CHAPTER 4: PERFECT COMPETITION

Similar documents
CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

AGENDA Mon 10/12. Economics in Action Review QOD #21: Competitive Farming HW Review Pure Competition MR = MC HW: Read pp Q #7

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

ECON 102 Kagundu Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

23 Perfect Competition

Slides and Images, Worth Publishers Inc. 8-1

Chapter Summary and Learning Objectives

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 24. Perfect Competition

Monopolistic Competition

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

Chapter 10 Pure Monopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

ECON December 4, 2008 Exam 3

I enjoy teaching this class. Good luck and have a nice Holiday!!

Pure Monopoly. McGraw-Hill/Irwin. Copyright 2012 by The McGraw-Hill Companies, Inc. All rights reserved.

Chapter 13 Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

AP Microeconomics Chapter 10 Outline

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Perfect Competition CHAPTER 14. Alfred P. Sloan. There s no resting place for an enterprise in a competitive economy. Perfect Competition 14

Chapter 13 Perfect Competition

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Perfect Competition and The Supply Curve

2007 Thomson South-Western

Module 67: Introduction to Monopolisitic Competition

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

2010 Pearson Education Canada

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

The above Figure 1 shows the demand and cost curves facing a monopolist.

Chapter 6. Competition

Chapter 28 The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 10A/23 PERFECT COMPETITION. Professor Charles Fusi

Monopolistic Competition

Teaching about Market Structures

Supply in a Competitive Market

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Exam 3 Practice Questions

CHAPTER 5: Perfect Competition

CHAPTER 8 Competitive Firms and Markets

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION

Practice Test for Final

Monopoly CHAPTER 15. Henry Demarest Lloyd. Monopoly is business at the end of its journey. Monopoly 15. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

The "competition" in monopolistically competitive markets is most likely a result of having many sellers in the market.

Chapter 13. What will you learn in this chapter? A competitive market. Perfect Competition

6) The mailing must be postmarked by June 15. 7) If you have any questions please me at

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

8 Perfect Competition

The Model of Perfect Competition

MONOPOLY. Characteristics

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

A Model of Monopoly. Monopoly Profit Maximization. The Monopolist s Price and Output Numerically. The Monopolist s Price and Output Numerically

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

Chapter 10: Monopoly

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key March 23, 2011

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

CLEP Microeconomics Practice Test

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Monopoly single producer strong barriers to entry price marker no close substitute discriminates the price

Other examples of monopoly include Australia Post.

Copyright 2013 N.S. Market Structure (4.1.2)

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

The Behavior of Firms

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Use the following to answer question 4:

Sample. Final Exam Sample Instructor: Jin Luo

Competitive Markets: Applications

COST OF PRODUCTION & THEORY OF THE FIRM

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

9.1 Zero Profit for Competitive Firms in the Long Run

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

Graph G-MIC9.1. Graph G-MIC9.2

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Answers to the Problems Chapter 11

Perfectly Competitive Supply. Chapter 6. Learning Objectives

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Refer to the information provided in Figure 12.1 below to answer the questions that follow. Figure 12.1

1 of 14 5/1/2014 4:56 PM

AP Microeconomics Review With Answers

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key Nov 13, 2007

7-1: PERFECT COMPETITION NOTES

ECON 101 Introduction to Economics1

The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Market Structures. Perfect competition Monopolistic Competition Oligopoly Monopoly

Multiple Choice Questions Exam Econ 205 Pascal Courty MOCK MIDTERM

Perfect Competition. Chapter 7 Section Main Menu

MICRO EXAM REVIEW SHEET

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

2) All combinations of capital and labor along a given isoquant cost the same amount.

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

Practice Exam 3 Questions

Transcription:

CHAPTER 4: PERFECT COMPETITION LEARNING OBJECTIVE In this topic the principles which guide firms in their price and quantity decisions will be set out in the short and long run. Perfect competition is defined. The demand and marginal revenue are derived. The equivalence between profit maximization and equality of marginal revenue and marginal cost is established. The long run equilibrium is studied. The economic effect of this market form is shown to be optimum for society. PERFECT COMPETITION Perfect competition is a type of market characterized by - a very large number of small producers or sellers, - a standardized, homogeneous product, - the inability of individual sellers to influence price, - the free entry and exit of sellers in the market, and - unnecessary nonprice actions. Examples of markets in perfect competition are extremely rare. Numerous markets in the retail, service and agricultural sectors approach perfect competition best. But, in the agricultural sector, government support price programs distort the market mechanism. Notwithstanding the lack of good examples, this form of market is important because of a general conviction among economists that it is the best form of market. PERFECT COMPETITION NUMBER OF FIRMS The very large number of firms in perfect competition implies that each individual firm is very small in comparison to the total market. Indeed, if one firm were to become significantly large, it would dominate the market and competition would be eliminated or at least diminished. In the milk production segment of agriculture, farms are usually small. They are especially small compared to the size of the entire market for milk. Note that the milk distributors are occasionally large, but not the productive farms.

PERFECT COMPETITION STANDARDIZED PRODUCT The product in perfect competition is said to be standardized (or homogeneous). This means that it does not make any difference to customers which specific firm sells the product: it is absolutely identical. This is the main distinction between perfect competition and monopolistic competition: once some differences can be recognized by customers, firms acquire power over these customers. Milk is a uniform and homogeneous product. It is not possible to make a distinction between the milk of one farm and another. The government has indeed set standards of quality, fat content and cleanliness. PRICE TAKER The firms in perfect competition have no power over price: they have to sell at the going market price. The firms in perfect competition are said to be price takers. Should a firm attempt to raise the price by the smallest possible amount, customers would not buy from it because they could buy the same product from other firms. Lowering the price is also not necessary because the firm can already sell all its output at the going price. A milk producer who would try to raise his/her revenues by increasing the price for milk, would find the company collecting the milk in that region unwilling to buy his/her milk any longer. One individual farmer is thus unable to affect the price of milk in the entire market. PERFECT COMPETITION ENTRY AND EXIT There are no barriers to entry to or exit from a market in perfect competition. This condition assures that no firm will dominate the market and evict other firms. It also assures that the number of firms (although changing) will remain large. Agricultural production can start for most crops by simply planting on a parcel of land. For instance, that is true for fruit trees and vegetables. (It is true. however, that for some products such as milk or tobacco, the government limits production because of the existing overproduction). PERFECT COMPETITION NONPRICE ACTION Nonprice actions such as advertising, service after sale or

warranty, are not necessary in perfect competition because the firm can already sell all its output at the going price, and incurring additional expense would only make it unprofitable. (Nonprice action for the entire industry may however be useful). A single milk producer cannot possibly influence the consumption of milk at large, and needs not advertise. An association of milk producers or a large milk distributor may, however, be in a position to use advertisement effectively. PERFECT COMPETITION DEMAND The demand of firms in perfect competition is perfectly elastic (i.e., the smallest possible price change results in a virtually infinite quantity change). Such demand is represented graphically by a horizontal demand curve: no matter what quantity is sold, the price is the same, and it is the going price in the market. Graph G-MIC4.1 Nationwide, the demand for milk is likely to be downsloping, that is inversely related to price. But for a single milk producer, it is given by the price the farmer can receive: the going market price. It does not change, no matter what quantity the farmer produces. Thus demand is horizontal.

PERFECT COMPETITION MARGINAL REVENUE The horizontal demand curve is also the marginal revenue of a firm in perfect competition. The marginal revenue, or additional revenue from one more unit sold, is just equal to the going price (which is shown graphically by the demand curve itself). Note that the average revenue is also the demand curve and total revenue is an upsloping straight line. PROFIT MAXIMIZATION A firm must seek to sell a volume of output where its total revenue exceeds its total cost by the largest amount possible; that is, its profit is the maximum. LOSS MINIMIZATION If a firm fails to derive a profit, it may nevertheless seek, in the short run, to produce at that level of sales where the difference between its cost and its revenue, i.e., its loss, is minimum. CLOSE DOWN DECISION If a firm has revenues that are insufficient to cover even its fixed costs in the short run, the firm must close down. BREAK-EVEN POINT The volume of output where total revenue is equal to total cost is known as the break-even point. A firm must be beyond its break-even point in order to be maximizing its profit. MARGINAL REVENUE MARGINAL COST RULE Producing at the level of output where marginal revenue equals marginal cost is equivalent to profit maximization. Indeed, if one less unit were to be produced, profit would be smaller by the excess of marginal revenue over marginal cost for that last

unit. If one more unit were to be produced, profit would also be smaller, this time by the excess of marginal cost over marginal revenue. MARGINAL REVENUE MARGINAL COST The marginal revenue = marginal cost rule is applicable to loss minimization as well as profit maximization. However, if marginal revenue intersects marginal cost below average variable cost, it means that revenues are not sufficient to cover fixed costs and the firm should close down. MAXIMUM PROFIT The maximum profit is obtained by first determining the level of output for which marginal revenue equals marginal cost (thus profits cannot possibly be increased). Then determining 1- total revenue given by price multiplied by quantity, 2- total cost given by average total cost multiplied by quantity, 3- the difference between 1 and 2 above is the profit (or loss). MAXIMUM PROFIT GRAPH Since maximum profit is the excess of total revenue over total cost, it is shown graphically as the area by which the total revenue rectangle exceeds the total cost rectangle. The height of total revenue rectangle is the price received by the firm, and the width is the optimum quantity (where MR=MC). The height of total cost rectangle is average total cost (on ATC curve), and the width is the optimum quantity. Graph G-MIC4.2

SHORT RUN SUPPLY CURVE The short run supply curve of firms in perfect competition is the upsloping portion of the marginal cost curve (above the average variable cost intersection). Indeed, a firm determines its optimum volume of sales by taking the intersection of marginal revenue and marginal cost. The marginal revenue is also the price it receives. Thus supplier's price-quantity combinations are given by the marginal cost upsloping portion. LONG RUN PERFECT COMPETITION EQUILIBRIUM The long run equilibrium for firms in perfect competition is where demand (and marginal revenue which is identical to it) is tangent to the minimum of average total cost (where marginal cost also intersects average total cost). At that point, there is no profit or loss for the firm. (Note that there is no pure or economic profit, but normal profit must still be covered). ENTRY OF FIRMS IN PERFECT COMPETITION Should demand be above the minimum of average total cost, pure profit would exist for firms in perfect competition. This profit would attract new firms to the industry. Such entry of new firms is not impeded by any entry barriers in industries in perfect competition. The new firms would increase the total market supply and drive the price down. The lower price pushes the demand for each firm down toward or even below the equilibrium minimum average total cost point.

EXIT OF FIRMS IN PERFECT COMPETITION Should the demand be below the minimum of average total cost, losses of firms would force some firms to leave the industry. As firms leave, a decreasing total supply pushes price back up. The increasing price lifts the demand curves for individual firms upward toward or even above the equilibrium point. Firms departure or entry will continue until the price settles to be just equal to minimum average cost. LONG RUN SUPPLY CURVE The long run supply curve for an industry in perfect competition is perfectly elastic (that is horizontal) in constant-cost industries and upsloping in increasing-cost industries. Whether an industry is constant-cost or increasing-cost is determined by the presence of adequate or insufficient resources. PERFECT COMPETITION ECONOMIC EFFECT Perfect competition is seen as an ideal or optimum form of market because of its very beneficial economic effect for society, which comes from - allocative efficiency, and - productive efficiency. But there are a few shortcomings nevertheless. PRODUCTIVE EFFICIENCY The productive efficiency of perfect competition can be observed in the long run equilibrium point of all firms in the industry, which is at the minimum of average total cost. This means that all firms are forced to cut their costs and utilize the best available technology in order to have their minimum average total cost no higher than that of all the other firms in the industry. There is also no under or over utilized capacity. ALLOCATIVE EFFICIENCY The allocative efficiency in perfect competition comes from the fact that the quantity produced by each firm is just that for which the price paid by society is equal to the cost of additional resources (marginal cost). More could not possibly

be obtained for a lower price. The resources are also the most efficiently allocated among industries since firms will bid for these resources up to the price consumers want to pay for them. PERFECT COMPETITION SHORTCOMINGS In spite of its beneficial economic effect, perfect competition fails to - provide any correction for income distribution inequity, - generate any public goods since there is not profit, - stimulate technological progress because of lack of profits, - offer diversity in products since these are standardized. Review Quiz Assignments [Your opinion is important to us. If have a comment, correction or question pertaining to this chapter please send it to comments@peoi.org.]