Education and the Structure of Informal Firms in Latin America (Short Note)

Similar documents
Obstacles to Registering: Necessity vs. Opportunity Entrepreneurs

Gender Disparity in Human Capital: Going Beyond Schooling

Challenges of Retailing in India (A Short Note)

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

Is personal initiative training a substitute or complement to the existing human capital of. women? Results from a randomized trial in Togo

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

Irina Levina. Decentralization of decision-making at the firm: comparative analysis of firms in 7 European countries and Russia.

Examining the Correlation Between GDP per Capita and Deforestation in 2005 in 38 Countries

CASE FAIR OSTER PRINCIPLES OF MICROECONOMICS E L E V E N T H E D I T I O N. PEARSON 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. Publishing as Prentice Hall

Job related training in Scotland what do the data tell us?

OPINION SURVEYS ON ACTIVITY, PRICES AND LABOUR MARKET DEVELOPMENTS IN THE EURO AREA: FEATURES AND USES

Reserve Bank of New Zealand Analytical Note Series 1. Analytical Notes. In search of greener pastures: improving the REINZ farm price index

Preliminary and incomplete Abstract:

Price and volume measures in national accounts - Resources

Strategy of Cluster-Based Development: KAIZEN, Microfinance, and Infrastructure

Economic Composition & Change Analysis

BIM QUICKSCAN: BENCHMARK OF BIM PERFORMANCE IN THE NETHERLANDS

Productivity of U.S. casinos and casino hotels,

I ntroduction. Job Creation and Poverty Reduction: Lessons from Ghana. Researcher. Francis Teal

Effect of Regulatory Quality on Wood Pulp Imports by India

Economic Impacts. Refineries in Skagit County

UGANDA. About the SECOND ECONOMIC UPDATE THE WORLD BANK

St. Gallen, Switzerland, August 22-28, 2010

ESTIMATING GENDER DIFFERENCES IN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTIVITY: BIASES DUE TO OMISSION OF GENDER-INFLUENCED VARIABLES AND ENDOGENEITY OF REGRESSORS

For more info, please visit us online at:

Report on Minnesota Farm Finances. April, 2010

METHODOLOGY AND PRINCIPLES OF ANALYSIS

(Indirect) Input Linkages

Expected Occupation Growth in El Paso and Doña Ana Counties

Estimation of the Marginal Rate of Return and Supply Functions for Schooling: The Case of Egypt

OXFAM GB S GLOBAL PERFORMANCE FRAMEWORK:

Strategy and General Management

Openness and Technological Innovation in East Asia: Have They Increased the Demand for Skills?

POLICY NOTE 4. Constraints on Productivity and Investment in Indonesia s Manufacturing Sector: Survey-based Analysis of Business Constraints

Policy Note August 2015

A Note on the Impact of Economic Reforms on the Performance of the Agriculture Sector in Latin America Daniel Lederman * Rodrigo Reis Soares **

Abatement Costs through 2050

Chris Forman Avi Goldfarb Shane Greenstein

TECHNICAL NOTE. The Logical Framework

Mobile Banking Impact: Quantifying the ROI and Customer Engagement Benefits. Understanding the Value of Engaging Consumers in the Mobile Channel

Monitoring Corruption: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Indonesia Additional Tables Benjamin A. Olken December 30, 2006

Chile Marketing Report

Who are the entrepreneurs and what constraints do they face? Labor Markets Core Course. Yoon Y. Cho Labor Markets Team, HDNSP

HOW MILLENNIAL MEN CAN HELP BREAK THE GLASS CEILING

Annexure 1: Questionnaires

INDUSTRIAL POLICY AND

Finance and Economics Discussion Series Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board, Washington, D.C.

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK

Experienced Bidders in Online Second-Price Auctions

Enabling Marketplace Literacy in Subsistence Marketplaces. Madhu Viswanathan

BDC S ENTREPRENEURIAL INSIGHT

CONSULTATION DOCUMENT AML/CFT SUPERVISORY STRATEGY

Economic Growth and Education Reform in Developing Countries

FIRM INNOVATION AND DEVELOPMENT

ENTERPRISE SURVEYS WHAT BUSINESSES EXPERIENCE. Dominican Republic 2016 Country Profile ENTERPRISE SURVEYS

CIPS POSITIONS ON PRACTICE PURCHASING & SUPPLY MANAGEMENT: MONITORING THE PERFORMANCE OF SUPPLIERS

The Central Role of Agriculture in Myanmar s Economic Development

Consumer Panel Report The Indian Ice Cream Market: What Consumers Eat and Why?

Traditional hotel performance evaluation using calculations of supply and

TECHNOLOGICAL ADOPTION, HUMAN CAPITAL AND JOB CREATION. William F. Maloney The World Bank Lima, July 2015

Revisiting What Works: Women, Economic Empowerment and Smart Design

MEET Project: Management E-learning Experience for Training secondary school's students. Code: LLP-LDV-TOI-10-IT-560

Seeing the Light: Effective Strategies for Promoting Compact Fluorescent Lighting to Residential Customers

Factors that Lead to Economic Growth

THE IMPACTS OF OPEN DATA: TOWARDS EX POST ASSESSMENT

Building Markets to Improve National Sanitation Coverage in Cambodia.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES INFORMALITY AND DEVELOPMENT. Rafael La Porta Andrei Shleifer. Working Paper

IMPLICATIONS OF FOOD PRICE CHANGES FOR THE POOR. Maros Ivanic and Will Martin World Bank 18 September 2014

Chapter 1. Introduction

CHARACTERISTICS OF SUCCESSFUL SMALL BUSINESSES IN SOUTHERN NEW JERSEY

Informal Tradables and the Employment Growth of Indian Manufacturing

Exploring the World of Business and Economics

Consumer Panel Report The UK Ice Cream Market: What Consumers Eat and Why?

Predictors of pro-environmental behaviour in 1993 and 2010 An international comparison. Janine Chapman

Review of PG&E Home Energy Reports Initiative Evaluation. CPUC Energy Division Prepared by DNV KEMA, Inc

Identifying Important Regional Industries: A Quantitative Approach

The Jack-of-All-Trades Entrepreneur: Innate Talent or Acquired Skill?

Session 9 Project M&E Plans. Document Version Date:

Managerial Accounting and Cost Concepts

Network-Based Job Search

Micro, Small and Medium Enterprises (MSME)- An Indian Perspective

Designing the integration of register and survey data in earning statistics

CHAPTER 7 MONITORING AND EVALUATION

Estimating the Impact of Free-Play Coupons Value on Players' Slot Gaming Volumes

Wage and Productivity Dispersion in U.S. Manufacturing: The Role of Computer Investment

THE DYNAMICS OF SKILL MISMATCHES IN THE DUTCH LABOR MARKET

BASE WAGE AND SALARY SYSTEM. PRESENTED TO: Mr. Haroon Hafeez BY:

Gasoline Consumption Analysis

8. Researchers from a tire manufacturer want to conduct an experiment to compare tread wear of a new type of tires with the old design.

Identify sampling methods and recognize biased samples

RETAIL TRADE Workforce Demographics

EUROPE ONLINE: AN EXPERIENCE DRIVEN BY ADVERTISING SUMMARY RESULTS

Production and Growth

Agricultural Labor Practices 2017

Labor Productivity during Postwar Recessions: Basic Data, Facts, and Figures

Associate Professors Department of Management Studies Rajalakshmi Engineering college Chennai Corresponding Author:1Dr.J.Krithika

Understanding Fluctuations in Market Share Using ARIMA Time-Series Analysis

Structural Change in the Economy of Nigeria

Gentrification and Locality: A study on Salons in Harlem. Research group members: Elizabeth Liu. Mike Ma. Advisor: BK

Transcription:

World Bank From the SelectedWorks of Mohammad Amin June 1, 2011 Education and the Structure of Informal Firms in Latin America (Short Note) Mohammad Amin Available at: https://works.bepress.com/mohammad_amin/37/

Education and the Structure of Informal Firms in Latin America (Short Note) Mohammad Amin Enterprise Analysis Unit, World Bank June, 2011 A recent survey of unregistered or informal firms in Argentina and Peru shows that about 74 percent of the owners have at least secondary or higher education. This note compares firms by the education level of the owners to assess how education affects the structure, conduct and performance of informal firms. The results show a limited impact of education. Firm-efficiency as measured by sales per worker rises sharply with the level of education of the owner and the same holds for firm-size as measured by monthly sales or employment. Firms with relatively more educated owners are more likely to use external sources of finance, cell phones and in some cases show greater inclination to register, work on contract basis and maintain business accounts separate from household accounts. However, in other dimensions such as the use of machinery and vehicles there is no significant difference between firms by the education level of the owner of the firm. Introduction There is a vast literature dealing with the impact of human capital or the level of education on economic development (see, for example, Barro 1991 and Benhabib and Spiegel 1994). Almost all of this literature focuses on the formal or the registered sector. However, a large proportion of economic activity occurs in the informal or the unregistered economy. For example, a recent study estimates that for the world as a whole, between 23 percent and 35 percent of all economic activity occurs in the informal economy; for countries in the lowest quartile of GDP per capita, the estimates range between 29 percent and 57 percent (La Porta and Shleifer 2008). Studies that explore the education-informality nexus are largely focused on how the level of education affects an individual s decision to participate in the formal vs. the informal economy (see, for example, Pisani and Pagan 2004). This note uses recently collected data on informal or unregistered firms in Argentina and Peru to shed some light on how the education level of the owner of the firm affects the performance and structure of the firm. The data were collected by the World Bank s Enterprise Analysis Unit in 2010 and cover 384 firms in Argentina and 480 firms in Peru. Firms were randomly selected from two cities in Argentina (Buenos Aires and Rosario) and two cities in Peru (Lima and Arequipa). It is important to note that due to lack of proper sampling frames, these surveys are not necessarily representative of the informal economy at the country or even the city level. Hence, the results presented below pertain to the structure of the firms surveyed rather than the informal economy per se. Extension of these results to the broader informal economy therefore requires circumspection. 1

Throughout this note, the focus is on the level of education of the largest shareholder (owner for short) of the firm. Without much loss of generality, a firm-owner is considered to be educated or highly educated if he or she attended secondary school or undertook vocational training or university training. The remaining individuals, the less educated, include those with either primary or no education. In the full sample, 74 percent of the firms have highly educated owners. The figure varies between 59 percent in Argentina and 85 percent in Peru. The results continue to hold if the highly educated category were divided into secondary education (50 percent in the full sample) and more than secondary education (24 percent in the full sample). 1 Unless otherwise mentioned, all differences discussed below are statistically significant. 2 Labor productivity is higher among the more educated Labor productivity is a commonly used measure of the level of efficiency of a firm. It equals total sales of a firm in a regular month (in U.S. dollars) divided by the total number of workers employed by the firm in a regular month. It is plausible that the more educated owners would have better managerial abilities and knowledge of the markets and business opportunities. Hence, labor productivity may be higher for the more educated. The data do not reject this hypothesis either in the full sample or in various sub-samples (figure 1). 3 It is possible that the difference in labor productivity between more or less educated firms could be due to other related differences such as the use of machines and vehicles, firm-size as measured by the number of employees, age of the firm, years of managerial experience, gender of the largest owner, age of the largest owner, whether the firm operates from inside or outside of household premises, disaggregated sector-specific factors (20 sectors within manufacturing and services) and country-specific factors. However, closer examination shows that these factors explain at most 49 percent of the gap in labor productivity by education. Figure 1: Labor productivity is higher for firms with more educated owners Sales to employment ratio in a regular month (USD, median values) 350 300 250 200 150 100 50 0 Full sample Argentina Peru Manufacturing Service Single employee Multiple employees Less than secondary educated Secondary or higher educated Source: Enterprise Surveys 2

Firm-size increases with the level of education of the owner It is well-known that informal firms operate at a very small scale which makes it difficult for them to exploit economies of scale in specialization, innovation and investment in fixed capital. Without an increase in firm-size, a dynamic and vibrant informal sector is almost impossible. Hence, it is important to understand how and why firm-size varies within the informal sector. The sample under study confirms that firm-size rises with the education of the owner. The median value of total sales in a regular month is U.S. $387 for firms with highly-educated owners and a much lower U.S. $258 for the rest. The larger firm-size among the more educated is also confirmed within the various sub-samples shown in figure 1. Commonly observed factors such as the use of machines and vehicles, age of the firm, years of managerial experience, gender of the largest owner, age of the largest owner, whether the firm operates from inside or outside of household premises, whether corruption and crime are severe obstacles to doing business, disaggregated sector-specific factors and country-specific factors cannot fully explain the positive relationship between monthly sales and the level of education (figure 2). Figure 2: Even a large number of observable factors cannot fully explain why monthly sales increase with the level of education of the owner of the firm 1.50 Sales in a regular month (logs, residuals, quartile averages) 1.00 0.50 0.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 0.20 0.40 0.60 0.50 1.00 1.50 Proportion of firms with the largest owner having secondary or higher education (residuals, quartile averages) Source: Enterprise Surveys The figure is a partial scatter plot of the quarterly average residual values of total sales in a regular month (log values) against the residuals of the dummy variable equal to 1 if the owner has secondary or higher education and 0 otherwise. The residuals are obtained from the regression of sales (logs) and education dummy variable on the following variables: dummy indicating if a firm uses machinery, dummy indicating if a firm uses vehicles, age of the firm (logs), years of managerial experience (logs), gender of the largest owner, age of the largest owner (logs), dummy indicating whether the firm operates from inside or outside of household premises, dummy indicating if corruption is a severe obstacle to doing business and a similar dummy for crime, dummy variables for the sector (20 sectors) and a dummy for the country. The positive relationship shown is statistically significant at the 5 percent level with Huber-White robust standard errors. The relationship between firm-size and education discussed above also holds for the number of employees as the measure of firm-size, although in this case the relationship is somewhat weak within Argentina. Younger entrepreneurs are more likely to have higher education 3

Due to ongoing economic progress, the proportion of the highly educated in a country tends to rise over time. However, it is not clear that the share of the more educated increases proportionately within the informal sector as well. For example, with economic progress, the more educated may increasingly prefer the formal over the informal sector leading to a decline in the proportion of the highly educated within the informal sector. This issue is important to understand in order to properly address human capital related problems faced by the informal firms. The data suggest that the proportion of the highly educated in the informal sector increases over time. That is, the proportion of the highly educated within the sample is higher among the relatively younger firm-owners. The median age of the firm-owners in the sample is 43 years. For the sample of firms with owners younger than the median age, 86 percent have owners with secondary or higher education. For firms with owners above the median age, only 61 percent have secondary education or higher. This percentage difference holds within various sub-samples and is robust to a number of differences in firm-characteristics. Owners with higher education are more likely to have parents who own a business and have higher education Consistent with the findings in the broader literature on education, owners of firms in the sample are more likely to be highly educated if their parents are highly educated too. About 86 percent of the firm-owners are highly educated if either of the parents of the firm-owner has a secondary or higher education, while only 66 percent of firm-owners are highly educated if both of their parents have less than a secondary education. The positive relationship between parental and own education for the firm-owners holds within various sub-samples such as manufacturing and service firms, single vs. multiple employee firms, and firms in Argentina and Peru. The relationship is also robust to a number of other differences between firms such as their age, gender of the largest owner and location of the business inside vs. outside of household premises. It is possible that individuals who own their businesses generate higher income than those working on wages. Since higher income levels are typically associated with greater desire to educate children, a positive relationship between owning a business and children s education level can be expected. The data do not reject this possibility. For firm-owners who have parents with their own business (currently or in the past), 83 percent have secondary or higher education. The corresponding figure for the set of remaining firms is much lower at 71 percent. This difference between the two sets of firms is robust. The more educated show a greater willingness to register It is commonly believed that bringing the informal firms within the fold of the formal or registered sector can have numerous beneficial effects for the economy. However, the transition from the informal to the formal sector is not well understood. For example, what sorts of agents are more likely to make the transition than others? The data reveal that such a transition is more attractive for firms with highly educated owners than the rest. That is, for the sample of firms with owners having secondary or higher education, 49 percent report their willingness to register. For firms with less than secondary educated owners, only 36 percent are willing. 4 It is confirmed in the data that this difference in the willingness to register by the level of education cannot be explained away by differences in firm characteristics such as sector of activity (20 disaggregated 4

sectors), country of location, age of the firm, gender of the largest owner, location of the firm inside vs. outside household premises, hours of normal operation in a given week, whether the firm uses machinery and vehicles or not and firm-size measured by the number of employees in a regular month. However, when one takes into account differences in the age of the owner or in firm-size measured by monthly sales, the positive relationship between education and willingness to register becomes weak. Hence, it is difficult to say whether it is education per se or firm-size or the lower age of the more educated that drives the greater willingness to register. With the exception of cell phones, the use of equipment, such as machinery and vehicles, does not increase with the level of education One might suspect that the more educated would be more likely to use efficiency-enhancing equipment such as machines, vehicles and cell phones due to being more aware of and more efficient at exploiting them.. That is, human and physical capital may be complements in the production process. However, the data do not support such complementarity, except in the case of cell phones. The more educated are much more likely to use machines in Peru but not in the full sample (figure 3). The percentage of firms that use vehicles for business activity is roughly the same irrespective of the level of education of the owner and this holds within various subsamples including Peru and Argentina. For cell phones, however, 28 percent of the firms with less than secondary educated owners compared with 53 percent of the firms with highly educated owners use a cell phone. This large percentage difference holds within various sub-samples. Figure 3: There is little complimentarity between human capital and machinery % of firms that using machinery 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Full sample Argentina Peru Manufacturing Service Single employee Multiple employees Less than secondary educated Secondary or higher educated Source: Enterprise Surveys Use of external sources of funds is more common among the more educated A number of studies suggest that access to finance improves with the income level or the level of education of the individual. The data show mixed results for the sample surveyed. The percentage of firms that use an external source to finance the day-to-day operations is larger among firms with a highly educated owner than the rest (27 percent vs. 14 percent). Similarly, percentage of firms that use their own or internal funds to finance their day-to-day operations is lower among firms with highly educated owners vs. the rest (77 percent vs. 87 percent). While 5

these percentage differences are significant and large in the full sample, they are weak within Argentina and Peru. Hence, it is difficult to say whether it is education level per se or other country specific factors that are responsible for the observed relationship between education level and the sources of finance. Some results are specific to the country and the sector to which a firm belongs There are a number of differences between firms by the level of education of the owner that are specific to Argentina and Peru and to the manufacturing and service sectors. This is not too surprising. Given little sunk cost and small scale of operation, informal firms are likely to adapt to the local conditions at the country and the sector level. For example, in Peru, 23 percent of the firms with highly educated owners produce or sell under a written contract compared with only 10 percent of the firms with less than secondary educated owners. In contrast, the corresponding figures for Argentina are roughly equal to one another (53 percent vs. 48 percent, respectively). Another example relates to the cost of registering as perceived by the firms. In the manufacturing sector, close to 19 percent of the firms that have a highly educated owner perceive inspections and required meetings with government officials as a severe obstacle to registering, while in manufacturing firms with less than secondary educated owners, the corresponding figure is much higher at 29 percent. Conversely, in the service sector, these percentages hardly differ from one another (21 percent vs. 21 percent, respectively). Conclusion This note sheds light on how the level of education of the entrepreneur affects the structure and performance of an informal firm in Argentina and Peru. Firm-efficiency and firm-size tend to increase with the education level of the firm-owner. Younger entrepreneurs tend to be more educated, reflecting the broader trend toward increasing literacy and human capital with overall economic development. Other differences such as tendency to use external vs. internal sources of funds, willingness to register and contract-based work are also related to the education level of the entrepreneur although in these cases more work is required to ascertain or reject them as robust findings. References Barro, R. J. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries." Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2): 407-43. Benhabib, J. and M. Spiegel. 1994. "The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data." Journal of Monetary Economics 34(2): 143-74. La Porta, R. and A. Shleifer. 2008. The Unofficial Economy and Economic Development. Tuck School of Business Working Paper No. 2009-57. Pisani, M. J. and J. A. Pagan. 2004. Sectoral Selection and Informality: A Nicaraguan Case Study. Review of Development Economics 8(4): 541-556. 6

1 That is, how firm characteristics change across various education categories on average is qualitatively similar whether those with secondary and more than secondary education are grouped into one category or not. 2 That is, the differences are statistically significant at the 5 percent level. The significance level is obtained through appropriate regression analysis with Huber-White robust standard errors. 3 Figure 1 uses median values of labor productivity within the various sub-samples shown. However, higher labor productivity among the more educated is also confirmed when looking at the mean instead of the median values of labor productivity. 4 The greater inclination among the more educated firms to register holds within Argentina and Peru. However, it does not hold when looking at the sample of service firms alone. 7