PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

Similar documents
Chapter 13. Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Entry and Merger Policy

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Nonlinear pricing of a congestible network good. Abstract

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Journal of Industrial Organization Education. Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

Competition in Two-Sided Markets

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

The Impact of Bargaining on Markets with Price Takers: Too Many Bargainers Spoil The Broth

Location Decisions of a Polluting Firm and the Time Consistency of Environmental Policy

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Search and Categorization

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS.

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

Measuring Market Power When Firms Price. Discriminate

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Commerce 295 Midterm Answers

Competition Policy Monopoly Competition Other. Bundling. Patrick Legros

Resale and Bundling in Multi-Object Auctions

INNOVATION, RENT EXTRACTION, AND INTEGRATION IN SYSTEMS MARKETS*

Instructions: must Repeat this answer on lines 37, 38 and 39. Questions:

Vertical Pricing and Parallel Imports

THE ECONOMICS OF MEDIA AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS

Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Introduction to Economics II: Producer Theory

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS THEORY, APPLICATIONS, AND CASES EIGHTH EDITION. W.Bruce Allen The Wharton School University of Pennsylvania

A few firms Imperfect Competition Oligopoly. Figure 8.1: Market structures

Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

Coalitions and Networks in Industrial Organization

CHAPTER 12 Pricing CHAPTER OUTLINE

Discussion Paper No. 16. Platform Ownership. Volker Nocke* Martin Peitz** Konrad Stahl*** July 2004

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

Tying in Two-Sided Markets

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Slides and Images, Worth Publishers Inc. 8-1

Imperfect Competition (Monopoly) Chapters 15 Mankiw

Third degree price discrimination. Welfare Analysis

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Equilibrium parallel import policies and international market structure

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Business Models for Media Firms: Does Competition Matter for how they Raise Revenue?

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Department of Economics, University of Oslo. ECON4820 Spring Last modified:

Product Improvement and Technological Tying in a Winner-Take-All Market. Richard J. Gilbert University of California

EconS Bundling and Tying

OLIGOPOLY AND TRADE. December 13, Abstract. In this chapter we present a selective analytic survey of some of the main results of trade under

Revisiting the Relationship between Competition and Price Discrimination in the Airline Industry

Pricing Information Goods: A Strategic Analysis of the Selling and On-demand Pricing Mechanisms

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Volume 30, Issue 3. Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly

"Nouvelle Loi de l Organisation du Marche de l électricité": Implications for the French Retail Market

Flexibility as an Instrument in Digital Rights Management

Chapter 15: Monopoly. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 1 / 83. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 2 / 83. Notes

ECMC02H Intermediate Microeconomics - Topics in Price Theory

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

Markus Reisinger: The Effects of Product Bundling in Duopoly

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Marginal Cost Pricing in Hydro-Thermal Power Industries: Is a Capacity Charge Always Needed? 1

Competition Between Open Source and Closed Source Software: The Contribution of Users

Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Duopoly Monopoly. The further right on the scale, the greater the degree of monopoly power exercised by the firm.

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Chapter 10: Monopoly

UC Berkeley Recent Work

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

7.1 The concept of consumer s surplus

Imperfect Competition

Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria", Games and Economic Behavior, 2, 29-46, 1990.

How to Sell Renewable Electricity - Interactions of the Intraday and Day-ahead Market Under Uncertainty

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

Competing for a Duopoly: International Trade and Tax Competition

Transcription:

THE JOURNAL O INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS 00-181 Volume LVII June 009 No. Notes on the Journal of Industrial Economics Website www.essex.ac.uk/jindec/ PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION LEVENT KUTLU w We examine the effects of price discrimination in the Stackelberg competition model for the linear demand case. We show that the leader does not use any price discrimination at all. Rather, the follower does all price discrimination. The leader directs all of its first mover preemptive advantage to attract the highest value consumers who pay a uniformly high price. We observe that profits and total welfare are larger and consumer surplus is smaller than those of the standard Stackelberg competition model. I would like to thank Marc Dudey for he was always there to guide me while I was writing this article. Moreover, I thank Goksel Asan, Baris Esmerok, Ozgur Inal, Robin Sickles, Sinan Ertemel, Tim Hazledine, the Editor and two anonymous referees for their comments and criticisms that substantially improved the paper. inally, I thank Benjamin Saxton for proofreading this article. w Author s affiliation: Department of Economics, Rice University, MS, P.O. Box 189, Houston, Texas 7751, U.S.A. e-mail: levent.kutlu@rice.edu 364

Price Discrimination in Stackelberg Competition Levent Kutlu y Abstract We examine the e ects of price discrimination in the Stackelberg competition model for the linear demand case. We show that the leader does not use any price discrimination at all. Rather, the follower does all price discrimination. The leader directs all of its rst mover preemptive advantage to attract the highest value consumers who pay a uniformly high price. We observe that pro ts and total welfare are larger and consumer surplus is smaller than those of the standard Stackelberg competition model. I. Introduction There is a large recent literature on price discrimination in oligopolistic contexts. 1 The literature varies in oligopoly models and types of discrimination considered. or example, Borenstein [1985] and Holmes [1989] examine third degree price discrimination in Bertrand models. Hazledine [006] examines second degree price discrimination in a Cournot model. In the second degree formulation, the rm is able to segment consumer demand by ranges of reservation price. Consumers with reservation price between r 1 and r pay one price, those between r and r 3 pay another, and so on. He shows that the output sold at a particular price is a multiple N of the output sold at the next lowest price, where N is the number of rms in the market. In this paper, we examine second degree price discrimination as modeled by Hazledine [006] and apply it to the Stackelberg formulation instead of Cournot. We nd that, in contrast to Hazledine s results, under the Stackelberg formulation, only the follower price discriminates. The leader directs all of its rst mover preemptive advantage to attract the highest value customers who pay a uniformly high price. The follower price discriminates over the residual demand. Another result of price discrimination is that pro ts and total welfare are larger and consumer surplus is smaller than those of the standard Stackelberg competition model. II. The Model and Results We consider a leader-follower duopoly with no cost of entry. Let c be the constant marginal cost of the leader and the follower. We assume that each consumer buys at most one unit of the good. The rms know valuations of the consumers and can prevent resale of the good. They divide the consumers into bins according to their reservation prices. The price of the good for the k th bin is given by: I would like to thank Marc Dudey for he was always there to guide me while I was writing this article. Moreover, I thank Goksel Asan, Baris Esmerok, Ozgur Inal, Patric Legros, Robin Sickles, Sinan Ertemel, and Tim Hazledine, and two anonymous referees for their comments and criticisms that substantially improved the paper. inally, I thank Benjamin Saxton for proof-reading this article. y Department of Economics, Rice University, MS, P.O. Box 189, Houston, TX 7751, USA. Contact: e-mail: levent.kutlu@rice.edu 1 See Stole (007) for a survey. 1

P k = a Q k (1) where Q k P k i=1 (qi L + qi ) is the total quantity sold in all bins from 1 to k. A good example for such a setting is airline seats o ered for a speci c route. Airline tickets are purchased in unit quantity and it is a common practice for airlines to price discriminate. or the airline case, one can think that consumers come to the market at di erent times and their valuations are inversely related with the length of time between purchase and ight. or example, business people learn of their travel plans at the last moment, and are willing to pay much more than tourists, who are at the other extreme and know their travel plans a year ahead of time. The linear demand assumes a continuum of people between these extremes. rom now on we will call the product an airline seat and a seller an airline. Before stating our results, we would like to remind the reader of some standard results from theories of monopoly and oligopolistic competition: A monopolist produces a c and each of the symmetric Cournot duopolist produces a c 3. inally, under the standard Stackelberg competition model, the leader produces a c a c, and the follower produces 4. Note that the leader produces the monopoly output which is more than the Cournot output. This is because of the strategic bene t of inducing the second mover to reduce output. In what follows, we state our propositions for Stackelberg model with price discrimination. Proposition 1 Suppose that price discrimination is permitted in a symmetric linear Stackelberg competition duopoly model with K bins. Then, in equilibrium, only the follower price discriminates. The equilibrium quantities and prices are: ql 1 = a c q j 1 = K + 1 P j = a (1+ j K + 1 )a and q j L = 0 for j = ; 3; :::; K a c for j = 1; ; :::; K c for j = 1; ; :::; K Proposition 1 shows that the leader allocates all its production to bin 1 and lets the follower do the discrimination. By doing this, the leader enjoys high pro ts from the high-end customers. The follower spreads its output equally among the bins. In order to explain the intuition for why the leader allocates all its production to bin 1, assume for now that K =. In addition to preempting the high-end consumer, the leader would preempt the low-end as well. But if the leader were to deviate from allocating all of its output to bin 1 and allocate some output to bin ; then this would induce the follower to allocate more output to bin 1. When the follower decides how much to allocate to bin 1, it takes into account the negative impact of an expansion in bin 1 output on the pro ts of bin. If the leader expands output in bin, then bin becomes less important to the follower which causes it to allocate more output to bin 1. The negative e ect on the leader s bin 1 consumers would o set the gains to the leader from obtaining bin consumers. This contrasts with the standard Stackelberg dynamics in which when the

leader expands output, the follower reduces output. Here, the follower lowers output in bin ; the problem for the leader is that the follower expands output in bin 1. Other implications of Proposition 1 are as follows: irst, as the number of the bins increases price converges to the marginal costs of the rms and the follower allocates essentially no output in bin 1. This is a vertical separation where the leader grabs the high-value consumers and leaves the lower ones to the follower. Second, one can show that if a monopolist can price discriminate, then it produces qm 1 = q M = a c 3. So, although in the standard Stackelberg model the leader produces the monopoly output (without price discrimination), if it can price discriminate, it produces less than the monopoly output (with price discrimination). inally, the price charged by the leader is higher than the Stackelberg competition price and the output-weighted price charged by the follower 3 is the same as the Stackelberg competition price. Proposition Suppose that price discrimination is permitted in a symmetric linear Stackelberg competition duopoly model with K bins. Pro ts of both the leader and the follower are higher compared to pro ts they would get in the standard Stackelberg competition. Although the consumer welfare is lower, the total welfare is higher. The pro ts, consumer welfare, and total welfare are: L = K (a c) > 1 (a c) = S L K + 1 4 4 = K (a c) > 1 (a c) = S K + 1 8 8 CW = K +5K + 3 (a c) (K + 1) < 9 (a c) 8 4 8 = CW S T W = 4K +8K + 3 (a c) (K + 1) > 15 (a c) = T W S 8 4 8 Proposition shows the welfare e ects of price discrimination. Because of the strategic interactions between the leader and the follower it might have been the case that the pro ts of both rms decrease as the degree of price discrimination increases. But it turns out that in our model the pro ts of both rms increase. Indeed, the pro t of the leader increases even though the quantity that it produces remains the same. The reason for this is that the follower abandons the high-value consumers to focus on the low-value ones. inally, note that total welfare monotonically converges to the socially optimal level of welfare, as K goes to in nity. Appendix The quantity of j th fare provided by the leader and the follower are q j L and qj ; respectively. Let Q j L P j i=1 qi L, Qj P j i=1 qi, Qj Q j L + Qj, and a c. We rst consider the decision problem of the follower. The pro t of the follower is given by: Note that in the case of price discrimination the leader produces the monopoly output without price discrimination. 3 i.e., P = P K i=1 P i q i P Ki=1 q i 3

(q L ) = q 1 (P 1 c) + q (P c) + ::: + q K (P K c) () = q 1 ( Q 1 ) + q ( Q ) + ::: + q K ( QK ) Di erentiating with respect to the decision variables q j order conditions for pro t maximization: for j = 1; :::; K gives the rst @ @q j = (Q j L +QK +q j ) = 0 for j = 1; ; ::; K (3) Then, 0 = @ @q j @ @q j 1 = q j 1 q j L q j (4) This implies that for all j = ; 3; :::; K q j L = qj 1 q j (5) Moreover, by equation (3) we have: q 1 L= q 1 Q K (6) Now, we solve the maximization problem of the leader. The pro t of the leader is given by: L = q 1 L(P 1 c) + q L (P c) + ::: + q K L (P K c) (7) = q 1 L( Q 1 ) + q L ( Q ) + ::: + q K L ( QK ) Substituting q j L and q1 L from equations (5) and (6) respectively gives: 4

L = ( q 1 QK )( Q 1 ) + (q 1 q )( Q )+::: + (q K 1 q K )( Q K ) (8) = ( q 1 QK )( (( q 1 QK ) + q 1 ))+ (q 1 q )( (( q 1 QK ) + q 1 +Q1 ))+. (q K 1 q K )( (( q 1 QK ) + q 1 +QK 1 )) = ( q 1 QK )Q K + (q 1 q )(Q K Q 1 )+. (q K 1 q K )(Q K Q K 1 ) = (( q 1 QK ) + (q 1 q ) + (q q3 ) + ::: + (q K 1 q K ))Q K ((q 1 q )Q 1 +(q q3 )Q 1 +::: + (qk q K )Q K 1 ) = ( Q K q K )Q K ((q 1 q )Q 1 +(q q3 )Q 1 +::: + (qk q K )Q K 1 ) KX = ( Q K )QK (q k ) k=1 By (8) we derive the rst order conditions for the leader as: @ L @q j = (Q K +qj ) = 0 for j = 1; ; :::; K (9) Hence, Q K +q j = for j = 1; ; :::; K (10) After summing (10) over j solving for Q K gives: Q K = K K + 1 (11) By (10) and (11) the follower s optimal quantity for the fare class j = 1; ; :::; K is given by: q j = 1 a K + 1 c (1) 5

By (5), (6), (11), and (1) the leader s optimal quantities for the fare class 1 is given by: ql 1 = a c (13) = 0 for j = ; 3; :::; K (14) q j L Given the quantities, both the calculation of prices and the proof of the Proposition are trivial; we leave them to the reader. References Borenstein, S., 1985, Price Discrimination in ree-entry Markets, RAND Journal of Economics, 16, 380-397 Corts, K., 1998, Third-degree price discrimination in oligopoly: All-out competition and strategic commitment, RAND Journal of Economics, 9, 306-33 Hazledine, T., 006, Price Discrimination in Cournot-Nash Oligopoly, Economics Letters, 93, 413-40 Holmes, T. J., 1989, The E ects of Third-Degree Price Discrimination in Oligopoly, American Economic Review, 79, 44-50 Stole, L.A., 007, Price Discrimination and Competition, M. Armstrong and R. Porter (ed.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. 3, Elsevier, chapter 34, 1-99 6