March 19, Dialogue U.S. Fact Sheet Economic Track (July 11, 2014), https://www.treasury.gov/presscenter/press-releases/pages/jl2563.aspx.

Similar documents
A COMPARATIVE AND ECONOMIC ANALYSIS OF THE U.S. FTC S COMPLAINT AND THE KOREA FTC S DECISION AGAINST QUALCOMM

GENERAL RECOMMENDATIONS

Unless otherwise stated, the questions concern unilateral conduct by a dominant firm or firm with significant market power.

GUIDE TO COMPETITION LAW FEBRUARY 2014

COMMENT ON THE KOREA FAIR TRADE COMMISSION S REVISED REVIEW GUIDELINES ON UNFAIR EXERCISE OF INTELLECTUAL PROPERTY RIGHTS

Towards an effects based approach to price discrimination. Anne Perrot «Pros and Cons 2005» Stockholm

Intellectual Property Right Holders and Dominance

WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION

Volume 12 No.1 Fall 2014

The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case

Antitrust Considerations in Healthcare. Cory A. Talbot ( )

Transaction Cost Economics, Antitrust Rules, and Remedies

CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market

4th Annual Advanced Patent Law Institute at USPTO Antitrust and SSO Developments

THE EC COMMISSION ARTICLE 82 GUIDANCE

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

Guidance On Enforcement Priorities Regarding Exclusionary Abuses: A Comparative Overview

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

In The Supreme Court of the United States

THE COMPETITIVE EFFECTS OF LOYALTY DISCOUNTS IN A MODEL OF COMPETITION IMPLIED BY THE DISCOUNT ATTRIBUTION TEST

Avoiding Antitrust Violations in Competitor Collaborations

VERTICAL MERGERS: THEORY AND POLICY

Predatory Pricing. 2. Please list your jurisdiction s criteria for an abuse of dominance/monopolization based on predatory pricing.

Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General

Competition policy and legislation in Mexico

Differences in Schools of Thought on Protecting Competition: Chicago School vs. European School

BBC response to Ofcom s consultation: Broadcast Transmission Services: a review of the market

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E

IDEOLOGY MATTERS IN THE ANTITRUST DEBATE

An Examination of New Theories on Price Effects of Cross-Market Hospital Mergers

Comments on the Report on Single-Firm Conduct

Anti-competitive exclusionary conduct in EU antitrust practice

Competition Law & Policy in India

ANTITRUST TREATMENTOF BUNDLED DISCOUNTSINUS:ACASE ANALYSIS By Mr. S Seetharaman & Mr. J Parthasarthy

PANDORA S DIGITAL BOX: DIGITAL WALLETS AND THE HONOR ALL DEVICES RULE ADAM J. LEVITIN EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39

Analysis Group vguppi Online Tool Detailed User Guide. Revised August 13, 2014

Product design in EU competition law

Organisation de Coopération et de Développement Économiques Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development

An Overview of the Antimonopoly Act in Japan. Fumio Sensui Professor at the Graduate School of Law, Kobe University sensui2015(at)gmail.

ICN Unilateral Conduct Workshop Remedies Breakout Session Guide

Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for Economic Analysis: Interpreting Data Under the Guidance of Economic Theory

L ABOR a n d ANTITRUST,

Testimony of Gerard Keegan In Opposition to Hawaii House Bill Before the Hawaii House of Representatives Intrastate Commerce Committee

Abuse of Dominance: New Developments in the Tetra Pak Decision

Regulation of dominant firms in South Africa

FOSTERING COMPETITION IN THE CONTEXT OF RISK MANAGEMENT 1

Carlton & Perloff Chapter 12 Vertical Integration and Vertical Restrictions. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration

CCIA Position on the Trademark regulation Review

MARKET DOMINANCE UNDER THE ANTI-MONOPOLY LAW: SAIC S LANDMARK DECISION ON TETRA PAK

Regulating Public Utility Performance The Law of Market Structure, Pricing and Jurisdiction Scott Hempling

Exclusivity rebates vs. predation: different paradigms?

The attached material is posted on regulation2point0.org with permission.

PRIORITY SETTING AND RESOURCE ALLOCATION IN THE UNITED STATES

Javier Berasategi Competition along the Food Chain OECD Food Chain Analysis Network 30/

Competing through Innovation: Implications for Market Definition

Provider Consolidation: Enforcement and Policy Perspectives from the Federal Trade Commission

EXPLOITING OTHERS INVESTMENTS IN OPEN STANDARDS

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

The opinions expressed in this presentation are the personal views of the author and do not prejudge decisions of the RRT

Appendix N: Market Structure Law. TV Stations Ownership

Market studies. Guidance on the OFT approach

Rationale for Competition Law and Economic Regulation Dr. Geeta Gouri (Former) Member Competition Commission of India Honorary Visiting Faculty

Ethical Implications of Trade

ALI-ABA Video Law Review The False Claims Act: Including New Proposed Amendments Wednesday, April 30, 2008 Live Video Webcast

AmCham EU comments on the European Commission s Preliminary Report on the E-Commerce Sector Inquiry

Understanding Antitrust Laws, Competition, the Economy, and Their Impact on Our Everyday Lives

HCCA Professional Code of Ethics

AS DISCUSSED IN MORE DETAIL IN

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

AAI Applauds Move to Block AT&T-Time Warner Merger, Sets Record Straight on Vertical Merger Enforcement

LESSON FIVE MAINTAINING COMPETITION

WARWICK ECONOMIC RESEARCH PAPERS

Francisco Marcos IE Law School Castellón de la Plana 8 E Madrid SPAIN

On Fairness and Welfare: The Objectives of Competition Policy (Comment)

tinitnl ~tat[s ~[nat[

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin

2. Facebook is a US American company. Why does the Bundeskartellamt have competence to investigate in this case?

United States v. Microsoft Corp.

THE ANTITRUST COMPLIANCE PROGRAMME OF THE ITALCEMENTI GROUP

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2013 (2)

understanding what the bumper sticker means.

European Parliament Committee on Legal Affairs. Draft Report on the proposal for a CESL ( )

Thoughts on Countervailing Buyer Power

Committee Newsletter Spring 2016

Two Recent Decisions Analyze Topics Important to All In-House Lawyers: Carefully Identifying Their Clients and Internally Communicating by

IN RECENT YEARS, THE FTC HAS ACHIEVED

Local Loop Unbundling: Some Economic Issues

A Guide to Competition Law

IN RECENT YEARS, both tying and bundling have been a concern for

Memorandum of understanding between the Competition and Markets Authority and the Office of Communications concurrent competition powers

ICN Unilateral Conduct Working Group: Responses to the Questionnaire

Interview with Fiona Scott Morton, DAAG for Economic Analysis at the DOJ

The Exchange of Commercially Sensitive Information. Some legal and economic issues

China s Fair Competition Review System, 1 Year Later

BUNDLING BEHAVIOR IN TELECOMS: WHAT FIRMS DO AND HOW EUROPEAN COMPETITION AUTHORITIES HAVE INCLUDED BUNDLING IN THEIR REASONING

Price Discrimination

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Learning Objectives. Chapter 28. Regulation and Antitrust Policy in a Globalized Economy

Compulsory Licensing of Intellectual Property As Merger Remedy: A Decision-Theoretic Approach

Transcription:

COMMENT OF THE GLOBAL ANTITRUST INSTITUTE, ANTONIN SCALIA LAW SCHOOL, GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY, ON THE PROPOSED REVISIONS TO THE PEOPLE S REPUBLIC OF CHINA ANTI-UNFAIR COMPETITION LAW March 19, 2017 This comment is submitted in response to the Legislative Affairs Commission of the Standing Committee of the National People s Congress (National People s Congress) of the People s Republic of China s public consultation on the February 26, 2017 draft revisions to China s Anti-Unfair Competition Law (AUCL). We submit this comment based upon our extensive experience and expertise in antitrust law and economics. 1 As an initial matter, we commend the National People s Congress for deleting Article 6 on abuse of superior bargaining position. With respect to the remaining draft provisions, we respectfully recommend that any provisions that relate to conduct covered by China s Anti- Monopoly Law (AML) be omitted entirely. As China recently recognized in the Sixth Meeting of the U.S-China Strategic and Economic Dialogue, the objective of competition policy is to promote consumer welfare and economic efficiency, rather than to promote individual competitors or industries, and... enforcement of its competition law should be fair, objective, transparent, and non- discriminatory. 2 The AUCL should be implemented in a manner consistent with these objectives of competition policy and in a manner that is consistent with the AML. In particular, we strongly urge that Article 11 (which provides that [b]usiness operators selling goods must not bundle the sale of goods against buyers wishes, and must not attach other unreasonable conditions ) be omitted in its entirety, as such conduct is already covered by Article 17(5) of the AML. In the alternative, at the very least, Article 11 should be revised to adopt an effect-based approach under which bundling will be condemned only when: (1) the seller has market power in one of the goods included in the bundle sufficient to enable it to restrain trade in the market(s) for the other goods in the bundle; and (2) the anticompetitive 1 The Global Antitrust Institute (GAI), a division of the Antonin Scalia Law School at George Mason University (Scalia Law), is a leading international platform for economic education and research that focuses upon the legal and economic analysis of key antitrust issues confronting competition agencies and courts around the world. University Professor Joshua D. Wright, Ph.D. (economics), is the Executive Director of the GAI and a former U.S. Federal Trade Commissioner. Koren W. Wong-Ervin is the Director of the GAI, and Adjunct Professor at Scalia Law, and former Counsel for Intellectual Property and International Antitrust at the U.S. Federal Trade Commission. Professor of Law Douglas H. Ginsburg is a Senior Judge, United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit, Chairman of the GAI s International Board of Advisors, and a former Assistant Attorney General in charge of the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice. Associate Dean for Research and Faculty Development and Professor of Law Bruce H. Kobayashi, Ph.D. (economics), is a GAI Senior Scholar and Founding Director. 2 Press Release, U.S. Dep t of Treasury, Sixth Meeting of the U.S.-China Strategic and Economic Dialogue U.S. Fact Sheet Economic Track (July 11, 2014), https://www.treasury.gov/presscenter/press-releases/pages/jl2563.aspx. 1

effects outweigh any procompetitive benefits. Such an approach would be consistent with Article 17(5) of the AML, which provides for an effects-based approach that applies only to firms with a dominant market position. 3 As explained in Section II, below, bundling is ubiquitous and widely used by a variety of firms and for a variety of reasons. 4 In the vast majority of cases, package sales are easily explained by economies of scope in production or by reductions in transaction and information costs, with an obvious benefit to the seller, the buyer or both. 5 Those benefits can include lower prices for consumers, facilitate entry into new markets, reduce conflicting incentives between manufacturers and their distributors, and mitigate retailer free-riding and other types of agency problems. 6 Indeed, bundling can serve the same efficiency-enhancing vertical control functions as have been identified in the economic literature on tying, exclusive dealing, and other forms of vertical restraints. 7 The potential to harm competition and generate anticompetitive effects arises only when bundling is practiced by a firm with market power in one of the goods included in the bundle. As the U.S. Supreme Court has explained, there is nothing inherently anticompetitive about package sales, 8 and the fact that a purchaser is forced to buy a product he would not have otherwise bought even from another seller does not imply an adverse impact on competition. 9 Rather, for bundling to harm competition there would have to be an exclusionary effect on other sellers because bundling thwarts buyers desire to purchase substitutes for one or more of the goods in the bundle from those other sellers to an extent that harms competition in the markets 3 Article 17 provides that [u]ndertakings holding dominant market positions are prohibited from doing the following by abusing their dominant market positions... (5) without justifiable reasons, conducting tie-in sale of commodities or adding other unreasonable trading conditions to transactions. AML, http://english.mofcom.gov.cn/article/policyrelease/businessregulations/201303/20130300045909.shtml. 4 See, e.g., Bruce H. Kobayashi, Does Economics Provide a Reliable Guide to Regulating Commodity Bundling By Firms?: A Survey of the Economic Literature, 1 J. COMP. L. & ECON. 4, 707-08 (2005) [hereinafter Kobayashi]; see also THOMAS T. NAGLE & REED K. HOLDEN, THE STRATEGY AND TACTICS OF PRICING: A GUIDE TO PROFITABLE DECISION MAKING 3d ed. (Prentice Hall 2002); David S. Evans & Michael Salinger, Why Do Firms Bundle and Tie? Evidence from Competitive Markets and Implications for Tying Law, 22 YALE. J. ON REG. 37 (2005); Stefan Stremersch & Gerard J. Tellis, Strategic Bundling of Products and Prices: A New Synthesis for Marketing, 66 J. MKT G 55 (2002) [hereinafter Stremersch & Tellis]. 5 Kobayashi supra note 4, at 708; see also Stremersch & Tellis, supra note 1, at 70; David S. Evans & A. Jorge Padilla, Designing Antitrust Rules for Assessing Unilateral Practice: A Neo Chicago Approach, 72 U. CHI. L. REV. 27 (2005). 6 Kobayashi, supra note 4, at 708; see also Bruce H. Kobayashi, Two Tales of Bundling: Implications for the Application of Antitrust Law to Bundled Discounts, GEORGE MASON UNIVERSITY LAW & ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER No 05-27 (2005). 7 Kobayashi, supra note 4, at 708. 8 Jefferson Parish Hosp. Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2, 25 (1984). 9 Id. at 16. 2

for those products. 10 Moreover, because of the widespread procompetitive use of bundling, by firms without and firms with market power, making bundling per se or presumptively unlawful is likely to generate many Type I (false positive) errors which, as the U.S. Supreme Court has explained, are especially costly, because they chill the very conduct the antitrust laws are designed to protect. 11 I. Unfairness Under the AUCL Should Be Linked to Universal Competition Law Principles Unfair competition has increasingly been a focus of antitrust agencies around the world, a trend that raises difficult questions regarding the relationship between unfair methods of competition laws and traditional antitrust laws. In many competition policy regimes, the differences between the two can lead to significant tension and even conflict. Traditional antitrust laws, which condemn only conduct that harms competition and is not outweighed by any procompetitive efficiencies, are grounded on the notion that there should be no regulation of ex post outcomes between firms, i.e., traditional antitrust laws are designed to protect the competitive process and not to micromanage market outcomes. In contrast, some unfair competition laws have been applied in a manner that prohibits conduct when efficiencies outweigh any anticompetitive effects, a risk that should be avoided. One way to avoid this risk is to limit unfair competition law to conduct not already covered by traditional antitrust laws. Another is to apply the same principles to unfair competition laws as have long been applied under traditional antitrust laws. From an economic perspective, there is no generally accepted definition of unfairness. However, there are two competing views of the proper relationship between unfairness and competition law. The ex ante approach views unfairness law as a complement to antitrust enforcement and is consistent with an economic approach to antitrust law. Under this view, unfairness liability does not conflict with competition law, but instead protects the competitive process by filling in the gaps in traditional antitrust laws. Under an ex ante approach, fairness is determined by considering barriers to entry, exclusion of rivals from the opportunity to compete, and other factors consistent with an effects-based approach of traditional competition law. This requires a showing that the alleged business s conduct has actually caused harm to competition. The ex post approach views unfairness and competition law as substitutes, with unfairness liability untethered from economic principles. This approach looks to govern the outcomes of bargaining disputes or prices themselves by evaluating the relative positions of the parties and the result from the transaction. This can result in a chilling effect that affects procompetitive conduct such as innovation, which ultimately benefits consumers. Most importantly, it does not take into account any effect on competition, and thus undermines the objectives of effect-based competition law regimes. 10 See Alden F. Abbott & Joshua D. Wright, Antitrust Analysis of Tying Arrangements and Exclusive Dealing at 7 (2009), https://www.law.gmu.edu/assets/files/publications/working_papers/08-37%20antitrust%20analysis%20of%20tying.pdf [hereinafter Abbott & Wright]. 11 Verizon Commc ns Inc. v. Law Offices of Curtis V. Trinko, LLP, 540 U.S. 398, 414 (2004) (internal quotations omitted). 3

Recognizing the distinction between these two approaches is a difficult task for any governmental agency. For the majority of its 100-year history, the U.S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC) approached its evaluation of unfair methods of competition from an ex post perspective; it is generally recognized now that the practice of evaluating unfairness untethered from competition law principles is likely to lead to bad outcomes for consumers. 12 As a result, the FTC has adopted a consistent method of dealing with unfair methods of competition in the 2015 FTC Unfair Methods of Competition Statement, which embraced ex ante unfairness analysis that tethered the evaluation of fairness to underlying traditional antitrust policy. 13 This policy statement clearly states that the FTC will be guided by three principles when enforcing Section 5 s unfair method of competition provision: (1) promote consumer welfare as that term is generally understood in U.S. antitrust law precedent; (2) evaluate conduct by balancing harm to the competitive process against the procompetitive benefits of that conduct; and (3) do not apply Section 5 to the conduct if the U.S. antitrust laws are sufficient to address the competitive concern at issue. Tethering unfairness to antitrust principles ensures consistency in applying the economic principles that guide competition laws. By focusing on an effects-based approach, antitrust agencies evaluate conduct based on harm to competition and allow for consideration of procompetitive efficiencies. II. Article 11 (Governing Bundling) Should Be Omitted in Its Entirety or, At the Very Least, Revised to Adopt An Effects-Based Approach As an initial matter, it is important to distinguish between pure and mixed bundling. Pure bundling occurs when a firm offers only the package and not the stand-alone goods. Mixed bundling occurs when both the package and the individual goods are available from the bundling firm. Thus, if the seller offers the goods separately from the bundle then the conduct at issue constitutes mixed bundling and there is no coercion. Bundling is not only widespread in practice, but also prevalent in markets in which no firm has significant market power. In competitive markets, the presumptive explanation for bundling is either economies of scope in production or reductions in transactions and 12 See generally William E. Kovacic & Marc Winerman, Competition Policy and the Application of Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act, 76 ANTITRUST L.J. 929, 940-43 (2010) ( The FTC s record of appellate litigation involving applications of Section 5 that go beyond prevailing interpretations of the other antitrust laws is uninspiring. ); Joshua D. Wright, Comm r, Fed. Trade Comm n, What s YourAgenda?, Remarks at the ABA Antitrust Spring Meeting 6-7 (Apr. 11, 2013), http://www.ftc.gov/sites/default/files/documents/public_statements/whatsyouragenda/130411abaspringmtg.pdf ( [I]t is no surprise that [Kovacic & Winerman] conclude the FTC experience with Section 5 is generally a bleak record. ). 13 FED. TRADE COMM N, Statement of Enforcement Principles Regarding Unfair Methods of Competition Under Section 5 of the FTC Act (Aug. 13, 2015), https://www.ftc.gov/system/files/documents/public_statements/735201/150813section5enforcement.pdf. 4

information costs, which benefit the seller, the buyer, or both. 14 Offering consumers more choices can be costly for firms; if the costs of providing more choice exceed the benefits to consumers, more choice can make consumers worse off. For example, for a company with 1,000 patents, the number of possible licensing combinations of patents is on the order of 10 301. 15 Thus, there is a significant cost of prohibiting bundling, including the significant (if not costprohibitive) transaction costs to both patent owners and implementers if they were forced to analyze each and every patent in a large portfolio and negotiate a license on each. These procompetitive uses also apply when used by firms with significant market power. In that setting, however, bundling has the potential to harm competition and generate anticompetitive effects. Market power is a necessary but not sufficient condition for harm to competition. Without power in one of the goods included in the bundle, the seller would not be able to force the buyer to purchase its bundle because the buyer could easily purchase the bundle of goods separately from other sellers. Even then, as the Supreme Court has explained, that a purchaser is forced to buy a product he would not have otherwise bought even from another seller does not imply an adverse impact on competition. 16 Rather, for bundling to harm competition there would have to be an exclusionary effect on other sellers as a result of buyers thwarted desire to purchase an item in the bundle from another seller. 17 While the economic literature demonstrates the possibility that bundling by sellers with market power can generate anticompetitive harm, it does not provide a reliable way to gauge whether the potential for harm would outweigh any demonstrable benefits from the practice. 18 As such, treating bundling as per se or presumptively unlawful can generate significant costs by erroneously condemning or deterring efficient business practices. For these reasons, we strongly urge the National People s Congress to omit Article 11 in its entirety or, at the very least, to adopt an effects-based approach with a market-power screen similar to the approach set forth in Article 17 of the AML. III. Conclusion We appreciate the opportunity to comment and would be happy to respond to any questions the National People s Congress may have regarding this comment. 14 Kobayashi, supra note 4, at 708. 15 See Anne Layne-Farrar & Michael A. Salinger, Bundling of RAND-Committed Patents at 11 (June 2015), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2585528. 16 Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 16. 17 Abbott & Wright, supra note 10, at 7. 18 Kobayashi, supra note 4, at 707. 5