the opportunity cost of holding M2 (market interest rates minus an average of the interest paid on deposits and financial instruments that make up M2). 15 However, in the early 1990s, M2 growth underwent a dramatic slowdown, which some 10 Michael Hamburger, Behavior of the Money Stock: Is There a Puzzle? Journal of Monetary Economics 3 (1977): 265 288. The stability of his money demand function also depends on his assumption that the income elasticity of the demand for money is unity. This assumption has been strongly criticized by many critics, including R. W. Hafer and Scott E. Hein, Evidence on the Temporal Stability of the Demand for Money Relationship in the United States, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review (1979): 3 14, who find that this assumption is strongly rejected by the data. 11 H. Heller and Moshin S. Khan, The Demand for Money and the Term Structure of Interest Rates, Journal of Political Economy 87 (1979): 109 129. 12 Frederic S. Mishkin, Discussion of Asset Substitutability and the Impact of Federal Deficits, in The Economic Consequences of Government Deficits, ed. Laurence H. Meyer (Boston: Kluwer-Nijhoff, 1983), pp. 117 120; Frederic S. Mishkin, Discussion of Recent Velocity Behavior: The Demand for Money and Monetary Policy, in Monetary Targeting and Velocity (San Francisco: Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, 1983), pp. 129 132. 13 This research is discussed in Judd and Scadding (note 9). 14 See, for example, Robert H. Rasche, M1 Velocity and Money-Demand Functions: Do Stable Relationships Exist? Empirical Studies of Velocity, Real Exchange Rates, Unemployment, and Productivity, Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 17 (Autumn 1987), pp. 9 88. 15 See David H. Small and Richard D. Porter, Understanding the Behavior of M2 and V2, Federal Reserve Bulletin 75 (1989): 244 254.

Empirical Evidence on the Demand for Money 83 researchers believe cannot be explained by traditional money demand functions. 16 In the late 1990s, M2 velocity seemed to settle down, suggesting a more normal relationship between M2 demand and macroeconomic variables. However, doubts continued to arise about the stability of money demand. 17 Conclusion The main conclusion from the research on the money demand function seems to be that the most likely cause of its instability is the rapid pace of financial innovation occurring after 1973, which has changed what items can be counted as money. The evidence is still somewhat tentative, however, and a truly stable and satisfactory money demand function has not yet been found. And so the search for a stable money demand function goes on. The instability of the money demand function calls into question whether our theories and empirical analyses are adequate. 18 It also has important implications for the way monetary policy should be conducted because it casts doubt on the usefulness of the money demand function as a tool to provide guidance to policymakers. In particular, because the money demand function has become unstable, velocity is now harder to predict, and as discussed in Chapter 16, setting rigid money supply targets in order to control aggregate spending in the economy is not seen as an effective way to conduct monetary policy. 16 See, for example, Bryon Higgins, Policy Implications of Recent M2 Behavior, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review (Third Quarter 1992): 21 36. For a contrary view, see Robert L. Hetzel, How Useful Is M2 Today, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review (September October 1992): 12 26. 17 For example, see Kelly Ragan and Bharat Trehan, Is It Time to Look at M2 Again? Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic Letter #98-07 (March 6, 1998). 18 Thomas F. Cooley and Stephen F. Le Roy, Identification and Estimation of Money Demand, American Economic Review 71 (1981): 825 844, is especially critical of the empirical research on the demand for money.