Who is Best at Negotiating Pharmaceutical Rebates?

Similar documents
Put Money Back in Your Classroom Finding the hidden revenue in your pharmacy benefits

Pharmaceutical Compliance Congress: Pricing Update

Drafting Pharmacy Benefit Manager Contracts: Controlling Costs, Avoiding Hidden Fees

Roundtable Webinar. Presenters. April 6, Managed Care Contracting Risks: An Antitrust, Government Pricing and Fraud & Abuse Analysis

Transparency Debate in PBM Industry Consumer Driven Healthcare Summit Sept , 2006 in Washington, DC. Marina Tackitt PBMI

Sales/Revenue Forecasting and Contract Analytics that Drive Profitability. March 16, 2015 Presented by: Jag Rajan VP of Finance

An Economic Analysis of Generic Drug Usage in the U.S.

INTERNATIONAL DIFFERENCES IN DRUG PRICES

CHAPTER 8: SECTION 1 A Perfectly Competitive Market

Medicare Drug Discount Cards: A Work in Progress

.COM. Pharmaceutical Brand Management Achieving Managed Care Pull-Through Performance

Commercial Pricing and Contracting 101

SAMPLE MULTIPLE CHOICE FINAL EXAM CHAPTER 6 THE ANALYSIS OF COSTS

13 C H A P T E R O U T L I N E

The U.S. Wholesaler Market: Past, Present and Future

Future Trends In Pharmaceutical and Biotech Distribution White paper

Loyalty Discounts and Pharmaceutical Competition

ARNOLD & PORTER UPDATE

The Drug Supply Chain Security Act: An Overview for Health System Pharmacy Staff April 17, 2015

Disclosure. Pre Lecture Questions. Learning Objectives. The Drug Supply Chain Security Act: An Overview for Health System Pharmacy Staff

Carlton & Perloff Chapter 12 Vertical Integration and Vertical Restrictions. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration

WHAT EVERY BUSINESS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT PRICE DISCRIMINATION

The Pharma/Payer Relationship Strategies for the Next Two Years

VALUE-BASED HEALTHCARE A MANUFACTURER S PERSPECTIVE PETER JUHN, MD, MPH VICE PRESIDENT AND GLOBAL HEAD, VALUE-BASED PARTNERSHIPS

CHAPTER 5 THE ANALYSIS OF COSTS

The Drug Importation Debate: An Economic Perspective

An Examination of New Theories on Price Effects of Cross-Market Hospital Mergers

Department of Economics, University of Oslo. ECON4820 Spring Last modified:

Countervailing Power in Wholesale Pharmaceuticals

AP Microeconomics Chapter 11 Outline

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Monopoly 2. Laugher Curve. The Welfare Loss from Monopoly. The Welfare Loss from Monopoly. Bad things that monopolist do!

Economics of two-sided markets

CHAPTER 12 Pricing CHAPTER OUTLINE

Access Based Network Design A new approach to significantly reducing prescription drug benefit costs.

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

SOUTH DAKOTA BOARD OF REGENTS. Policy Manual

Economic Analysis of Price Determinants in Pharmaceutical Industry in United States

Price Discrimination. It is important to stress that charging different prices for similar goods is not pure price discrimination.

Towards an effects based approach to price discrimination. Anne Perrot «Pros and Cons 2005» Stockholm

The North-Atlantic Free Trade Agreement and the Trans-Pacific Partnership: Side-by-Side Comparison. NAFTA Chapter 10: Government Procurement

The NBCH PBM Assessment. A Cross-PBM RFI

Hatch-Waxman: Driving Access, Savings & Innovation

Pricing with Perfect Competition. Advanced Pricing Strategies. Markup Pricing. Pricing with Market Power

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

Advertising and Marketing Genetic Tests New Pathways or Old Roads?

Executive Summary PBM Purchasers Guide A Quality Management Toolkit

The Measurement and Importance of Profit

1.5 Nov 98 a. Explain the term natural monopolies and why are they considered a danger if left unregulated. [10] b. (not in 2013 syllabus)

Lecture 13 - Price Discrimination

LOW R&D EFFICIENCY IN LARGE PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES

ASHP Guidelines on Medication Cost Management Strategies for Hospitals and Health Systems

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Publicly Funded Clinical Trials: A Route to Sustained Innovation with Affordable Drugs

Revenue from Contracts with Customers

COUNTERVAILING POWER IN WHOLESALE PHARMACEUTICALS

Other examples of monopoly include Australia Post.

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

PBMs: From RFP To Implementation. Christopher Cannon, NASTAD U.S. Virgin Islands ADAP and Georgia ADAP April 3, 2014

Pubic Monopolies, Concessions and Competition Law and Policies

COMPOUNDING PHARMACIES: STEPS TO AVOID ISSUES WITH THE FDA, DEA, PHARMACY BOARDS, AND PATENT HOLDERS. Denise Leard, Esq Brown & Fortunato, P.C.

14.23 Government Regulation of Industry

Global Forum on Competition

Utility-Wind Energy Marketer Partnerships: A New Model for Building Wind Facilities. WINDPOWER 2003 Conference

The U.S. Food and Drug Administration (FDA) is expected

10/10/2013. Hawaii Regional Annual Conference Conflicts of Interest Never End. Conflicts of Interest: Disclosure, Monitoring and Auditing

ExaLink services Pricing and contracts

ATM MODERNIZATION FOUR REASONS TO MODERNIZE YOUR AGING ATM INSTALL BASE. An NCR white paper

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Memorandum Issue Date September 2012

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

FEEDBACK TUTORIAL LETTER

Managing Fraud Risks. Procurement & Contacting. John J. Hall, CPA (970)

Revenue from contracts with customers

Economics. Monopoly. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Vance Ginn & Ron Cronovich C H A P T E R P R I N C I P L E S O F

Ford Motor Company of Canada, Limited Ford Dealer Advertising Co-op Program Guidelines at a Glance

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Managerial Economics

Managerial Economics

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

New Member Reference Guide Your guide to getting the most from your Part D coverage.

YASHAJIT SAHA & ABHISHEK SHARMA, SUBJECT MATTER EXPERTS, RESEARCH & ANALYTICS ADVANCED ANALYTICS: A REMEDY FOR COMMERCIAL SUCCESS IN PHARMA.

4/13/2018. Evolving Standards on Resale Price Maintenance, Tying and Other Vertical Restraints. Program Overview

AP Microeconomics Chapter 10 Outline

A few firms Imperfect Competition Oligopoly. Figure 8.1: Market structures

AQA Economics A-level

College Record: 59.7% 4 year school, 13.1% 2 year school, 9.9% trade school

Tutor2u A2 Business Economics Glossary

The Journal of Applied Business Research Volume 18, Number 4

PRICING. Quantity demanded is the number of the firm s product customers wish to purchase. What affects the quantity demanded?

PHARMACEUTICAL ANTITRUST: Delayed Generic Entry Cases. December 7, 2011 Linda Nussbaum John Radice

Conflict of Interest Policy

Health Reform for New Health Reform Reporters Kaiser Family Foundation July 7, 2016

FERC Standards of Conduct Training & Compliance (Updated August 2006)

DATA SHARING AGREEMENT

Understanding the Prescription Drug Landscape & Best Practices for Managing the Benefit

Transfer Pricing. 2. Advantages and Disadvantages of Decentralization

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

COST OF PRODUCTION & THEORY OF THE FIRM

Transcription:

Who is Best at Negotiating Pharmaceutical Rebates? By Lawrence W. Abrams, Ph.D. 12/01/05 Lawrence W. Abrams, Ph.D. Nu-Retail P.O. Box 1285 Watsonville, CA. 95077 831-254-7325 (C.) labrams@nu-retail.com Disclosures: I have not received any remuneration for this paper nor have I financial interest in any company cited in this working paper. I have a Ph.D. in Economics from Washington University in St. Louis and a B.A. in Economics from Amherst College. Other working papers on PBMs can be accessed at www.nu-retail.com. Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 1

Introduction The roll out of the new Medicare drug benefit program has renewed the debate about who is best at negotiating drug rebates with pharmaceutical manufacturers ( Pharma ). Those who favor the Federal government point to statistics showing that Medicaid gets significantly better rebates than private sector entities called pharmacy benefit managers ( PBMs ). The purpose of this paper is to provide new insights into this question by viewing pharmaceutical rebates through bargaining theory. The first insight is that rebates are paid selectively so that averages of rebate rates across all brands are a poor measure of negotiating power. PBMs ability to extract rebates from Pharma is much greater than previously realized when rebate averages are disaggregated. The second insight derived from bargaining theory is that the rebate transaction is much more complex than the price theory conceptualization of rebates as volume discounts. Drug rebates are tariffs, or entrance fees, paid by Pharma to gatekeepers who promise access to markets with reduced competition. Medicaid gets more than PBMs, but gives up more in terms of rights to impose co-payments, prior authorization restrictions and rights to switch onpatent brand prescriptions to lower cost therapeutic equivalents. PBMs receive less than Medicaid, but they give up less. Based on the overall goal of cost containment, there is evidence that private sector PBMs do a better job at rebate negotiation than Medicaid. The Variability of Pharmaceutical Rebates Two recent studies provide new data on the variability of pharmaceutical rebates rates. Disaggregating this data by classes of drugs demonstrates the weakness of using broad averages to measure rebate-negotiating power. A recent letter from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) provided an unprecedented breakdown of the often-quoted nineteen percent average rebate rate that Medicaid receives from Pharma. The Medicaid deal is as follows: in return for being placed on the Medicaid formulary and sheltered from prescription switching and other restrictions, a drug s manufacturer must rebate the government the greater of 15.1 percent of its average manufacturer s price (AMP) or the difference between the best price given to a private sector reseller and the 15.1 percent minimum. Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 2

The CBO letter revealed that thirty-six percent of Medicaid brand drug spend received a best price rebate while sixty-four percent of brand drug spend received the minimum. In addition, the CBO letter provided evidence of the value of a little known clause in the Medicaid deal that gave the government inflation protection. The value of that clause amounted to a surprisingly large additional rebate of 11.7 percent of AMP in 2003. Based on the above data, it is possible to disaggregate the 19.6 percent basic Medicaid average into a 27.6 percent average paid on best price drugs and the 15.1 percent minimum paid on the rest. In September of 2005, the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) released a long awaited study of potential conflicts of interest by independent PBMs. The FTC obtained data on rebate receipts by drug for the Big Three independent PBMs Caremark Rx, Medco Health Solutions, and Express Scripts. These three large PBMs manage about sixty percent of all outpatient prescriptions in the United States. The FTC study confirmed that Pharma pays rebates only on a small portion of brand drugs. It does not pay on brand drugs with a monopoly position. Nor does Pharma pay on brand drugs in aging therapeutic classes where most of the competing brands have lost patent protection. The FTC also confirmed that Pharma negotiates brand rebate deals only with PBMs, and not retail drugstore chains like Walgreen and CVS. Size does not matter on the buy-side if an entity does not also have the power to affect the demand for brand drugs through discretion in formulary design and compliance. On the other hand, it is generic drug manufacturers that negotiate volume discount deals with drugstores because only dispensing pharmacies have the power to choose from an array of suppliers of perfect substitutes. Unfortunately, the FTC failed, or was prohibited, from disclosing any detail about rebates rates by drug or therapeutic class. However, it is possible to perform a rough disaggregation of the disclosure that the Big Three PBMs received an average of $6.34 in rebates and data fees per on-patent drug in 2003. The FTC disclosed that data collection fees paid by Pharma amounted to three percent of wholesale acquisition costs. Subtracting out these substantial fees, that some allege are masked rebates exempt from inclusion in Medicaid Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 3

best price calculations, the estimate for the average rebate received per brand is $4.22. The key to disaggregating this average was another disclosure that seventy-one percent of rebate receipts for each PBM were concentrated in the top twenty-five rebate receiving drugs. Assuming that these highly rebatable brands represent about twenty percent of brand drug prescription volume, it is possible to decompose the $4.22 broad average into rebate components of $14.98 for the top rebate-receiving drugs and $1.53 for the rest. For comparison purposes, Table 1 presents the conversion of rebate levels to rebate rates based on an assumed average wholesale cost (WAC) or AMP. While the Big Three PBMs received on average 8.0 percent of AMP across all brands, they receive 22.7 percent of AMP on rebatable drugs. This is comparable to the 27.6 percent that Medicaid receives as a best price rebate. Not too much should be made of differences as the ratio is sensitive to an assumed average for WAC and AMP. Table 1: Disaggregation of Average Rebate Rates "Best Price" 15.1% Minimum Medicaid 'Best Price', 2003 36% of Brand Spend 64% of Brand Spend Average Rebate as % of AMP Rebate as % of AMP Basic Rebate Rate 19.6% 27.6% 15.1% Inflation Protection 11.7% 11.7% 11.7% Rate + Inflation Protection 31.4% 39.3% 26.8% "Rebatable" Brands Rest of On-Patent Brands Big 3 PBMs Rebate Rate, 2003 71% of Rebate Receipts 29% of Rebate Receipts 20% of Brand Rx 80% of Brand Rx Average 25% of Brand Spend 75% of Brand Spend Rebates $ / Brand Rx $4.22 $14.98 $1.53 WAC $70.50 $88.13 $66.09 AMP =.75* WAC $52.88 $66.10 $49.57 Rebate as a % of WAC 6.0% 17.0% 2.3% Rebate as a % of AMP 8.0% 22.7% 3.1% Sources: CBO Letter and FTC Study of PBM Conflict of Interest Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 4

Overall, Medicaid receives more, but this is mostly due to the inflation factor and government s unique ability to confiscate a 15.1 percent minimum from the all powerful (monopolists) and the all powerless (many competitors). Disaggregation presents a completely different perspective on the rebate negotiation ability of the Big Three PBMs. This ability is not something that they care to make transparent for strategic reasons. They also show no inclination to challenge the validity of using broad averages as measures of rebate negotiating ability. There is much speculation over who actually triggers the Medicaid best price. Some believe that the Big Three PBMs get the best price based on their sheer size and a business model bias that favors abstaining from switching of a rebatable brand drug to lower cost generic that garners no rebates. Others believe that HMOs with captive PBMs, like Kaiser Permanente, trigger the best price. These HMOs know that their members are willing to sacrifice some freedom of choice for competitive premiums. HMOs with captive PBM operations garner rebates through formulary design and compliance that advantages a single drug in a therapeutic class. In contract, the Big 3 PBMs tend not to play favorites, but extract rebates from competing manufacturers by promising each that they will abstain from disadvantageous restrictions and prescription switching. This passivity allows other forms of competition like advertising and physician detailing to take over. The Pharmaceutical Rebate Bargain Price theory has been misapplied to the case of pharmaceutical rebates. Rebates are not volume discounts. They are not evidence of price discrimination based on elasticity of demand. It may be incorrect to apply the analysis of most favored nation clauses to the Medicaid best price formula. Rebates are the result of a bargain over the surplus that is created in a market characterized by a bilateral oligopoly. Secrecy and credible threats are central to the negotiation of pharmaceutical rebates. There are several fundamental insights gained by viewing pharmaceutical rebates through bargaining theory. Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 5

First, the welfare implications of this deal are complex. PBMs may not be the populist countervailing force conceptualized by John Kenneth Galbraith. PBMs may be enabling and co-dependent, rather than countervailing. The surplus that is being divided up here is not necessarily fixed. It is possible that Pharma and PBMs are tacitly colluding to increase the surplus in an intermediate market at the expense of excluded competitors on the sell side and powerless downstream consumers on the buy side. Evidence that PBMs and the government extract substantial rebates from Pharma is not sufficient proof that their actions improve consumer welfare. Second, there are two sides to the rebate deal. The question of who is the best rebate negotiator involves an evaluation of what is received relative to what is given up. Private sector PBMs receive less that Medicaid, but they give up less in terms of rights to engage in therapeutic interchange, impose usage restrictions, and affect demand through co-payment differentials. When the Medicaid deal was struck in 1990, generic drugs were not the competitive threat that they are today. In return for rebates, the government promised to place a brand drug on the Medicaid formulary and exempt it from any prescription switching and usage restrictions such prior authorization. In 1993, the deal was modified so that generic substitution an off-patent brand switched to a generic equivalent was allowed. Companies paying Medicaid for formulary placement today are still protected from any type of therapeutic interchange an on-patent brand switched to less costly generic that is a therapeutic equivalent. In addition, prior authorization restrictions cannot be imposed at the national level, but remain a local option that several states have seized as a bargaining chip to extract supplemental rebates from Pharma. A recent study by the Lewin Group evaluated the performance of different Medicaid plan managers on the basis of overall drug spend delivered, and not narrowly on net unit prices after rebates. One set of plans known as Medicaid fee-for-service (FFS) are eligible for best price rebates, but must adhere to Medicaid guidelines limiting therapeutic interchange and usage restriction. The other set of plans known as Medicaid managed care organization (MCO) are privately managed by PBMs and not eligible for Medicaid rebates. However, these PBMs have a lot more discretion in formulary design and compliance. Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 6

The Lewin Group study found that Medicaid FFS plans received rebates averaging fifteen percentage points higher than Medicaid MCO plans. However, the discretion allowed by PBMs who managed Medicaid MCO plans enabled them to deliver a fifty-nine percent generic dispensing rate the number of generic prescriptions divided by the sum of all prescriptions compared to a fifty percent rate found for Medicaid FFS plans. Even more dramatic was difference in usage rates number of prescriptions per member per month. PBMs were able to deliver a usage rate that was fifteen to twenty percentage points lower than Medicaid FFS plans. Overall, the drug spend of privately managed plans was ten to fifteen percentage points lower than government run plans despite lagging in rebates received from Pharma. The results of this study clearly demonstrate the weakness of evaluating bargaining agents solely on the basis of rebate rates. Based on overall goal of cost containment, this study provides evidence that private sector PBMs do a better job at rebate negotiation than Medicaid. References and Further Reading Beronja, Nancy et. al. 2003. Comparison of Medicaid Pharmacy Cost and Usage between Fee-for-Service and Capitated Settings. Resource Paper prepared by the Lewin Group for the Center for Health Care Strategies, Inc. Congressional Budget Office. 2005. The Rebate Medicaid Receives on Brand- Name Prescription Drugs. Attachment to letter to Senator Charles Grassley dated June 22, 2005. Federal Trade Commission. 2005. Pharmacy Benefit Managers: Ownership of Mail-Order Pharmacies. Lawrence W. Abrams, 2006 7