EconS Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Similar documents
EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Bundling and Tying

Introduction to Economics II: Producer Theory

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Agenda. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 1. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 2. Marginal Revenue. 3. Profit Maximization Exercise

Chapter 15: Monopoly. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 1 / 83. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 2 / 83. Notes

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

Commerce 295 Midterm Answers

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

INTERPRETATION. SOURCES OF MONOPOLY (Related to P-R pp )

Chapter 11. Monopoly. I think it s wrong that only one company makes the game Monopoly. Steven Wright

11.1 Monopoly Profit Maximization

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Pricing with Market Power

Chapter 11. Monopoly

MONOPOLY SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS: Quick Quizzes

Third degree price discrimination. Welfare Analysis

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Chapter 10: Monopoly

A few firms Imperfect Competition Oligopoly. Figure 8.1: Market structures

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Class Agenda. Note: As you hand-in your quiz, pick-up graded HWK #1 and HWK #2 (due next Tuesday).

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

Unit 8: Imperfect Competition II oligopoly and monopolistic competition

Monopoly and How It Arises

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Fundamentals of Markets

Midterm 1 60 minutes Econ 1101: Principles of Microeconomics October 8, Exam Form A

ECON 102 Kagundu Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Imperfect Competition (Monopoly) Chapters 15 Mankiw

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Comm295 Midterm Review Package. October, Content:

Labour Demand. 1 The Simple Model of Labour Demand. 2 De nitions (refreshing your memory) 3 Labour Demand in the Short Run.

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

1. Fill in the missing blanks ( XXXXXXXXXXX means that there is nothing to fill in this spot):

Econ 1A Fall, The first aim of all economic policy is to achieve efficiency. A necessary condition for efficiency is that p = mc.

COST OF PRODUCTION & THEORY OF THE FIRM

ECON December 4, 2008 Exam 3

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

EconS 301 Intermediate Microeconomics Review Session #9 Chapter 12: Capturing Surplus

Basic Monopoly Pricing and Product Strategies

Business 33001: Microeconomics

Pricing with Perfect Competition. Advanced Pricing Strategies. Markup Pricing. Pricing with Market Power

Lecture 13 - Price Discrimination

Gregory Clark Econ 1A, Winter 2012 SAMPLE FINAL

Consumer and Producer Surplus and Deadweight Loss

9.1 Zero Profit for Competitive Firms in the Long Run

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

ECON 251 Exam 2 Pink. Fall 2012

Homework 4 Economics

ECON 251 Practice Exam 2 Questions from Fall 2013 Exams

ECMC02H Intermediate Microeconomics - Topics in Price Theory

Monopoly Monopoly occurs when there is a single seller of a good or service. Despite this simple definition that is usually given in textbooks, we

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key Nov 13, 2007

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key March 23, 2011

SAMPLE MULTIPLE CHOICE FINAL EXAM CHAPTER 6 THE ANALYSIS OF COSTS

1. Suppose that policymakers have been convinced that the market price of cheese is too low.

Thursday, October 13: Short and Long Run Equilibria

AP Microeconomics Review With Answers

PICK ONLY ONE BEST ANSWER FOR EACH BINARY CHOICE OR MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTION.

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Econ 410: Micro Theory Monopoly, Monopsony, and Monopolistic Competition

iv. The monopolist will receive economic profits as long as price is greater than the average total cost

Chapter 2: The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply. Multiple Choice Questions

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

Perfectly Competitive Markets

ECON 202 2/13/2009. Pure Monopoly Characteristics. Chapter 22 Pure Monopoly

Economics 102 Summer 2015 Answers to Homework #2 Due Tuesday, June 30, 2015

Lecture 6 Pricing with Market Power

Chapter Summary and Learning Objectives

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

PRICING. Quantity demanded is the number of the firm s product customers wish to purchase. What affects the quantity demanded?

Economics. Monopoly. N. Gregory Mankiw. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Vance Ginn & Ron Cronovich C H A P T E R P R I N C I P L E S O F

Marginal willingness to pay (WTP). The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra unit of the good.

Special Pricing Practices. Managerial Economics: Economic Tools for Today s Decision Makers, 4/e

2007 NATIONAL ECONOMICS CHALLENGE NCEE/Goldman Sachs Foundation

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Lecture 20: Price Discrimination, Monopoly Rents and Social Surplus

Economics of Managerial Decision Making (MGEC 611) SAMPLE EXAM

1. Welfare economics is the study of a. the well-being of less fortunate people. b. welfare programs in the United States.

I enjoy teaching this class. Good luck and have a nice Holiday!!

Transcription:

EconS 425 - Third-Degree Price Discrimination Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41

Introduction Today, we ll nish our discussion of rst-degree price discrimination with a look at block pricing. Then we ll move on to third-degree price discrimination. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 2 / 41

Block Pricing Last time, we looked at two-part pricing, or as I like to call it, the "Costco model." Firms set an access fee, or xed price for the right to purchase from the monopolist, and then just charge a price of marginal cost per unit sold. By setting the xed price equal to the consumer surplus under perfect competition, the monopolist can capture all of the surplus for themself. Do you see any problem with this? Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 3 / 41

Block Pricing Consider two college best friends, Nathaniel and Wade. They both just graduated and are sharing an apartment while looking for jobs in their degree eld (neither of them majored in economics). They both love to eat chimichangas, with Wade liking them a bit more than Nate. Their local chimichanga stand knows this, and has implemented a two-part pricing scheme that charges Wade a much higher access fee than Nate. What can Nate and Wade do? Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 4 / 41

Block Pricing Nate and Wade could just have Nate go to the chimichanga stand, pay his access fee, then buy enough chimichangas for both himself and Wade. In fact, Wade could even give Nate some money to cover part of Nate s access fee. The monopolist loses more than half of its pro ts, while Nate and Wade get quite a bit of consumer surplus (in total among both of them). And chimichangas. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 5 / 41

Block Pricing Two-part pricing, by design, cannot prevent arbitrage. A consumer with a lower valuation can simply buy enough for everyone else. This is why we need another method: block pricing. In block pricing, the rm restricts the quantity sold to the consumer. Rather than letting a consumer pay an access fee and a per-unit cost, the rm charges a total fee T (x, q) to consumer x for a speci c quantity q. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 6 / 41

Block Pricing The rm can do this because they know each consumer s willingness to pay v(x, q). From this information, they can infer how much each consumer would buy in a perfectly competitive market, q C. Then they just set the total fee equal to the consumer s valuation for the perfectly competitive quantity, T (x, q C ) = v(x, q C ) Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 7 / 41

Block Pricing Now the consumers pay exactly the same amount as they would have under two-part pricing while purchasing the same amount. They simply can t choose how much they want to purchase. As before, this is an economically e cient arrangement, as everyone who should be in the market is in the market. Just a few more calculations. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 8 / 41

Third-degree price discrimination, also known as group pricing, can be utilized by a rm when they know that their market can be split into two or more groups, and they can also identify which consumers belong to which groups. These groups are usually easily identi able characteristics, like age, gender, etc. As long as the groups have di erent demand functions, the rm can charge di erent prices to each group to extract more pro ts. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 9 / 41

Fortunately, third-degree price discrimination is fairly straightforward. If a rm can segregate their market into subgroups, then they can treat each subgroup as if they were a separate market. Consider a case where there are n di erent identi able subgroups within a market. The rm s pro t maximization problem is max p 1 q 1 c(q 1 ) + p 2 q 2 c(q 2 ) +... + p n q n c(q n ) q 1,q 2,...q n {z } {z } {z } Pro t from Pro t from Pro t from subgroup 1 subgroup 2 subgroup n = max q 1,q 2,...q n n p i q i c(q i ) i=1 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 10 / 41

= max q 1,q 2,...q n n p i q i c(q i ) i=1 From here, we can take rst-order conditions, and we ll end up with n equations and n unknowns, with i from 1 to n, π q i = p 0 i (q i )q i + p i (q i ) c 0 (q i ) = 0 where p i (q i ) is the inverse demand function for subgroup i. The nice thing is that none of the rst-order conditions overlap. What we end up is an equation that is virtually identical to a monopolist s problem. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 11 / 41

You are a manager for a ski resort located in northern Idaho. Your boss has come to you with new market research data that indicates that your market demand function can be broken into two individual demand functions: the demand for people from Idaho, and the demand for people from the rest of the world. The inverse demand functions are as follows: and the total cost function is: Idaho: p = 6 1 2 q Not Idaho: p = 9 q TC = q + 1 6 q2 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 12 / 41

p p 9 6 MR D S MR D S 1 1 q Idaho Not Idaho q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 13 / 41

Idaho: p = 6 1 2 q Not Idaho: p = 9 q If we could only charge one price to this market, we would need to know the aggregate inverse demand function. First, we need to convert these two inverse demands back to demand functions, then add them to obtain Idaho: q = 12 2p Not Idaho: q = 9 p Q = 12 2p + (9 p) = 21 3p Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 14 / 41

Q = 21 3p From here, we convert back to an aggregate inverse demand function to obtain, 1 p = 7 3 Q Note: when p 6, the Idaho group will not purchase any goods. Thus, our piecewise inverse aggregate demand function is 9 Q if p 6 p = 1 7 3 Q if p < 6 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 15 / 41

p 9 6 MR D S 1 Market Q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 16 / 41

Visually, it appears that our solution exists where both subgroups of consumers are served (p < 6). Note: this may not always be the case. When a rm can only charge one price, it might be more pro table to cut out a segment of the market. Thus, we ll use that segment of the aggregate inverse demand function in our pro t maximization problem, 7 Q q + 16 q2 max Q with rst-order condition, 1 3 Q π Q = 7 2 3 Q 1 1 3 Q = 0 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 17 / 41

Rearranging terms, π Q = 7 2 3 Q 1 1 3 Q = 0 Q = 6 and plugging this back into the aggregate inverse demand function gives us our market price, p = 7 1 3 Q = 5 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 18 / 41

p 9 6 5 MR D S 1 6 Q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 19 / 41

Now, let s look at what happens when we can price discriminate. Let Idaho residents be subgroup 1 while non-idaho residents are subgroup 2. The rm s maximization problem is now max q 1,q 2 6 1 2 q 1 with rst-order conditions, q 1 q + 1 6 q2 1 + (9 q 2 )q 2 q + 1 6 q2 2 π q 1 = 6 q 1 1 π q 2 = 9 2q 2 1 1 3 q 1 = 0 1 3 q 2 = 0 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 20 / 41

π q 1 = 6 q 1 1 π q 2 = 9 2q 2 1 1 3 q 1 = 0 1 3 q 2 = 0 We can solve both of these rst-order conditions individually. Starting with the rst, rearranging terms, 4 3 q 1 = 5 q 1 = 15 4 And the second, rearranging terms, 7 3 q 2 = 8 q 2 = 24 7 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 21 / 41

q 1 = 15 4 = 3.75 q 2 = 24 7 3.43 Plugging these back into their respective inverse demand functions yield the group prices, p1 = 6 1 2 q 1 = 6 1 15 = 33 2 4 8 = 4.125 p2 = 9 q2 = 9 24 7 = 39 7 5.57 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 22 / 41

p p 9 6 4.125 MR D S 5.57 MR D S 1 1 q 3.75 Idaho 3.43 Not Idaho q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 23 / 41

Comparing our results before and after implementing price discrimination, Idaho - U Not Idaho - U Idaho - NU Not Idaho - NU p 5 5 4.125 5.57 q 2 4 3.75 3.43 π 6 12 8.41 10.39 The main thing to notice is that the Idaho residents are charged a lower price while the Not Idaho residents are charged a higher price relative to uniform pricing. This matches up with their relative elasticities. Lowering the price for Idaho residents brings in several new consumers to the market, while raising the price for Not Idaho residents does not drive that many out. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 24 / 41

Furthermore, total pro t for the monopolist also increases from 18 under uniform pricing to 18.8 under price discrimination (a 4% increase). We should expect this. Price discrimination should always increase pro ts for the monopolist. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 25 / 41

The result where price decreased for the more elastic group but increased for the less elastic group holds generally. We can even prove it by looking at a general pro t maximization function, max p pq(p) c(q(p)) and taking a rst-order condition with respect to p, q + p dq dp c 0 dq dp = 0 Rearranging terms, q + p dq dp = c0 dq dp Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 26 / 41

q + p dq dp = c0 dq dp Dividing both sides by dq dp and moving the q in the rst term to the denominator, + p = c 0 1 dq 1 dp q then I factor p out of the left-hand side of the equation,! p 1 dq dp p p q + 1 1 ε + 1 = c 0 = c 0 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 27 / 41

1 p ε + 1 = c 0 Rearranging this a bit more, I obtain price as a function of marginal cost and the price elasticity of demand, 1 + ε p = c 0 ε ε p = c 0 ε + 1 This is known as the inverse elasticity pricing rule, and it s a common shortcut used to nd a monopoly price when you have data on marginal cost and the price elasticity of demand. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 28 / 41

ε p = c 0 ε + 1 Now, let there be two di erent subgroups, and we ll assume that the price for subgroup 1 is higher than the price for subgroup 2, p 1 > p 2 Substituting the inverse elasticity pricing rule, c 0 ε1 > c 0 ε2 ε 1 + 1 ε 2 + 1 ε 1 ε 2 > ε 1 + 1 ε 2 + 1 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 29 / 41

Cross multiplying, ε 1 ε 1 + 1 > ε 2 ε 2 + 1 ε 1 (ε 2 + 1) > ε 2 (ε 1 + 1) ε 1 ε 2 + ε 1 > ε 1 ε 2 + ε 2 ε 1 > ε 2 Now we have to remember that the price elasticity of demand is negative while well behaved. Thus, when ε 1 > ε 2, this implies that subgroup 1 is less elastic than subgroup 2. Thus, the subgroup with the more inelastic demand pays the higher price. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 30 / 41

To calculate welfare e ects under third-degree price discrimination, we must look at each subgroup individually, regardless of whether we used uniform or price discrimination. Let s look at it graphically. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 31 / 41

p p 9 6 5 CS PS D DWL S CS PS D DWL S 1 1 q 2 Idaho 4 Not Idaho q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 32 / 41

p p 9 6 4.125 CS PS D DWL S 5.57 CS PS D DWL S 1 1 q 3.75 Idaho 3.43 Not Idaho q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 33 / 41

For the majority of cases, welfare decreases under third-degree price discrimination. Producer surplus rises, consumer surplus and deadweight loss can either rise or fall. Under speci c demand functions, welfare can increase. But those are rarely seen in the real world. There is one noteworthy special case, though! Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 34 / 41

What if, when under uniform pricing, all but one subgroup was left out of the market? Basically, the monopolist could earn higher pro ts by selling only to the consumers who will accept the high price. All of the surplus in the subgroup that was left out is deadweight loss. Let s adjust our resort example to see that. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 35 / 41

p p 9 D 4 D S MR S 1 1 MR q Idaho Not Idaho q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 36 / 41

p 9 6 4 MR D S 1 Market Q Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 37 / 41

In this case, under uniform pricing, the rm simply sets the monopoly price for the Not Idaho subgroup and ignores the Idaho subgroup. The rm receives the same pro ts from the Not Idaho subgroup as they would under third-degree price discrimination, but nothing for the Idaho group. It s all deadweight loss. By implementing third-degree price discrimination, the rm can get the Idaho subgroup into the market, converting some of the deadweight loss into welfare for both the rm and the Idaho consumers. This has no impact on the Not Idaho subgroup s welfare, so it is certainly welfare improving. Note: This is only guaranteed to work if only one rm is in the market under uniform pricing. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 38 / 41

Summary Block Pricing is a way for rms to get around the arbitrage problems inherent in two-part pricing. Third-degree price discrimination allows a rm to increase their pro ts by segregating the market into identi able subgroups. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 39 / 41

Next Time Second-degree price discrimination. Reading: 5.4. Note: This section is tough. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 40 / 41

Homework 2-4 A monopolist with marginal cost of production of 40 sells to two distinct regions. In Region 1, demand is given by: q 1 = 300 p 1. In Region 2, it is given by: q 2 = 180 p 2. 1. Determine the optimal uniform price and output when discrimination is impossible. 2. Assume the monopolist can discriminate between regions. What price and quantity will be set for each region? 3. How does the discriminatory price relate to the price elasticity of demand for each region? Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 41 / 41