Dynamic Vertical Collusion

Similar documents
The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Collusion. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Collusion February / 31

International Journal of Industrial Organization

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Vertical Integration and Foreclosure

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

PRIVATE LABELS, DUAL DISTRIBUTION, AND VERTICAL RESTRAINTS AN ANALYSIS OF THE COMPETITIVE EFFECTS

BUYER POWER AND EXCLUSION IN VERTICALLY RELATED MARKETS.

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Vertical integration and vertical restraints

Collusion. So be deviating Firm 1 s profits are: So for the proposed strategies to form an equilibrium it has to be the case that 1 1

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Beliefs, Market Size and Consumer Search

Competition Policy Monopoly Competition Other. Bundling. Patrick Legros

Shelf Space Fees and Inter-Brand Competition

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Product bundling and tying in competition

Exclusive Contracts with Complementary Inputs

Volume 30, Issue 3. Specialization through Cross-licensing in a Multi-product Stackelberg Duopoly

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

Entry and Merger Policy

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly.

Signaling Private Choices

No 250. Backward Ownership, Uniform Pricing and Entry Deterrence. Matthias Hunold

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Bundling Can Signal High Quality

Exclusivity and Control

An Economic Approach to Article 82

Dynamic Vertical Foreclosure

Forecast Information Sharing and Tacit Collusion in Supply Chains

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

Industrial Organization

Manufacturer Bundling and Price Discrimination With Heterogeneous Retail Markets

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

Part I PRELIMINARY. Part II MARKET DEFINITION ASSESSING SIGNIFICANT MARKET POWER. Part IV IMPOSITION OF OBLIGATIONS UNDER THE REGULATORY FRAMEWORK

Search markets: Introduction

Online Appendix (Not for Publication): Extensions to Raising Retailers Profits: On Vertical Practices and the Exclusion of Rivals

Comparative Price Signaling by a Multiproduct Firm

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality

Price-Fixing and. Repeated Games. Collusion and cartels. Recent events. Collusion and cartels 2. Cartels. Recent cartel violations 2

Working Paper No Can By-product Lobbying Firms Compete? Paul Pecorino

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure

Cartelization of Cross-Holdings

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

Portfolio Effects and Merger Control: Full-line Forcing as an Entry-Deterrence Strategy

Carlton & Perloff Chapter 12 Vertical Integration and Vertical Restrictions. I. VERTICAL INTEGRATION AND VERTICAL RESTRICTIONS A. Vertical Integration

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

UNIVERSITY OF VIENNA

Robust Exclusion and Market Division through Loyalty Discounts

Integrating Production Costs in Channel Decisions

Oligopoly. Quantity Price(per year) 0 $120 2,000 $100 4,000 $80 6,000 $60 8,000 $40 10,000 $20 12,000 $0

Bundling and Tying: Should Regulators Use the Per Se Approach or the Rule-of-Reason Approach? Lessons from the Economics Literature

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Application bundling in system markets

Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

1. INTRODUCTION IS IT POSSIBLE TO MOVE THE COPPER MARKET? MATTI LISKI AND JUAN-PABLO MONTERO *

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

Game theory and business strategy. Relative prices and backlog in the large turbine generator industry

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Vertical Integration, Foreclosure, and Productive

References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

Antitrust law rule. Infineon Technologies AG.

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Working papers of the Department of Economics University of Perugia (IT) Favoritism in public procurement auctions: model of endogenous entry

EXCLUSIVE CONTRACTS WITH COMPLEMENTARY INPUTS

An Analysis of Upstream and Downstream Interaction, From a View of Principal-Agent Relationship

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy. Game Theory: Inside Oligopoly

Portfolio Effects and Merger Control: Full-line Forcing as an Entry-Deterrence Strategy

Analytic Preliminaries for Social Acceptability of Legal Norms &

Chapter 10: Monopoly

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

Consumer Basket Information, Supermarket Pricing and Loyalty Card Programs

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

Bill-and-Keep vs. Cost-Based Access Pricing Revisited

Department of Economics, University of Oslo. ECON4820 Spring Last modified:

GUIDE TO COMPETITION LAW FEBRUARY 2014

Exclusivity rebates vs. predation: different paradigms?

Journal of Industrial Organization Education

Competition in Posted Prices With Stochastic Discounts

Buyer Power and Functional Competition for Innovation

Transcription:

Dynamic Vertical Collusion By David Gilo and Yaron Yehezkel* August 06 (first draft, August 04) Abstract: We show that when retailers and their supplier all care about future profits, collusion involving all of them is easier to sustain in a repeated game than collusion among retailers. This is so even when the supplier is as impatient as retailers are and even though vertical contracts are assumed to be secret. We also find that the more the retailers and the supplier care about future profits, retailers obtain a higher share of the monopoly profits. Furthermore, vertical collusion can enable the supplier to collect a higher wholesale price and make higher profits even when retailers have the bargaining power. Sustaining collusion requires retailers to commit to deal exclusively with the joint supplier and to charge slotting allowances. Keywords: vertical relations, tacit collusion, opportunism, slotting allowances JEL Classification Numbers: L4, L4, K, D8 * David Gilo: Buchmann Faculty of Law, Tel Aviv University (email: gilod@post.tau.ac.il); Yaron Yehezkel: Tel-Aviv Business School, Tel Aviv University (email: yehezkel@post.tau.ac.il). We thank Ayala Arad, Giacomo Calzolari, Bruno Jullien, Markus Reisinger, Patrick Rey, Tim Paul Thomes, Noam Shamir, Yossi Spiegel, as well as participants at the MaCCI 06 conference in Mannheim, the CRESSE 06 conference in Rhodes, and seminar participants at Tel-Aviv University, the Hebrew University, the Interdisciplinary Center in Hertzelia and Bar-Ilan University for helpful comments. We thank the Israeli Science Foundation and the Cegla Institute for financial assistance and Michael Leshem, Haim Zvi Yeger and Nofar Yehezkel for research assistance.

. Introduction This paper asks whether and how ongoing collusion involving not only retailers, but also their joint supplier (all of whom are strategic players caring about collusive profits) is more sustainable than collusion among retailers not involving the supplier. Often, in a certain geographic area, retailers fiercely compete over end consumers. Retailers would prefer to collude at the expense of consumers, but competition among them is often too intense to support such collusion. Retailers typically buy from a joint supplier, where all firms interact repeatedly. The supplier is typically a strategic player too, who, like retailers, cares about future profits. This raises the question: can including the supplier in the collusive scheme improve the prospects of collusion? Intuitively, when competing retailers do not place a high value on future profits, they may benefit from including a more patient supplier in their collusive scheme. It seems counterintuitive, however, that including a supplier that is as impatient as retailers are in the collusive scheme can help sustain it. After all, a short-sighted supplier, which can gain from deviating from the collusive scheme, may at first blush seem to be more of a burden to the collusive scheme than an asset. Also, how can such a collusive scheme survive when the contracts between the supplier and each retailer is not observable to the other retailer? Had each retailer been able to observe the other retailer s contract with the supplier, retailers could have made a credible commitment to each other to charge a high retail price, by paying the supplier an observable high wholesale price. But normally, vertical contracts between suppliers and retailers are not publicly observable, so one retailer does not know whether the supplier granted a secret discount to a competing retailer. Importantly, exchange of information among retailers competing in a downstream market regarding the terms of their contracts with a supplier is an antitrust violation. Since discounts given by the supplier to a retailer are secret, they encourage the See Department of Justice/Federal Trade Commission (000) (stressing that the exchange of current or future, firm specific, information about costs is most likely to raise competitive concerns); European Commission (0) ( the exchange of commercially sensitive information such as purchase prices and volumes may facilitate coordination with regard to sales prices and output and thus lead to a collusive outcome on the selling markets ); Federal Trade Commission (0) ( If the information exchanged is competitively sensitive that is, if it is information that a company would not normally share with its competitors in a competitive marketplace, such as supplier or cost information or other similar information companies should establish appropriate firewalls or other safeguards to ensure that the companies remain appropriately competitive throughout their cooperation."); OECD (00) (discussing an antitrust case brought by the South African Competition Commission and condemning information exchanges among competing buyers of raw milk regarding the prices paid to suppliers as a violation of the section forbidding illegal agreements); New Zealand Commerce Commission (04) (warning that information exchanges such as discussing supplier interactions with a competitor create an environment in which anti-competitive agreements or conduct can easily emerge. This creates significant risk for the parties involved, including employees. Such exchanges and discussions should be avoided."

retailer to charge a low retail price. Also, when the supplier is tempted to make such secret price cuts in favor of one retailer at the expense of the other retailer, even the supplier of a strong brand finds it difficult to commit to charging a high wholesale price. We show that when two competing retailers and a joint supplier interact repeatedly, and all of them are strategic players who equally care about future profits, they can increase their profits (at the expense of consumers) by engaging in a collusive scheme involving retailers and the supplier as well. We refer to such a scheme as vertical collusion. Each of the three firms has a short-run incentive to deviate from collusion and increase its own current-period profit at the expense of the other two, yet they collude because they all gain a share of future collusive profits, should they adhere to the collusive scheme in the current period. The three firms manage to do so even when retailers are too short-sighted to maintain standard horizontal collusion between themselves and even when the supplier is as short-sighted as the retailers are. Moreover, vertical collusion holds despite the fact that vertical contracts are secret. The supplier is willing and able to participate in the vertical collusion scheme because it enables the supplier to collect higher wholesale prices and make higher profits than absent collusion. Hence, even though retailers do not observe the supplier's price cuts to one retailer at the expense of the other, the supplier himself has an incentive to police its own and retailers' adherence to the collusive scheme. In the vertical collusive scheme we identify as an equilibrium, the higher wholesale price the supplier charges retailers reduces their short-term profits from deviating from collusion. At the same time, the supplier pays the retailers slotting allowances (fixed fees paid by suppliers to retailers in exchange for shelf space, promotional activities, and the like) in order to raise their long-term profits from collusion. The supplier s short-term gain from deviating from the collusive scheme involves rejecting one of the retailers contracts and saving the slotting allowances owed to this retailer. But if the supplier deviates, it sacrifices the ability to charge a higher wholesale price in future periods. The parties construct the vertical contracts so as to deter all of them from deviating from the collusive scheme. When a retailer attempts to deviate from the collusive price by offering the supplier a different vertical contract, the supplier, who also benefits from maintaining the collusive scheme, rejects the retailer s offer. Our base model considers undifferentiated retailers. We find that for any positive discount factor, there is an equilibrium in which retailers charge the monopoly price and earn positive profits. The supplier earns his share of the vertical collusive scheme by being able to collect a higher wholesale price and making a higher profit than absent collusion. We show that the more the supplier and retailers care about the future, retailers can maintain a higher share of collusive profits. The level of slotting allowances, however, is non-monotonic in the firms' discount factor: the more firms care about future profits, the level of slotting allowances first increases and then decreases. 3

We then show that the existence of a competing supplier causes the collusive scheme to break down. Retailers can restore the ability to sustain vertical collusion if they can commit to buy exclusively from one of the suppliers. We study whether such exclusivity can be maintained in a collusive equilibrium. We then extend our base model to the case of differentiated retailers. We find that our result according to which vertical collusion is easier to sustain than ordinary horizontal collusion carries over to this case as well. Unlike in the case of homogenous retailers, however, the three firms cannot sustain vertical collusion for any discount factor. We find that the less differentiated retailers are, vertical collusion becomes sustainable for a wider set of discount factors. With regard to policy implications, our results shed a new (and negative) light on various vertical restraints. In our framework, slotting allowances, coupled by exclusive dealing by retailers with a sole supplier, facilitate the vertical collusion scheme even though vertical contracts are secret. Current literature implies that such practices can facilitate downstream collusion only when vertical contracts are observable. This implies that slotting allowances and exclusive dealing deserve stricter antitrust treatment than currently believed. The results also imply that the Chicago School approach advocating lenient treatment of vertical restraints that eliminate downstream competition may not be justified. In particular, resale prices dictated or suggested by suppliers may equal the monopoly price, to the detriment of consumers, rather than be set at a level merely stimulating efficiencies in distribution. The supplier in our model pays the retailers slotting allowances, and hence the supplier s profits stem solely from the wholesale price it charges. It allegedly follows, according to the Chicago School s approach, that the supplier would want retail prices to be as low as possible, to maximize the number of units sold. Our results, however, imply that the supplier may want to dictate or suggest to the retailers to charge the monopoly retail price, since this is what drives the vertical collusive scheme. Our paper is related to several strands of the economic literature. The first strand involves vertical relations in a repeated infinite horizon game. Asker and Bar-Isaac (04) show that when entry of a new supplier requires accommodation by retailers, an incumbent supplier can exclude the new supplier by offering retailers, on an ongoing basis, part of his monopoly profits, via vertical practices such as resale price maintenance, slotting fees, and exclusive territories. Because retailers in their model care about future profits, they may prefer to keep a new supplier out of the market, so as to continue receiving a portion of the incumbent supplier s profits. At the same time, Chu (99), Lariviere and Padmanabhan (997), Desai (000) and Yehezkel (04) show that slotting allowances may also have the welfare enhancing effect of enabling suppliers to convey information to retailers concerning demand. See also Federal Trade Commission (00, 003), and European Commission (0) discussing some of the pro s and con s of slotting allowances. 4

Another part of this literature examines collusion among retailers, where suppliers are myopic. In particular, Normann (009) and Nocke and White (00) find that vertical integration can facilitate downstream collusion between a vertically integrated retailer and independent retailers. Piccolo and Miklós-Thal (0) show that retailers with bargaining power can collude by offering perfectly competitive suppliers a high wholesale price and negative fixed fees. Doyle and Han (0) consider retailers that can sustain downstream collusion by forming a buyer group that jointly offers contracts to suppliers. The rest of this literature studies collusion among suppliers, where retailers are myopic: Jullien and Rey (007) consider an infinite horizon model with competing suppliers where each supplier sells to a different retailer and offers it a secret contract. Their paper studies how suppliers can use resale price maintenance to facilitate collusion among the suppliers, in the presence of stochastic demand shocks. Nocke and White (007) consider collusion among upstream firms and the effect vertical integration has on such collusion. Reisinger and Thomes (05) analyze a repeated game between two competing and long-lived manufacturers that have secret contracts with myopic retailers. They find that colluding through independent, competing retailers is easier to sustain and more profitable to the manufacturers than colluding through a joint retailer. Schinkel, Tuinstra and Rüggeberg (007) consider collusion among suppliers in which suppliers can forward some of the collusive profits to downstream firms in order to avoid private damages claims. Piccolo and Reisinger (0) find that exclusive territories agreements between suppliers and retailers can facilitate collusion among suppliers. The main difference between our paper and this literature is that we examine collusion involving the whole vertical chain: supplier and retailers alike, who are all forward looking, and all have a short run incentive to deviate from collusion which is balanced against a long run incentive to maintain the collusive equilibrium. The second strand of the literature concerns static games in which vertical contracts serve as a devise for reducing price competition between retailers. Bonanno and Vickers (988) consider vertical contracts when suppliers have the bargaining power. They find that suppliers use two-part tariffs that include a wholesale price above marginal cost in order to relax downstream competition, and a positive fixed fee, to collect the retailers profits. Shaffer (99) and (005), Innes and Hamilton (006), Rey, Miklós-Thal and Vergé (0) and Rey and Whinston (0) consider the case where retailers have buyer power. In such a case, retailers pay wholesale prices above marginal cost in order to relax downstream competition and suppliers pay fixed fees to retailers. The difference between our paper and this strand of the literature is that we study a repeated game rather than a static game. This enables us to introduce the concept of vertical collusion, where the supplier, as well as retailers, care about future profits. Also, in this literature, vertical contracts are observable to retailers. We consider the prevalent case where vertical contracts are unobservable. 5

The third strand of literature involves static vertical relations in which a supplier behaves opportunistically by granting price concessions to one retailer at the expense of the other. Hart and Tirole (990), O Brien and Shaffer (99), McAfee and Schwartz (994) and Rey and Verg e (004) consider suppliers that make secret contract offers to retailers. They find that a supplier may behave opportunistically (depending on the retailers beliefs regarding the supplier s offer to the competing retailers) and offer secret discounts to retailers. Anticipating this, retailers do not agree to pay high wholesale prices and the supplier cannot implement the monopoly outcome. The vertical collusive scheme we identify resolves the opportunism problem exposed in the above literature and restores the supplier s power to charge high wholesale prices. If a supplier and one of the retailers in our model behave opportunistically in a certain period, vertical collusion breaks down in the next periods. Since the two retailers and the supplier all care about future profits, this serves as a punishment against opportunistic behavior.. The model Consider two downstream retailers, R and R that compete in prices. In our base model, we focus on the extreme case where retailers are homogeneous. Doing so enables us to deliver our main results in a clear and tractable manner. In section 5, we show that the qualitative results of the base model extend to markets with differentiated retailers. Retailers can obtain a homogeneous product from an upstream supplier. Production and retail costs are zero. Consumers' demand for the product is Q(p), where p is the final price and pq(p) is concave in p. Let p* and Q* denote the monopoly price and quantity, where p* maximizes pq(p) and Q*=Q(p*). The monopoly profit is p*q*. The two retailers and the supplier interact for an infinite number of periods and have a discount factor,, where 0. The timing of each period is as follows: Stage : Retailers offer a take-it-or-leave-it contract to the supplier (simultaneously and non-cooperatively). Each R i offers a contract (w i,t i), where w i is the wholesale price and T i is a fixed payment from R i to the supplier that can be positive or negative. In the latter case the supplier pays slotting allowances to R i. The supplier observes the offers and decides whether to accept one, both or none. All of the features of the bilateral contracting between R i and the supplier are unobservable to R j (j i) throughout the game. Moreover, R i cannot know whether R j signed a contract with the supplier until the end of the period, when retail prices are observable. The contract offer is valid for the current period only. 3 3 See Piercy (009), claiming that large supermarket chains in the UK often change contractual terms, including the wholesale price and slotting allowances, on a regular basis, e.g., via e-mail correspondence; Lindgreen, Hingley and Vanhamme (009), discussing evidence from suppliers regarding large 6

Stage : The two retailers set their retail prices for the current period, p and p, simultaneously and non-cooperatively. Consumers buy from the cheapest retailer. In case p = p, each retailer gains half of the demand. At the end of the stage, retail prices become common knowledge (but again retailers cannot observe the contract offers). If in stage the supplier and R j didn't sign a contract, R i only learns about it at the end of the period, when R i observes that R j didn't set a retail price for the supplier's product (or equivalently charged p j = ). Still, R i cannot know why R j and the supplier didn t sign a contract (that is, R i doesn't know whether the supplier, R j, or both, deviated from the equilibrium strategy). We consider pure-strategy, perfect Bayesian-Nash equilibria. We focus on symmetric equilibria, in which along the equilibrium path both retailers choose the same strategy, equally share the market and earn identical profits. We allow an individual retailer to deviate unilaterally outside the equilibrium path. When there is no upstream supplier and the product is available to retailers at marginal costs, retailers only play the second stage in every period, in which they decide on retail prices, and therefore the game becomes a standard infinitely-repeated Bertand game with two identical firms. Then, a standard result is that horizontal collusion over the monopoly price is possible if: p * Q* p * Q* where the left hand side is the retailer s sum of infinite discounted profit from colluding on the monopoly price and gaining half of the demand and the right hand side is the retailer's profit from slightly undercutting the monopoly price and gaining all the demand in the current period, followed by a perfectly competitive Bertrand game with zero profits in all future periods. Given this benchmark value of = /, we ask whether the prospects of vertical collusion, involving retailers and the supplier as well, are higher than horizontal collusion between the retailers. This analysis will take account of the fact that one retailer s two-part-tariffs are unobservable to the competing retailer throughout the game and both retailers and the supplier equally care about future profits., 3. Competitive static equilibrium benchmark supermarket chains dealing with them without written contracts and with changing price terms; See also How Suppliers Get the Sharp End of Supermarkets' Hard Sell, The Guardian, http://www.theguardian.com/business/007/aug/5/supermarkets. 7

The result that retailers cannot earn positive profits in any competitive equilibrium suggests that in a dynamic, infinitely repeated game, retailers have an incentive to engage in tacit collusion. They cannot sustain horizontal collusion, however, for discounts factors below half. The supplier has an incentive to participate in a collusive equilibrium when the supplier expects that otherwise retailers will play a competitive equilibrium involving π C < p*q*. In this section we solve for a competitive equilibrium benchmark in which the three firms have = 0. This can also be an equilibrium when > 0 and the three firms expect that their strategies in the current period will not affect the future. This benchmark is needed for our analysis because we will assume that an observable deviation from vertical collusion will result in playing the competitive equilibrium in all future periods. The main result of this section is that in the static game price competition dissipates all of the retailers profits. Moreover, since contracts are secret and the supplier has an incentive to act opportunistically, there are equilibria in which the supplier earns below the monopoly profits. In a symmetric equilibrium, in stage both retailers offer the contract (T C, w C ) that the supplier accepts. Then, in stage, both retailers set p C and equally split the market. Each retailer earns (p C w C )Q(p C )/ T C and the supplier earns w C Q(p C ) + T C. Since vertical contracts are secret, there are multiple equilibria, depending on firms' beliefs regarding off-equilibrium strategies. In what follows, we characterize the qualitative features of these equilibria. First, notice that in any such equilibrium p C = w C, because in the second stage retailers play the Bertrand equilibrium given w C. Therefore, there is no competitive equilibrium with T C > 0, because retailers will not agree to pay a positive fixed fee in stage, given that they don't expect to earn positive profits in stage. There is also no competitive equilibrium with T C < 0. To see why, notice that the supplier can profitably deviate from such an equilibrium by accepting only one of the contracts, say, the contract of R i. R i expects that in equilibrium both of the retailers' offers are accepted by the supplier. R i cannot observe the supplier's deviation of not accepting R j's contract. Accordingly, in stage R i sets the equilibrium price p C. The supplier's profit is w C Q(w C ) + T C -- higher than the profit from accepting both offers, w C Q(w C ) + T C whenever T C < 0. Therefore, in all competitive equilibria, T C = 0. Next, consider the equilibrium wholesale price in the competitive static equilibrium benchmark, w C. The equilibrium value of w C depends on the beliefs regarding out-ofequilibrium strategies. In particular, when R i makes a deviating offer that the supplier accepts, R i cannot observe whether the supplier accepted R j's equilibrium offer, and therefore needs to form beliefs concerning the supplier's response to such a deviation. Suppose that the three firms share the following belief: When R i's offer to the supplier deviates from the equilibrium contract, making it worthwhile for the supplier to reject R j's offer, the supplier indeed rejects R j's offer. These beliefs are close in nature to the wary beliefs discussed in McAfee and 8

Schwartz (994) and in what follows we adopt the same terminology. 4 At first blush, it might be thought that the optimal deviation for R i and the supplier is to a contract with w i = 0, that the supplier accepts, while rejecting R j's offer. With such a deviation, R i can set the monopoly price p*, maximize the joint profits of the supplier and himself, and share these profits with the supplier via T i. Given that R i offered to pay the supplier w i = 0, however, the supplier has the incentive to behave opportunistically and accept R j's offer to pay a positive wholesale price. Under wary beliefs, R i expects such opportunistic behavior, and hence will not offer to pay the supplier w i = 0. The following lemma characterizes the set of competitive static equilibria under wary beliefs. It shows that in the competitive benchmark case, retailers make zero profits, while the supplier makes a positive profit: Lemma : Suppose that = 0. Then, under wary beliefs, there are multiple equilibria with the contracts (T C, w C ) = (0, w C ), w C [w L, p*], where w L is the lowest solution to C C max{ wq( p( w ))} w Q( w ) where p( w ) argmax{( p w ) Q( p)}, () wi i i i i p and 0 < w L p*. In equilibrium, retailers set p C and earn 0 and the supplier earns π C w C Q(w C ), π C [w LQ(p(w L)), p*q*]. Proof: see the Appendix. Notice that there is a competitive static equilibrium in which the supplier earns the monopoly profit, p*q*. Intuitively, this equilibrium holds because the supplier can implement the monopoly outcome by dealing with only one of the retailers. Given that R j offers w j = p* and expects that R i does the same, R i cannot profitably deviate to any other contract than w i = p*, because the supplier can earn p*q* by accepting R j's contract offer alone. In what follows, we rule out the equilibrium with C = p*q* for two reasons. First, this equilibrium is an artifact of our simplifying assumption that retailers are homogeneous. The equilibrium does not hold when retailers are even slightly differentiated, because in such a case the supplier needs to deal with both retailers in order to implement the monopoly outcome. The second reason is that as shown in the next section, retailers' profits in the collusive equilibrium are decreasing with C. Consequently, retailers have an incentive to coordinate on a punishment strategy in which following a deviation from collusion they play the competitive equilibrium that provides the supplier with the lowest profit possible. 4 In McAfee and Schwartz (994), under "wary beliefs" a retailer believes that if the supplier offered him a contract that deviates from the equilibrium contract, the supplier offers the competing retailer a contract that maximizes the joint profit of the supplier and competing retailer. 9

As we will show in the next section, other than our assumption that C < p*q*, the qualitative features of the collusive equilibrium do not depend on the value of C. 5 4. Vertical collusive equilibrium with infinitely repeated interaction 4.. The condition for sustainability of the collusive equilibrium The result that retailers cannot earn positive profits in any competitive equilibrium suggests that in a dynamic, infinitely repeated game, retailers have an incentive to engage in tacit collusion. They cannot sustain horizontal collusion, however, for discount factors below half. The supplier, for its part, has an incentive to participate in a collusive equilibrium when it expects that otherwise retailers will play a competitive equilibrium involving π C < p*q*. In this section, we solve for the collusive equilibrium in an infinitely repeated game when > 0. In this equilibrium, in the first stage both retailers offer the same equilibrium contract, (w*,t*) that the supplier accepts. Then, in stage, both retailers set the monopoly price, p*, and equally split the monopoly quantity, Q*. Given an equilibrium w*, each retailer earns in every period R(w*) = (p* w*)q*/ T* and the supplier earns in every period S(w*) = w*q* + T*. In order to support the collusive scheme, the contract (w*,t*) must prevent deviations from this scheme. R i can observe whether R j deviated from the monopoly retail price p*, thereby dominating the downstream market. R i cannot observe, however, whether this deviation is a result of R j offering the supplier a different contract than (w*,t*), which motivates R i to deviate from the monopoly price, or whether R j offered the supplier the equilibrium contract (w*,t*), but nevertheless undercut the monopoly price. It is only the supplier and R j that will know which type of deviation occurred. R i can also observe whether R j did not carry the product in a certain period. R i cannot tell, however, whether this is a result of a deviation by R j (i.e., R j offered a different contract than (w*,t*) that the supplier rejected) or by the supplier (i.e., R j offered the equilibrium contract (w*,t*), but the supplier rejected). Finally, another type of deviation is when R i offers a contract different than (w*,t*) that the supplier accepted, but then R i continued to set p*. R j will never learn of this deviation, since contracts are secret. Because of the dynamic nature of the game and the asymmetry in information, there are multiple collusive equilibria. We therefore make the following restrictions. First, suppose that whenever a publicly observable deviation occurs (i.e., a retailer sets a different price than p* or does not carry the product), retailers play the competitive equilibrium defined in section 3 in all future 5 It is possible to show that if retailers have "passive beliefs" according to the definition in McAfee and Schwartz (994), then any w C [0, p*] and therefore any C [0, p*q*] can be an equilibrium. 0

periods. 6 Second, since we concentrate here on retailers with strong bargaining power, we focus on outcomes that provide retailers with the highest share of the monopoly profit that ensures the supplier at least its competitive equilibrium profit, C. 7 To solve for the collusive equilibrium, we first consider necessary conditions on (w*,t*). Then, we show that these conditions are also sufficient. The first condition is that once retailers offered a contract (w*, T*) that the supplier accepted, R i indeed plays in stage the monopoly price p* rather than deviating to a slightly lower price. By deviating, R i gains all the demand in the current period, but stops future collusion. R i will not deviate from collusion in the second stage if: ( p * w*) Q* ( p * w*) Q* T * ( p* w*) Q*, )( where the left hand side is R i s profit from maintaining collusion and the right hand side is R i s profit from deviating. Notice that condition () is affected only by the retailers' discount factor and not by the supplier's, because this constraint involves a deviation by a retailer assuming the supplier had not deviated: he played the equilibrium strategy and accepted the two equilibrium contract offers in stage. The second necessary condition is the supplier's participation constraint: w* Q* T * w* Q* T * C. (3) The left hand side is the supplier's profit from accepting the two equilibrium contracts and thereby maintaining collusion. The right hand side is the supplier's profit from accepting only one of the contracts. If the supplier rejects R i s offer, R j can detect this deviation only at the end of stage, when R j observes that R i doesn't offer the product. Therefore, in stage R j will still charge the monopoly price p* and sell Q*, implying that the supplier earns in the current period w*q* + T* and collusion breaks down in all future periods, in which the supplier earns C. If the left hand side of (3) is higher than the right hand side, then R i has the incentive to deviate to a contract with a lower T i, that the supplier would accept, since even with this lower T i, the supplier prefers collusion to deviation. If the right hand side of (3) is higher than the left hand side, then when both retailers offer the equilibrium contract, the supplier will deviate from the equilibrium strategy in stage and accept only one of the contracts. Therefore, condition (3) 6 We consider an alternative trigger strategy in section 4.5. 7 Retailers may also be able to coordinate on the competitive equilibrium outcome and choose the lowest C possible, w LQ(w L). Our qualitative results do not rely on the size of C, however, as long as collusion is weakly beneficial to all three firms (i.e., C < p*q*). Accordingly, we solve for the collusive equilibrium for any arbitrary C.

must hold in equality. Notice that this condition is affected by the supplier's discount factor only, and not by the retailers' discount factor, because it deals with the supplier's deviation given that retailers had offered the equilibrium contracts. Extracting T* from (3) and substituting into R(w*), we can rewrite the supplier and retailers one-period profits as a function of w* as: C C R( w*) p* w* Q*/, S( w*) w* Q*. (4) As can be expected, R(w*) is decreasing in w* while S(w*) is increasing in w*. The two conditions above ensure that the supplier accepts the two equilibrium contracts and that each retailer sets p* if the supplier accepts its equilibrium contract. The remaining requirement is that R i does not find it profitable to deviate in stage to any other contract. To examine this requirement, suppose that in a certain period, R i offers some deviating contract, (w i, T i) (w*, T*). As in the competitive, static case, the benefit to R i and the supplier from such a deviation depend on their out-of-equilibrium beliefs concerning each other's future strategies given the deviation. In particular, when deciding whether to accept the deviating contract, the supplier needs to form beliefs on whether this contract will motivate R i to set the monopoly retail price or undercut it. Likewise, if the supplier accepts the deviating contract, R i needs to form beliefs on whether the supplier accepts the equilibrium contract of R j as well. We apply wary beliefs as follows. Suppose R i deviated to (w i, T i) (w*, T*). If this deviation induces R i to undercut the monopoly retail price, the supplier correctly anticipates this fact and rejects R j s contract (since R j will make no sales). R i, in turn, understands that the supplier will behave in this manner. Conversely, if the deviation does not induce R i to undercut the monopoly retail price, the supplier anticipates this and accepts R j s contract, and R i again understands that the supplier will behave in this manner. 8 Proposition below shows that given wary beliefs, conditions (), (3) and S(w*) C, R i cannot profitably deviate to any (w i, T i) (w*, T*). Therefore, conditions (), (3) and S(w*) C are also sufficient for sustainability of the collusive equilibrium. Proposition also characterizes the unique collusive contract that maximizes the retailers' profits subject to (), (3) and S(w*) C. 8 It is possible to show that when the supplier is "naive" and wrongly anticipates that any contract deviation will not motivate R i to undercut the monopoly retail price, all collusive equilibria fail for < /.

Proposition : Suppose that > 0. Then, under wary beliefs, there is a unique collusive equilibrium that maximizes the retailers profits subject to (), (3) and S(w*) > C. In this equilibrium: ( p* Q* C ) p * ; (0, ]; ( ) Q* w* C ; [,]; Q* (5) ( )( * * C p Q ); (0, ]; and : T* 0; [,]. Proof: see the Appendix. (6) Substituting (5) into (4) yields that the retailers and the supplier earn in equilibrium R* R(w*) and S* S(w*) where: ( * * C p Q ); (0, ]; R* ( p* Q* C ); [,]; ( ) * * C p Q ; (0, ]; S* C ; [,]. (7) 4.. The features of the retailers' most profitable collusive equilibrium Let SA* = T* denote the equilibrium slotting allowance. The following corollary describes the features of the retailers most profitable vertical collusion equilibrium, while figure illustrates the retailers' most profitable vertical collusion equilibrium as a function of. Corollary : In the retailers most profitable collusive equilibrium: (i) For (0, /]: retailers' one-period profits are increasing with while the supplier's one-period profit is decreasing with ; the equilibrium wholesale price is decreasing with ; The supplier pays retailers slotting allowances: SA* > 0. The slotting allowances are an inverse U-shape function of. (ii) For [/, ]: the equilibrium wholesale price and the firms' profits are independent of and retailers do not charge slotting allowances: T* = 0; the supplier earns its reservation profit (from the competitive equilibrium) and retailers earn the remaining monopoly profits. 3

p* C S Q * w* 0 Panel (a): The equilibrium w* as a function of SA* 0 Panel (b): The equilibrium SA* as a function of p*q* C ( * * ) p Q S C S 0 Panel (c): The firms equilibrium profits as a function of R * S * Figure : The features of the retailers most profitable equilibrium as a function of 4

Figure and part (i) of Corollary reveal that at 0, w* p*, SA* 0 the supplier earns most of the monopoly profits. As increases, w* decreases and retailers gain a higher proportion of the monopoly profits. Moreover, the equilibrium slotting allowances are an inverse U-shaped function of. The intuition for these results is as follows. Consider first the case where = 0. Since retailers do not care about the future, the only possible w* that motivates a retailer to set the monopoly price in stage is w* = p*. For any other w* < p*, an individual retailer will deviate in stage to a price slightly below p* and monopolize the market, ignoring the negative effect of doing so on future profits. Since the supplier also does not care about the future, and since w* = p*, retailers cannot charge slotting allowances. To see why, notice that if R i asks for a slotting allowance, the supplier can reject R i's contract and earn S(w*) = w*q* = p*q* from accepting the contract of R j and ignoring the negative effect of breaking collusion in the future. As a result, with w* = p* and without slotting allowances, a collusive equilibrium requires the supplier to gain all of the monopoly profits. However, in such a case retailers have week incentives to participate in the collusive equilibrium to begin with. Suppose now that increases slightly above 0. In this case retailers have two complementary ways to collect a positive share of the monopoly profit from the supplier. First, now R i can charge slotting allowances. If the supplier rejects R i's contract and accepts only R j's contract, the supplier earns a one-period profit close to the monopoly profit in the current period, but collusion breaks in future periods. Since now the supplier cares about the future, R i can ask for slotting allowances, which the supplier accepts, just in order to maintain collusion in the following periods. The second option that R i can use in order to gain a positive share of the monopoly profit is by reducing w* below p*. Now that retailers care about the future, they can sustain collusion even for a smaller w*. Intuitively, the higher is w*, the lower is R i's profit margin, and the lower is its short-term profit from deviating from p* in stage. To see why, notice that whenever R i sets p*, R i earns in the current period a profit margin of p* w* on half of the monopoly quantity, while by deviating to a slightly lower price than p*, R i can earn a profit margin p* w* on all the monopoly quantity. Accordingly, when = 0 the only possible collusion-supporting wholesale price is w* = p*. However, when is slightly higher than 0, R i cares about the future, and in stage will charge the monopoly price even when w* < p*. Hence, when > 0, R i can exploit the supplier's concern about future profits (through condition (3)) in order to charge slotting allowances and can exploit its own concern about future profits (through condition ()) in order to reduce w*. Therefore, in equilibrium, retailers ask for slotting allowances and set w* < p*, both enabling them to gain a positive share of the monopoly profit. As increases, the supplier's incentive to maintain collusion increases, and retailers can take 5

advantage of it by offering a contract that allocates to them a higher share of the monopoly profit. As a result, the retailers' profits increase with while the supplier's profit decreases with. This also explains why the equilibrium w* decreases with. As increases, retailers have more of an incentive to maintain the collusive equilibrium, and therefore a lower w* is sufficient for motivating retailers not to undercut the monopoly price in stage. The effect of on the level of slotting allowances is non-monotonic, because has two opposite effects on the level of slotting allowances. First, there is a positive direct effect, because the more the supplier cares about the future, the higher the slotting allowances the supplier is willing to pay to maintain collusion. Second, an indirect negative effect, because as increases, w* decreases. This in turn reduces the supplier's willingness to pay slotting allowances. The first effect dominates for low values of while the second effect dominates for high values of. Part (ii) of Corollary reveals that when > /, retailers sufficiently care about the future to maintain horizontal collusion, without the supplier s participation. Accordingly, retailers keep the supplier on its profit when collusion breaks down, C, and earn the remaining monopoly profits. As a result, the firms' profits and the equilibrium contract are not a function of. The intuition follows from the benchmark case in section, where two firms that compete in prices can maintain horizontal collusion on their own for > /. Corollary shows that as increases, retailers gain a higher share of collusive profits and the supplier s share diminishes, while when is small, retailers have a smaller share of the collusive profits, and most of the monopoly profits go to the supplier. This implies that even though retailers have all of the bargaining power and are asking (and receiving) slotting allowances, they are not always the main beneficiaries of the collusive scheme. Finally, we are interested in asking whether retailers can maintain a collusive equilibrium when they cannot charge T*<0. Notice that the answer to this question does not directly follow from proposition, because this proposition only shows that the retailers most profitable collusive equilibrium involves slotting allowances. It is yet to be determined whether a collusive equilibrium is still possible when retailers cannot charge negative fees. In the context of this model, the following corollary shows that for (0, /], firms cannot maintain any collusive equilibrium without using slotting allowances. Corollary : If < /, then there are no contracts (w*, T*) that can maintain a collusive equilibrium with T* 0. Proof: see the Appendix. 6

The intuition for corollary is that a high wholesale price has two conflicting effects on the retailers' incentive to participate in vertical collusion. First, a positive short-run effect, in that a high wholesale price decreases the profit a retailer can earn in the current period by undercutting the collusive price. Second, a long-run negative effect, because a high wholesale price (also to be paid in future periods) decreases the retailer's future profits from maintaining collusion. In order to offset the second, negative effect, future contracts need to involve fees paid by the supplier to the retailer. Notice that in the current period, the retailer earns the slotting allowance regardless of whether the retailer charges the collusive price or not. These fees are set in the first stage of the current period and will have already been paid in the second stage of the current period, when the retailer sets its price. Nevertheless, the retailer knows that if it does not charge the monopoly price in the current period, he will not receive slotting allowances in future periods. This is what induces the retailer to maintain collusion in the current period. 4.3 Competition among suppliers Until now, we have assumed that the supplier is a monopoly. Because the monopolistic supplier cares about future profits, he enables vertical collusion even for < ½, where ordinary horizontal collusion breaks down. An important question is whether competition among suppliers causes the collusive scheme to break down. The main conclusion of this section is that retailers cannot maintain the collusive equilibrium when they have the option to buy the input from a competitive supplier. Suppose now that the market includes a dominant supplier, S, and a competitive supply market, which consists of one or more identical suppliers, S S n. The dominant supplier discounts future profits by while the competitive suppliers are myopic. We ask whether the two retailers can sustain a collusive equilibrium in which they offer only the dominant supplier a contract (w*,t*) that the dominant supplier accepts, and then charge consumers p*. As before, we assume that any observable deviation in period t triggers the competitive equilibrium from period t + onwards. We further assume that in this competitive equilibrium, all firms earn zero. That is, C = 0. In order to maintain a collusive equilibrium, the collusive contract has to satisfy conditions () and (3). In addition, the collusive contract needs to eliminate the incentive of R i to deviate from collusion by offering the collusive contract to the dominant supplier and at the same time making a secret contract offer to a competing supplier with w i = T i = 0 (we are assuming, for now, that R i may not offer the dominant supplier to buy exclusively from it, and later relax this assumption). To see the profitability of such a unilateral deviation, suppose that R j plays according to the proposed equilibrium by offering (w*,t*) to the dominant supplier 7

only, but the deviating retailer, R i, offers (w*,t*) to the dominant supplier and at the same time makes a secret offer to S with w i = T i = 0. The dominant supplier will accept both offers, because it is unaware of R i's secret offer to S. Hence R i will earn a slotting allowance, T* > 0, from the dominant supplier. Moreover, R i can then charge consumers a price slightly below p*, dominate the market and earn p*q* T*. If this deviation is profitable for R i even though it breaks down collusion in all future periods, the collusive equilibrium fails. Therefore, the equilibrium requires that R i s discounted future profits from the collusive equilibrium are higher than a one-period deviation in which R i buys from the competitive supplier. That is: ( p* w) Q*/ T * p* Q* T *. To see whether this condition holds, recall from equation (7) that the highest sum of discounted profits that a retailer can earn in a collusive equilibrium the retailers' most profitable collusive equilibrium is p*q*/( ) (note that when collusion breaks down C = 0). According to corollary, in any collusive equilibrium T* < 0, and hence the lowest profit that a retailer can make by making a secret offer to a competitive supplier, is p*q*. However: p* Q* p* Q*, (8) implying that R i will deviate from this collusive equilibrium by making the secret offer to the competing supplier. The following corollary summarizes this result: Corollary 3: Suppose that the upstream market includes a dominant supplier and a competitive supply market. Then, if < ½, there is no collusive equilibrium in which the two retailers sign in every period a contract with a dominant supplier. Intuitively, for < ½, retailers are too short-sighted and have a strong incentive to deviate from collusion. A dominant supplier is therefore needed in order to engage in vertical collusion, since otherwise collusion breaks down. But when retailers can buy the product at w = 0 from a competitive supplier, the dominant supplier s ability to support vertical collusion is eliminated. The result of corollary 3 continues to hold even when the competing suppliers are not myopic but rather forward looking, i.e., they have a discount factor > 0. In an equilibrium in which the two retailers deal with the dominant supplier only, all other suppliers earn 0 and they do not have any outside option. Suppose R j plays according to the proposed equilibrium by offering (w*,t*) to the dominant supplier only, but the deviating retailer, R i, offers (w*,t*) to the dominant supplier and at the same time makes a secret offer to S with w i = T i = 0. Even a 8

forward looking S would accept such a deviating offer, because S earns 0 anyway if it rejects R i s offer. As before, R i could then earn p*q* T* from deviating, which is higher than R i's expected profit from the collusive equilibrium if < /. One might expect that retailers would want to mimic the monopoly upstream market result and restore vertical collusion by signing exclusive dealing agreements with one supplier and granting him monopoly power. Such a strategy, however, is similarly vulnerable to retailers incentive to deviate. Suppose now that a retailer can offer a supplier an exclusive dealing contract in which the retailer commits not to buy during the relevant period from any competing supplier. The results of Corollary 3 still hold and collusion breaks down in the presence of competing suppliers. To see why, suppose that retailers can commit to an exclusive dealing contract, which is valid for one period at a time. Consider a collusive equilibrium in which in every period, each retailer offers the dominant supplier the collusive contract along with an exclusive dealing clause. The exclusive dealing obligation excludes the possibility that a retailer make an offer to the dominant supplier while ending up buying the product from a competing supplier. Nevertheless, a retailer can choose not to make an offer to the dominant supplier at all, and instead make an offer only to a competing supplier, with w = T = 0. The retailer's profit from deviation would no longer be p*q* T* but only p*q*. However, it follows from (8) that the result of corollary 3 remains intact: collusion is still impossible for < /. Hence, collusion and exclusive dealing are not practices that can sustain each other: when collusion is vulnerable to deviation by a retailer, so is exclusive dealing with a mutual supplier. 9 There must be an external commitment mechanism that ties both retailers to the same supplier. This external commitment mechanism can take the form of a long-term contract both retailers sign with the same supplier. For example, suppliers of dominant brands are often made category captain of the relevant category within the branches of all leading retail chains and can use this position to eliminate rivals who may cut wholesale prices. 0 Alternatively, one of the suppliers may have some inherent advantage. For example, he may offer a brand or product that is a must have brand for retailers. When retailers must purchase a portion of their requirements from a particular supplier, the supplier can relatively cheaply use loyalty rebates to induce retailers to operate exclusively with him. Another external commitment device that can secure exclusivity, despite retailers inherent incentive to breach it, may be a relationshipspecific investment made by the retailer that ties the retailer to a particular supplier (such as 9 We discuss the robustness of our results to the possibility of sequential offers in the conclusion. 0 See, e.g., the cases of Conwood, and Church & Dwight Co., Inc., supra note Error! Bookmark not defined.. See Nalebuff (005). 9