BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002)

Similar documents
Applications and Choice of IVs

Lecture 11 Applications of BLP. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005

Store Brands and Retail Grocery Competition in Breakfast Cereals

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

Measuring the Effect of Infant Indu Title The Japanese Automobile Industry in.

Identification in differentiated product markets

Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

An Empirical study on the automobile industry

An Analysis of Automobile Demand. Øyvind Thomassen Exeter College University of Oxford

An Empirical Study of National vs. Local Pricing under Multimarket Competition

A Simple Model of Demand Accumulation

Pricing with Market Power

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for Economic Analysis: Interpreting Data Under the Guidance of Economic Theory

Technological Change, Trade in Intermediates and the Joint Impact on Productivity

An empirical study of the automobile industry. Preliminary Draft

The Impact of One Stop Shopping- Induced Purchasing Complementarities in Structural Econometric Models of Retails Competition

On the Relevance of Probability Distortions in the Extended Warranties Market

Consumer Choice of Food Products and the Implications for Price Competition and for an Analysis of Government Policy

ESTIMATING DEMAND FOR MOBILE APPLICATIONS

Using Random Utility Structural Demand Models to Infer the Value of Quality Information

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: a Dynamic Model with Firm and Worker Heterogeneity

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB

Mergers with differentiated products: the case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry

Empirical Tools and Competition Analysis: Past Progress and Current Problems

Advertising in the US Personal Computer Industry

A study of cartel stability: the Joint Executive Committee, Paper by: Robert H. Porter

Product Repositioning and Short-Run Responses to Environmental Change

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Lecture 2: Market Structure I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE, TRADE IN INTERMEDIATES AND THE JOINT IMPACT ON PRODUCTIVITY

Environmental and Economic Effects of CO2-based Automobile. Taxes in Germany

Modeling Locations and Pricing Decisions in the Gasoline Market: A Structural Approach

The Microfoundations of Urban Agglomeration Economies: Dicussion of Duranton and Puga (DP), 2004

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB

Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Reports

The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Competition and Ideological Diversity: Historical Evidence from US Newspapers

Market integration and competition

Competition, Product Proliferation and Welfare: A Study of the U.S. Smartphone Market

Competition, Product Proliferation and Welfare: A Study of the U.S. Smartphone Market

Rebound effects in GB road transport. Steve Sorrell and Lee Stapleton November 2015

The Effects of Banning Advertising on Demand, Supply and. Welfare: Structural Estimation on a Junk Food Market

ESTIMATING DEMAND FOR AUTOMOBILE INDUSTRY IN THE U.S. MARKET: A thesis presented. Xiaonan Qin. to The Department of Economics

Tilburg University. Published in: Marketing Letters. Publication date: Link to publication

Kuhn-Tucker Estimation of Recreation Demand A Study of Temporal Stability

Supermarkets Price Competition in Dallas Fort Worth Fluid Milk Market. Benaissa Chidmi

Do Coupons Expand or Cannibalize Revenue? Evidence from an e-market

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Professor Jan Hanousek CERGE-EI Charles University Academy of Sciences Politickych veznu 7 P.O.Box Prague Czech Republic

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

R&D Investment, Exporting, and Productivity Dynamics

Portfolio Considerations in Differentiated Product Purchases: An Application to the Japanese Automobile Market

PICK ONLY ONE BEST ANSWER FOR EACH BINARY CHOICE OR MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTION.

Third degree price discrimination. Welfare Analysis

Vertical relationships between Manufacturers and Retailers: Inference with Limited Data

Technological change, trade in intermediates and the joint impact on productivity

Wage Mobility within and between Jobs

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

LECTURE 13 THE NEOCLASSICAL OR WALRASIAN EQUILIBRIUM INTRODUCTION

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

The Impacts of Retail Promotions on the Demand for Orange Juice: A Study of a Retail Chain

ZIBS Technical Report

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Estimating Demand Elasticities of Meat Demand in Slovakia

Problem Set #2 - Answers. Due February 2, 2000

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

NOTA DI LAVORO Designing Carbon Taxation Schemes for Automobiles: A Simulation Exercise for Germany

Dynamic Labor Demand in China: Public and Private Objectives

Search markets: Introduction

The PSB Review Stage 1 document has attracted criticism for its optimistic assessment of

Dynamic Efficiencies of the 1997 Boeing-McDonnell Douglas Merger

Unemployment, Sick Leave and Health

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

The Economic and Social Review, Vol. 33, No. 1, Spring, 2002, pp Portfolio Effects and Firm Size Distribution: Carbonated Soft Drinks*

Chapter 8. Competitive Firms and Markets

Practical Regression: Fixed Effects Models

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

LOW R&D EFFICIENCY IN LARGE PHARMACEUTICAL COMPANIES

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Audit firms face downward-sloping demand curves and the audit market is far from perfectly competitive

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Product-Level Efficiency and Core Competence in Multi-Product Plants

Intertemporal Effects of Consumption and Their Implications for Demand Elasticity Estimates

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

An Econometric Assessment of Electricity Demand in the United States Using Panel Data and the Impact of Retail Competition on Prices

The Value of Branding in Two-Sided Platforms

One Markup to Rule Them All: Taxation by Liquor Pricing Regulation

Demand- how much of a product consumers are willing and able to buy at a given price during a given period.

Economics of Managerial Decision Making (MGEC 611) SAMPLE EXAM

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Transcription:

BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002) February 16, 2009 1 Nevo 2001 (Econometrica): Measuring market power in the ready-to-eat cereal industry Main question: The ready-to-eat (RTE) cereal industry is characterized by high price-to-cost margins (PCM) and high concentrations, and so has been accused of being an industry with collusive pricing behavior and intense nonprice competition. Nevo examines this argument by estimating the PCM and decomposing it into 3 sources: 1) that due to product differentiation, 2) that due to multiproduct firm pricing and 3) that due to price collusion. Basic idea: Use the BLP framework to estimate brand-level demand. Then use these demand estimates along with different pricing rules to back out PCMs. Compare these PCMs against crude measures of actual PCM to separate the different sources of the markup. 1.1 Demand Model Indirect utility is: u ijt = x j β i + α i p jt + ξ j + ξ jt + ɛ ijt (1) 1

uses brand-level dummy variables (fixed effects) to capture the mean characteristics of RTE cereal. Because the fixed effect picks up all characteristics (observed and unobserved), what s left as a structural error is the change in ξ j over time, or ξ jt. Need to have a rich data set to use fixed effects. Also includes demographic variables allows them to interact product characteristics (e.g. does a consumer have a child, interacted with if a cereal is sugary). Data are from the March Current Population Survey. e.g. α i = α + demographic component + demographic/random component Because has top 25 products over time, no change in characteristics or choice sets over time. So usual BLP instruments do not work. Paper has a nice section on instruments, which you should read. Nevo tries a couple of different instruments (all of which have their faults) to convince the reader of the robustness of the results. 1.2 Supply Model Suppose there are F firms each of which produces some subset of F f of the j = 1,..., J brands in the RTE cereal industry. Profits are given by Π f = (p j mc j )Ms j (p) C f (2) j F j where M is market size, s j is market share, mc is marginal cost and C is fixed cost. Assuming a Bertrand-Nash equilibrium in prices, the price p j of any product must satisfy the FOC s j (p) + r { j (p r mc r ) ds r(p) dp j = 0 (3) As before, define an ownership structure, where 1, if f : {r, j} F f ˆΩ jr = 0, otherwise (4) 2

and S jr = ds r dp j (5) and so Ω jr = ˆΩ jr S jr. Get the usual markup equation p mc = Ω 1 s(p) (6) Unlike BLP which solved for both demand and supply side simultaneously, Nevo does it separately (and so the demand side estimates do not depend on the supplyside assumptions). The advantage of of imposing a supply side is that the extra structure typically gives you smaller standard errors. Nevo can forego this b/c of the quality of his data. 1.3 Data a market is a city-quarter. market shares and prices in each market (65 cities) brand characteristics (e.g. fiber contents, sugary), advertising and demographic information (last two are extra ) period: 1988:Q1 to 1992:Q4 only uses 25 brands with the highest national market share Why limit the subsample? Not sure. In BLP (and others), main source of identification is the change in choice set over time. See how consumers react when products enter and exit. Here, there is no entry/exit. But do have lots of price variation. Perhaps the high amount of entry/exit of small products reflects dynamic forces (experimentation with characteristics, etc), that a static model would be bad at capturing. 3

1.4 Results Strategy is: estimate the demand side and compute the price elasticities. Then he can evaluate the PCM for three different industry conduct models. 1. single-product firms prices of each brand are set to maximize profits for that brand. Under this structure, see how much product differentiation drives PCM 2. current industry structure (multiproduct firms) Under this structure, see how much product differentiation and multiproduct profit maximization drives PCM 3. Joint profit maximization (i.e. collusion) Under this structure, see how collusive behavior and product differentiation drives PCM By comparing the PCM under the three structures can see which one matches the data best, as well as, decompose the sources of PCM. See table of price elasticities (Table VII) See table of median margins (Table VIII) In the data/literature: PCM estimates are 46%, lower bound of 31% and an upper bond of 64%. Conclusions: Collusion does not match the data (PCM would be much higher), but multiproduct pricing does. Large part of the PCM is driven by product differentiation. Final thought: There is a lot of entry and exit of products in cereal (not addressed here). Interesting to consider the endogeneity of product characteristics. 4

2 Petrin 2002 (Journal of Political Economy): Quantifying the Benefits of New Products: The Case of the Minivan Main question: What are the consumer welfare benefits from the introduction of the minivan? Basic idea: Augments the BLP framework with an extra set of moments (micro-moments), allows for more precise estimation of structural parameters. 2.1 Data Data set one (basic) List price and sales of new vehicles in the US from 1981 to 1993 an annual basis Vehicle characteristics (e.g. weight, horsepower) Data set two (extra) moments from Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) demographics of purchasers family size and age of head of household by vehicle type Nevo simply added demographics to indirect utility Petrin incorporates the demographics in the indirect utility & adds extra moments. 2.2 Demand Side Indirect utility is: u ij = X j β + α i log(y i p j ) + ξ j + k γ k ν ik x jk + ξ j + ɛ ijt (7) 5

where α 0, if y i ȳ 1 α i = α 1, if ȳ 1 y i ȳ 2 (8) α 2, if y i ȳ 3 and where (ȳ 1, ȳ 2 ) divide the US population into three equally sized groups. note: in general it is easier to forgo the log specification and use α y i p j. ν are draws from N(0, 1), measuring deviations from mean value of a characteristic Make parametric assumptions about how demographics influence tastes of characteristics, where (mi, sw) stand for minivan and station wagon, and fv stands for family vehicle. γ i,mi = γ mi log(familysize i )ν i,fv (9) γ i,sw = γ sw log(familysize i )ν i,fv (10) (11) where ν i,fv is the iid shock for family vehicles. This parameterization implies that larger families will prefer minivans and station wagons (as seen in the data). Example of building the model to reflect the data (i.e. CEX). Don t want to build in the results, but also want to give the model a chance. 2.3 Supply Side The usual framwork profits are: Π f = M j F f (p j mc j )s j (12) and you get easily derive the usual PCM equation. 6

2.4 Results Has the usual BLP moments E[ξ j (X, W )] = E[ω j (X, W )] = 0 where ω j are the structural errors on the supply side, and W are the observed components of cost. In addition, has 7 additional moments based on the data from the CEX. The first three pin down sensitivity to price E[{i purchases new vehicle {y i < ȳ 1 }], (13) E[{i purchases new vehicle {ȳ 1 < y i < ȳ 2 }], (14) E[{i purchases new vehicle {y i > ȳ 2 }] (15) and the last four deal with family vehicles E[fs i i purchases a minivan], (16) E[fs i i purchases a station wagon], (17) E[fs i i purchases a SUV], (18) E[fs i i purchases a fullsize van], (19) Add these additional 7 moments, by just stacking them with the BLP moments. Note the weighting matrix will be block-diagonal, since the two sets of moments come from independent sampling processes. Show table 4 in paper (highlight the α estimates) 2.5 Welfare analysis Compensating variation is used to measure changes in consumer welfare from the introduction of the minivan. This is the change in a consumer s income that equates utility in a particular economic environment to a choosen benchmark. Benchmark is the real world with minivans, alternative environment one without. Counterfactual, use the FOC on the supply side to solve for prices without minivans. 7

see Table 7 for some price changes when minivans disappear Compensating variation is the dollar amount needed to make consumers indifferent between counterfactual and real world. For purchases of minivans, how many dollars are needed to compensate them for buying something other than a minivan. see Table 8 for compensating variation. Note that OLS, IV, and RC all imply that minivan purchases dislike minivan characteristics relative to their second choice (see negative signs for obs char) which is implausible. Adding the micromoments fixes this. (Table 13 has compensating variation over all consumers). For change in profits, Petrin looks at markups in the observed case and in the counterfactual. See paper (table 11) for details. General Comment One needs to think carefully about how the model is designed and what is the main question to be answered. For example, if going after certain effects, adding moments can be key. Also, what you include in the model is a function of your question. For example, if going after welfare effects, it is crucial that the indirect utility inputs reflect stuff that you really believe could be in a person s utility function (e.g. horsepower). But if only going after price elasticities, that you can be more liberal and include things in the indirect utility that proxy for stuff you think are in the utility function. Petrin spends a lot of time comparing results from the simpl logit to the full-blown random-coefficients. The theme is that the simplier models rely too much on the iid logit error. Putting in more flexibility with the observed characteristics reduces the model s dependence on the error term, and, in turn, leads to more sensible results. 8