FACTORS THAT DETERMINE THE STATED WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR AIR POLLUTION: A CASE OF BOPHELONG TOWNSHIP

Similar documents
Consumers short- and long-term response to mad cow : beef consumption and willingness-to-pay for organic beef in Italy

Predicted vs. Estimated Welfare Measures: A Test of the Benefits Transfer Method 1

NON-MARKET VALUATION OF RURAL TOURISM IN YOGYAKARTA, INDONESIA

The Contingent Valuation Method for Thessaloniki s Aesthetic Pollution in Greece

Does Benefit Transfer Always Work: a Multi-country Comparison. Hala Abou-Ali A. Mohammed Belhaj B

Willingness to Pay for Offsetting Carbon Programs by Vehicle Owners in Sunsari District, Nepal

Topics in Labor Supply

China Economic Review

A Note on Risk Aversion and Labour Market Outcomes: Further Evidence from German Survey Data

Extending the methods for measuring impact and welfare effects of tourism

Contingent Valuation Method and Carbon Tax in Mitigating CO2 Emissions from Road Transport Sector: A Literature Review

Estimating Recreation Value of Darband Area in Tehran (Iran)

Investigation of Citizens' WTP for Mashhad Air Pollution Reduction: Applying Heckit model

Valuing Community Based Forest Landscapes Restoration: Bivariate Probit Analysis for Degraded Forest Lands in North Western Ethiopia

Measuring the indirect costs associated with the establishment of a wind farm: An application of the Contingent Valuation Model

Categorical Data Analysis

Preferences for Energy Efficiency vs. Renewables: How Much Does a Ton of CO 2 Emissions Cost?

ESTIMATING TOURISTS' ECONOMIC VALUES OF PUBLIC BEACH ACCESS POINTS

Modelling and Empirical Analysis for Outsourcing Agricultural Services to Control Pests and Diseases

Households Choice of Drinking Water Sources in Malawi

Economic Valuation Methods for Efficient Water Resources Management: Theory and Applications

An Economic Evaluation of a Wind Power Electricity Generating Farm in South Africa

Value of a statistical life estimation of carcinogenic chemicals for socioeconomic analysis in Korea

Ibrahim Consumer Willingness to Pay a Premium for Halal Goat Meat 73 halal goat meat. The multiple bounded model was the appropriate model because it

THE ROLE OF OLSON S INTEREST GROUPS THEORY IN EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENT LEVEL OF AGRICULTURAL SUPPORT IN COUNTRIES WITH DIFFERENT DEVELOPMENT LEVEL 1

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Environmental Sciences 30 (2015 )

VALUING THE ENVIRONMENT

A study on determining the awareness level and attitudes of households on water pollution: The case of Erzurum City

Private Returns to Education in Greece: A Review of the Empirical Literature

Willingness to Pay for Drinking Water Supply in Vavuniya UC Area

Valuing informal care an overview. Bernard van den Berg

Adapting to climate change: Are people willing to pay or change?

The economic value of improved air quality in urban Africa: a contingent valuation survey in Douala, Cameroon

The methods to estimate the monetary value of the environment

Clean Air Health Benefits from Climate Change Mitigation Action George D. Thurston

Chapter 2 Tools of Positive Analysis

Contingent Valuation: Using Surveys to Elicit Information about Costs and Benefits

An Analysis of Factors that Influence the Income of Poor Women: A Research Survey in Ho Chi Minh City of Vietnam

Willingness to Pay for Drinking Water Quality Improvements

An Empirical Estimation of Energy Poverty in Poor South African Households

The Theoretical Structure of. Producer Willingness to Pay Estimates

CONSUMER CONFIDENCE ON FOOD SAFETY INSTITUTIONS IN KOSOVO WHETHER IT INFLUENCES DAIRY CONSUMER S WILLINGNESS TO PAY?

The Cost-Benefit Analysis of the Improvement of Water Quality of the. Paldang Reservoir in Korea.

An empirical estimation of energy poverty in poor South African households

Morningness-evenigness pay gap in creative R&D jobs

Biodiversity, Ecosystem Conservation and Poverty Reduction: A Contingent Valuation Approach in Grande Riviere

Factors Influencing Credit Default: A Case Study of Maize Farmers in the Asante Akim North District of Ashanti Region

Work package 6 - Deliverable 9

CONSUMER WILLINGNESS-TO-PAY FOR A SALINE FISH SPECIES GROWN IN THE MIDWEST: THE CASE OF STRIPED BASS. Dept. of Agricultural Economics

Eco311, Final Exam, Fall 2017 Prof. Bill Even. Your Name (Please print) Directions. Each question is worth 4 points unless indicated otherwise.

CHAPTER-V EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF SOLID WASTE MANAGEMENT BY USING CONTINGENT VALUATION METHOD

Estimation of Willingness to Pay for Virtual Reality Theme Park

MARRIAGE, CHILD BEARING AND THE PROMOTION OF WOMEN TO MANAGERIAL POSITIONS i

4.12 Private Provision of Public Goods: Experiments Testing Free Rider Behavior 4.7 OPTIMAL PROVISION OF PRIVATE GOODS

Never Smokers Exposure Case Control Yes No

FAIR TAX - EUROPE S WAY TO ECONOMIC GROWTH AND SOCIAL EQUALITY

The Impact of E-Commerce and GDP on the Revenue of One. Rezarta Zhaku-Hani, Lirinda Vako Abedini

PAY EQUITY AN ECONOMIC PERSPECTIVE CHEN SONG, PH.D. - JULY 2018

Project Tatirano (Phase II): Improving access to clean drinking water via rainwater harvesting in the Anosy Region, southeast Madagascar

Bundling Products with Decreasing Value: Evidence from the US Cable Television Industry

Environmental Economics Lecture on topics in valuation of environmental goods. Jon Strand February 15, 2017

Efficiency, Firm-size and Gender: The Case of Informal Firms in Latin America

Long-term exposure to gaseous air pollutants and cardio-respiratory mortality in Brisbane, Australia

The study obtains the following results: Homework #2 Basics of Logistic Regression Page 1. . version 13.1

JUVRE MEADOW - AN ECONOMIC ANALYSIS. Line Block Christoffersen

Economic Value of Groundwater Protection in the Mekong Delta. Vo Thanh Danh

The Effect of Service Guarantees on Online Customers Purchase Intention

RESOURCE RECOVERY & REUSE SERIES: SPECIAL ISSUE

Industrial organisation and procurement in defence firms: An economic analysis of UK aerospace markets.

A COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS ON THE SERVICE QUALITY PERCEPTIONS OF PHILIPPINE COMMERCIAL BANKS

Households Willingness to Pay for Improved Rural Water Service Provision: Application of Contingent Valuation Method in Eastern Ethiopia

Estimation of the Marginal Rate of Return and Supply Functions for Schooling: The Case of Egypt

External Costs to Parties Involved in Highway Traffic Accidents: The Perspective of Highway Users

Using Contingent Valuation Method to Explore Willingness to Pay for Electricity and Water Service Attributes

ENVIRONMENTAL VALUATION: STATED PREFERENCE METHODS

Climate Change and Recreation Benefits in an Alpine National Park

EVALUATING SOLID WASTE MANAGEMENT SYSTEM IN PAKISTAN: A Regional Analysis. Usama Ehsan KHAN,* Shabbir AHMED** and Ambreen FATIMA*** Abstract

Public Economics by Luca Spataro. Market failures: Externalities (Myles ch. 10. sections 4.4, 5, 7.2 & 7.3 excluded)

The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies

Supplementary Information. S1. Selective Literature Review. S1.1 Exposure-Response Coefficients. S1.2 Health Costs Assessment

Researchers Lauren Knapp M.S. Yiting Li M.S. Yufeng Ma M.S., M.A.E. Matthew Rife M.S. Co-Authors Jarod Kelly, Ph.D. University of Michigan Craig

Econ 101, section 3, F06 Schroeter Exam #2, Red. Choose the single best answer for each question.

Class Agenda. Note: As you hand-in your quiz, pick-up graded HWK #1 and HWK #2 (due next Tuesday).

Estimating Arizona Residents Willingness to Pay to Invest in Research and Development in Solar Energy

Prateek Sangal Senior Economics Major 10/03/03 Testing the Relationship of Education to Income

Analysis of the Effects of Farmers Characteristics on Poverty Status in Delta State

ESTIMATING BIODIVERSITY VALUE OF EAST KOLKATA WETLAND IN WEST BENGAL -A CONTINGENT VALUATION APPROACH

Consumers Willingness to Pay for Biotech Foods in China

Abstract No A Study on Risk Perception toward Nuclear Power Operation in Taiwan

Reply to A comment on Three reasons to use annual payments in contingent valuation. April 2017

Esxon Publishers. International Journal of Applied Research and Technology ISSN

Valuing the Attributes of Renewable Energy Investment in Scotland

Supplementary Materials for

Contracts for environmental goods and the role of monitoring for landowners willingness to accept

VALUING WATER SUPPLY SERVICE IMPROVEMENTS IN ADDIS ABABA 1

Proposal. The Impact of Economic Recession on. Customer Loyalty to Banks

2. Objectives of the Study 2.1. General Objective The general objective of the study was to estimate use value of Ajora water fall recreational area.

12I. MAIN STAGE WILLINGNESS TO PAY. K WILLIS REVIEW

A Selectivity Model of Household Pork Consumption Behavior in Taipei, Taiwan

Suitability and Determinants of Agricultural Training Programs in Northern Ethiopia

Transcription:

FACTORS THAT DETERMINE THE STATED WILLINGNESS TO PAY FOR AIR POLLUTION: A CASE OF BOPHELONG TOWNSHIP Ismael Maloma North-West University, Vaal Triangle Campus, South Africa Mr E-mail: Ismael.maloma@nwu.ac.za Mmapula Brendah Sekatane North-West University, Vaal Triangle Campus, South Africa Dr E-mail: Brendah.sekatane@nwu.ac.za Abstract The aim of this paper is to quantify the willingness to pay for improved air-quality in a typical low-income settlement in South Africa by making use of the contingent valuation method (CVM). Direct valuation methods or stated preferences methods such as CVM are used to value goods that do not have a market value i.e. price-quantity data does not exist for such goods. The mean WTP to reduce air pollution in Bophelong is approximately R132 per annum. The econometric analysis found that most parameters had their expected sign. WTP was found to be positively correlated with employment status and income. Males were however, found to be less likely to have a positive WTP than their female counterparts. Household size was also found to be negatively correlated with WTP. Key Words: Pollution, Willingness to pay, Bophelong 1

JEL Classification: Q51, Q53 1. INTRODUCTION Pollution is defined as the introduction into the environment of substances or energy liable to cause hazards to human health, harm to living resources, and ecological systems, damage to structure or amenity, or interference with legitimate use of the environment (Kidd, 1997). In addition, the National Environmental Management Act 39 of 2004 defines air-pollution as any change in the composition of air caused by smoke, soot, dust (including fly ash), cinders, solid particles of any kind, gases, fumes, aerosols and odorous substances. Human beings exist in an environmental space. The environment offers a great deal of services to mankind; firstly, the environment acts as a form of a consumption good by offering services to humankind in the form of air to breath and space; secondly, the environment supply resources such as water, sun and oil; thirdly, the environment is a recipient for waste through the atmosphere, land and water and lastly, the environment acts as a geographical location for economic activities (Bella, 2003). Air pollution is regarded as a negative externality to production. Producers treat environmental goods such as air and water as free goods and consequently do not internalise them in their production processes. It is in this light that economists saw the need to develop theories that will force producers to be more responsible in the process of producing goods and services. Two main theories that deal with the issue of externalities and social cost are the Pigouvian theory and the Coasean theory. Pigou preferred government intervention to address the issue of market failure. Pigou s theory advocates for the levying of taxes to close the divergence that exist between marginal private net benefits and marginal social costs. Coase on the other hand was in favour of the market mechanism to deal with the issue of externality. The main thrust of his argument is that in cases where property rights are well defined and transaction costs are minimal, the market system will produce an optimal level of production regardless of who owns the property rights (Simpson, 1996). 2

The aim of this paper is to quantify the willingness to pay for improved air-quality in a typical low-income settlement in South Africa by making use of the contingent valuation method (CVM). Direct valuation methods or stated preferences methods such as CVM are used to value goods that do not have a market value i.e. price-quantity data does not exist for such goods (Brookshire & Crocker, 1981). The paper is structured as follows: Firstly, literature review, followed by the methodology used in the study. Thirdly the analysis of the data is done followed by concluding remarks. 2. LITERATURE REVIEW An increase in human production and consumption does lead to unintended negative consequences such as increased health risk and damage to the environment (Nas, 1993). There is therefore, a need for an adequate policy response to combat the health damage resulting from air pollution caused by human activities. Environmental economics provide economists with a variety of tools that can be used to value the environment. Before the introduction of the economic valuation tools environmental decisions were taken without quantifying the costs and benefits of the decisions. All the economic valuation techniques have strengths and weaknesses and each of them should therefore be used for a purpose for which it is most appropriate. One major criticism against environmental valuation is that some people find it wrong to attach a monetary value to environmental goods such as good air quality. Some kind of evaluation of the environment is, however, necessary because there is a need to timorously and systematically assess the consequences of an environmental decision (Rabi et al., 2007). Contingent valuation is a stated preference approach to valuation. This approach enquires about future behaviour by asking willingness to pay (WTP) and willingness to accept (WTA) type of questions (Todaro & Smith, 2006). This method is very useful in measuring the value of public goods. Under market conditions people are well informed and rational; the same behaviour is however not displayed when it comes to public goods (Hanemann, 1994). 3

The divergence between WTP and WTA can be described in terms of the compensating variation and the equivalent variation concepts. For a welfare gain the compensating variation is the amount that an individual is willing to pay to experience the welfare gain, whilst the equivalent variation refers to the amount of monetary income an individual is willing to accept in lieu of the improvement in welfare (Nas, 1996). For a welfare loss, the compensating variation refers to the amount of monetary income that an individual is willing to accept as compensation for the loss of welfare, whilst equivalent variation refers to the amount of monetary income that an individual is prepared to sacrifice to be exempted from the welfare loss or to prevent the welfare loss from occurring in the future (Nas, 1996). Thus in theory, there is not supposed to be any divergence between results measured using either WTP or WTA. Both methods are used to measure individuals willingness to pay and willingness to accept for a welfare change. Empirical studies have, however, shown that in most cases there is no convergence between WTP and WTA results (Vankatachalam, 2004). The divergence between WTP and WTA can be attributed to factors such as the existence of income and substitution effects, transaction costs and property rights. In empirical studies WTA values in most cases were found to be larger than WTP. Economists in general prefer the use of WTP over WTA, because WTA is considered not to be consistent with convergent validity as it does not adequately measure economic surplus (Vankatachalam, 2004). Hence this paper analyse the factors that determine the stated WTP for air pollution in Bophelong. 3. METHODOLOGY 3.1. SURVEY DESIGN Approximately 300 households were visited and personally interviewed by trained fieldworkers. Of the 300 households interviewed in the survey only 285 were analysed. Fifteen questionnaires were destroyed due to incompleteness, largely due to the reluctance of respondents to answer questions pertaining to income. This survey has to a large extent attempted to adhere to the steps and guidelines of conducting a Contingent valuations survey as outlined by Pope III and Miner (1988). Information was obtained mainly from the head of the household, spouse and children above the age of 18. The questionnaire made use of an open-ended 4

question to elicit respondents willingness to pay. Open-ended questions are deemed desirable as they generally manage to overcome the problem of starting point bias and secondly, they tend to provide a more conservative result as they tend to produce lower WTP than referendum type questions (Carlsson & Johansson-Stenman, 2000). The survey made use of probability sampling which is more statistically acceptable than convenience sampling. Face-to-face interviews were conducted at the homes of the respondents as home is the place where respondents are more likely to feel comfortable and are expected to provide well thought-out responses. 3.2. REGRESSION MODEL Binary choice models such as logistic and probit models are commonly used in environmental valuation studies to predict dichotomous outcomes. In this paper WTP is estimated using a regression analysis. The aim of a regression analysis is to determine the factors which cause the variation of the dependent variable namely, WTP. In this paper a basic OLS regression could not be used to estimate WTP since WTP is a censored dependent variable. Using a basic OLS regression would yield negative WTP values which would not make sense from a theoretical point of view. In assessing an individual s willingness to pay for the reduction of air-pollution the authors made use of an open-ended elicitation format wherein respondents could indicate if he/she is willing to pay for reduced air-pollution (i.e. yes or no answer) and how much he/she is willing to pay. WTP is regarded as a qualitative regress and i.e. a person is either willing to pay or not. The response variable can take only two values namely 1 if the person is willing to pay and 0 if not. As indicated above, the WTP variable is binary in nature. In order to analyse the dichotomous choices made by the respondents a logistic model was used as it was considered the most appropriate for this type of study. (Loureiro & Umberger). The logistic regression can be specified as follows: = ( ) = 1+ + + 1 5

Where: The logistic formula stated in terms of the probality that 1 if the household is willing to pay (p i ), and = 0 otherwise (1-p i ) Employment status of the head of household Gender of the head of household (Male = 1, Female = 0) Marital status of the head of household (Married = 1, Not Married = 0) Educational level of the head of household Household size number of people in the household Household income (monthly) Age of the head of household The error term that follows a logistic regression 4. ANALYSIS The mean WTP to reduce air pollution in Bophelong is approximately R132 per annum (the annual figure was obtained by multiplying the mean WTP of approximately R11 by the number of months in a year). The annual social cost of pollution in Bophelong can be calculated by multiplying the mean annual WTP with the estimated total population of Bophelong. Bophelong s population was estimated at 49 408 in 2009 (Slabbert & Sekhampu, 2009). The annual social cost of pollution in Bophelong is thus estimated at R6 521 856. The logistic regression model was evaluated using the Likelihood Ratio test which is operationalised using the Chi-Square. 6

Table 1: Log-Likelihood Ratio Test for the Logistic Regression Logistic regression Number of obs 274 LR chi2(7) 25.8 Prob > chi2 0.0005 Log likelihood = -161.27051 Pseudo R2 0.0741 Source: Calculated from Survey Data, 2012 Table 1 summaries the results of the log likelihood test. The Log likelihood was 161.27. The Log likelihood Ratio test as measured by the Chi-Square was 25.8 with a p-value of 0.0005. That means even at 1 percent, the null hypothesis that the model was not a good fit is rejected in favour of the alternative hypothesis that the model was a good fit. As Table 2 shows, the choice to have a willingness to pay or not, was found to be inelastic to changes in education levels. The elasticity between education and WTP for pollution in Bophelong was inelastic at -0.256. An increase in education by one unit however had the possibility of lowering the WTP as evidenced by the negative sign. Employment status was also inelastic in influencing the WTP for reduced air pollution in Bophelong. The employment status elasticity of WTP was 0.15; therefore, employment status could not be regarded as a very important factor that influences the level of WTP in the area. However, there was a positive elasticity meaning that those who were employed were more likely to have a positive WTP for reduced air pollution in Bophelong. 7

Table 2: Marginal Effects reporting elasticities ey/ex Std. Err. Z P> z [95% Conf. Interval] Education -0.25567 0.230419-1.11 0.267-0.70728 0.195946 Employment status 0.146747 0.07565 1.94 0.052-0.00152 0.295017 Sex -0.04969 0.124649-0.4 0.69-0.294 0.194617 Size of household -0.42625 0.247223-1.72 0.085-0.9108 0.058294 Income 0.0979 0.048435 2.02 0.043 0.002969 0.192831 Marital status -0.07518 0.141086-0.53 0.594-0.35171 0.201344 Age of head of household -0.7785 0.456018-1.71 0.088-1.67228 0.115278 Source: Calculated from Survey Data, 2012 The elasticity of WTP due to gender was estimated at -0.049. This implies that gender as represented by Sex in table 2 did not have any significant influence on the WTP. However, males were less likely to have a positive WTP than females since the sex elasticity of WTP for reduced air pollution was negative In the study by Carlsson and Johansson-Stenman (2000) the marginal effects for gender were found to be significant but with opposite signs. The reported marginal effects in the Carlsson and Johansson-Stenman (2000) study were -0.054, which implied that men have about 5 percentage units lower probability of a positive Willingness to Pay than women. Again the size of the household was also found to be inelastic although it was negative. Households with higher numbers of inhabitants were less likely to have a positive WTP compared to those with small members. The size of household elasticity of WTP for pollution was -0.426. The income elasticity of WTP was about 0.1 which was inelastic. Those with higher income levels however were more likely to have a positive WTP for pollution compared to those with lower levels of income. An elasticity coefficient of less than one is common in CVM studies for environmental goods. In the 8

Carlsson and Johansson-Stenman (2000) study the elasticity for income was calculated as 0.32. Marital Status also was inelastic and negative. Households whose head was married were less likely to have a positive WTP for reduced air pollution compared to those with single heads. Lastly, age of the head of household also was inelastic in influencing the WTP for pollution in Bophelong. This means that although the relationship was inelastic, older people were less likely to have a positive WTP compared to younger people. Wang and Mullahy (2006) also found that age has a negative relationship with the probability of a positive WTP, which implies that as age increases people s probability of having any positive Willingness to Pay for the reduction of air-pollution decreases. A similar study by Alberini et al. (1997) whose objective was to determine WTP for reducing fatal risk by improving air quality also found that age and WTP were inversely related. Another study by Tanrivermi (1998) on WTP and WTA measures in Turkey also found a negative correlation between age and WTP. 5. CONCLUSION This paper estimated WTP for the reduction of air pollution in Bophelong Township. The mean willingness-to-pay for the reduction of air pollution in Bophelong was estimated at R132 per annum. The regression analysis was performed making use of the more appropriate logistic model instead of the basic OLS regression model. The econometric analysis found that most parameters had their expected sign. WTP was found to be positively correlated with employment and income. Males were however, found to be less likely to have a positive WTP than their female counterparts. Household size was also found to be negatively correlated with WTP. The paper made use of the open-ended format because it did not want to overestimate the social cost of air-pollution in Bophelong Township. The openended elicitation format made use of a willingness to pay question rather than willingness to accept question. Firstly, a willingness to pay question generally yield lower estimates than willingness to accept because the willingness to pay is tied to the respondent s ability to pay which is not the case with willingness to 9

accept (Beder, 2005). Secondly willingness to pay may also be affected by various factors such as lack of information about the good being valued and opinion. For instance, many of those who indicated that they are not affected by air-pollution stated low willingness to pay bids as opposed to those who indicated otherwise. Lastly, with Bophelong Township being a low-income settlement it would be expected that the estimated willingness to pay would be lower as willingness to pay is a function of ability to pay. BIBLIOGRAPHY Alberini, A, Cropper, M, Tsu-Tan F, Krupnick, A, Jin-Tan-Liu, Shaw, D and Harrington, W, (1997), Valuing health effects of air-pollution in developing countries. Journal of environmental economics and management, Vol. 34, pp. 107-126. Beder, S, (2000), Costing the earth: Equity, sustainable development and environmental economics,.new Zealand journal of environmental law, Vol. 4, pp. 227-243. Bella, G, (2003), Does pollution affect economic growth?, Political economy of the environment, Italy: University of Cagliari. Brookshire, D.S, & Crocker, T.D. 1981.The advantages of contingent valuation methods for benefit-cost analysis.public choice, 36(2):235-252. Carlsson, F. and Johansson-Stenman, O, (2000), Willingness to pay for improved air quality in Sweden, Applied Economics, Vol. 32, No. 6, pp. 661-669. Hanemann, W.M, (1994), Valuing the environment through contingent valuation, The journal of economic perspectives, Vol. 8, No. 4, pp. 19-43 Kidd, M, (1997) Environmental law, Cape Town: Juta. Loureiro, M.J, and Umberger, W.J, (2003), Estimating consumer willingness to pay for country of origin labeling Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Vol. 28, No. 2, pp. 287-301. Nas, T.F, (1996), Cost-benefit analysis: Theory and application, London: Sage Publications. 10

Pope III, C.A, Burnett, R.T, Thun, M.J, Calle, E.E, Krewski, D, Ito, K. and Thurston, G.D, (2002), Lung cancer, cardiopulmonary mortality, and long-term exposure to fine particulate air pollution, JAMA, The journal of the American Medical Association, Vol. 287, No. 9, pp.1132-1141. Simpson, A.W.B, (1996) "Coase v. Pigou reexamined, The journal of legal studies, pp. 53-97. Slabbert, T.J.C, Sekhampu, T.J, (2009), Bophelong: a socio-economic and environmental analysis, Vandebijlpark: Vaal Research Group. Tanrivermi, H, (1998), Willingness to pay (WTP) and willingness to accept (WTA) measures in Turkey: May willingess to pay and willingness to accept be indicators to share the environmental damage burdens: A case study, Journal of Economic Cooperation among Islamic Countries, Vol. 19, No. 3, pp. 67-93. Todaro, M.P, and Smith, S.G, (2006), Economic development, New York: Pearson. Venkatachalam, L, (2004), The contingent valuation method: A review, Environmental impact assessment review, Vol. 24, No. 1, pp. 89-124. Wang, H, and Mullahy, J, (2006), Willingness to pay for reducing fatal risk by imporving air-quality: A contingent valuation study in Chongqing, China. Science of the Total Environment, Vol. 367, pp. 50-57. 11