Between Varieties. 1 Although true in this instance, the equality of aggregate productivity between the trading countries is no longer a

Similar documents
Lesson22: Trade under Monopolistic Competition

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES THEORIES OF HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS AND TRADE. Stephen J. Redding. Working Paper

Firm Distribution. Ping Wang Department of Economics Washington University in St. Louis. April 2017

MIT PhD International Trade Lecture 12: Heterogeneous Firms and Trade (Theory part II)

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model

Final Exam - Answers

Vertical FDI and Global Sourcing Strategies of Multinational Firms

Different Models in International Trade

Implications of Transatlantic Trade and Investment Partnership and Trans-Pacific Partnership for Food Processing Sector

Modern trade theory for CGE modellers: the Armington, Krugman and Melitz models. presentation at GTAP2015

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

R&D Investments, Exporting, and the Evolution of Firm Productivity

International Trade Lecture 15: Firm Heterogeneity Theory (II) After Melitz (2003)

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment

9.1 Zero Profit for Competitive Firms in the Long Run

The Decision to Import

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Problem Set 1 (Gains From Trade and the Ricardian Model)

Alternative Trade Theories!

Union Formation, Firm Selection and Aggregate Industry Productivity

Competition and Welfare Gains from Trade: A Quantitative Analysis of China Between 1995 and 2004

Producer Services, Trade, and Wages

Unequal Effects of Trade on Workers with Different Abilities

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

Plants, Productivity, and Market Size, with Head-to-Head Competition

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Comparison of Welfare Results from Trade Liberalization in the Armington, Krugman and Melitz Models: Impacts with features of real economies*

Innovation and the Elasticity of Trade Volumes to Tariff Reductions

Lecture 7c: Firm Heterogeneity. Thibault FALLY C181 International Trade Spring 2018

Search markets: Introduction

Practice Test for Final

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Modeling Firm Heterogeneity in International Trade: Do Structural Effects Matter?

Caballero and Hammour, Macroeconomics of factor specificity, JPE 1998

Toru Kikuchi Kobe University. Abstract

Competition, Markups, and the Gains from International Trade

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

New goods, old theory, and the welfare costs of trade restrictions. Paul Romer

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS WORKING PAPER SERIES. A Simple Model of Quantity Heterogeneity and International Trade. Elias Dinopoulos University of Florida

Economics. E.1.4 Describe how people respond predictably to positive and negative incentives.

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Field Exam January Labor Economics PLEASE WRITE YOUR ANSWERS FOR EACH PART IN A SEPARATE BOOK.

Study Questions. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

Trade Liberalization and Heterogeneous Technology Investments.

Market Structure, Innovation, and Allocative Efficiency

Product Mix, Trade, and the Environment: Theory and Evidence from Indian Manufacturing

NEW KEYNESIAN THEORY: MONOPOLY PRICING MARCH 29, 2010 RELEVANT MARKET STRUCTURE(S)? Introduction

Volume 37, Issue 4. Trade Induced Firm Productivity and Division of Labor in a General Equilibrium with Oligopoly. Keita Kamei Yamagata University

Economics 101 Fall 2014 International Trade. Problem Set 2. November 10, Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Theory and Wages

Trade Liberalization and Firm Dynamics. Ariel Burstein and Marc Melitz

How Learning Affects Firm s Export Entry Decisions. (Preliminary

Innovation, Firm Dynamics, and International Trade

Helpman, Itskhoki, Redding (2010): Inequality and Unemployment in a Global Economy

Trade Liberalization and Inequality: a Dynamic Model with Firm and Worker Heterogeneity

Paper 11 Urban Economics

Pollution Haven Effect with Heterogeneous Firms

AP Microeconomics Review With Answers

The Model of Perfect Competition

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Trade Costs and Regional Productivity in Indian Manufacturing. Hanpil Moon

Per-capita Income, Taste for Quality, and Exports across Countries

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES MEASURED AGGREGATE GAINS FROM INTERNATIONAL TRADE. Ariel Burstein Javier Cravino

Monopolistic Competition

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Trade Liberalization, Heterogeneous Firms and Industrial Dynamics

Paolo Bertoletti and Federico Etro. Monopolistic Competition: A Dual Approach

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Take-Home Final Exam -Answers

Final Term Examination Spring 2006 Time Allowed: 150 Minutes. Question No. 1 Marks :1. Question No.

New economic geography, part II: International specialization and industrial clustering

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy

Productivity in a Differentiated Products Market Equilibrium

Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

Multi-Product Firms and Trade Liberalization

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

Measuring the Welfare Gains of Technological Adoption: The Case of Steam Power in the Canadian Manufacturing Sector in the Late Nineteenth Century

Fragmentation and The Product Cycle

Wage and Price Dispersion: On-the-job-search meets Monopolistic Competition

International Outsourcing and Intra-Industrial Trade

Answer both questions. (Question II has a multi-page text for analysis.)

Products and Productivity

Products and Productivity

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Allocative Efficiency, Mark-ups, and the Welfare Gains from Trade

Trade Liberalization, Heterogeneous Firms and the Soft Budget Constraint. Michael Alexeev* and. Yong Joon Jang** June 2010

Chapter 1- Introduction

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

ExportVersusFDI with Heterogeneous Firms

Imperfect competition, productivity differences and proximity-concentration trade-offs

2) A production method that relies on large quantities of labor and smaller quantities of capital equipment is referred to as a: 2)

Firms in International Trade 1

Facilitating Export through Trade Intermediaries

Welfare in Models of Trade with Heterogeneous Firms

Too Much R&D? Vertical Differentiation in a Model of Monopolistic Competition. Jan Kranich. May 15, Abstract

Transcription:

The Impact of Trade: Between Varieties Changes in the Elasticity of Substitution In the spirit of Krugman ((1979),(1980)), I now examine the impact of trade on two economies of the kind previously described. In this section, I assume as in (Krugman 1979) that the increase in product variety made possible through trade induces an increase in the elasticity of substitution between varieties. I then analyze the effects of this increased elasticity on aggregate productivity and the reallocations of market shares and proþts between Þrms in the industry. I initially assume that there are no additional costs involved with trade. In the next section, I investigate the effects of certain trade costs such as the cost of entry into the export market and some non-tariff barriers. This model shares the same characteristics as those based on Krugman s ((1979),(1980)) seminal work: in the absence of differences between countries in relative factor abundance, taste, and technology, trade nevertheless occurs and increases welfare by providing the beneþts of an increase in country size. As with Krugman ((1979),(1980)), the free trade equilibrium attained by two countries of the type previously described (when there are no transport costs) replicates the equilibrium outcome of a single integrated world economy that combines the resources of both countries. This property is driven by the creation of a single world market where all varieties are traded. Consumers in both countrieshaveaccesstothesamebundleofgoodsatthesameaggregatepriceindexp. Regardless of country size or relative wage differences, the cutoff productivity levels in both countries must satisfy the same h(ϕ )=k(ϕ ) condition and must therefore be identical. This, in turn, implies the equality of aggregate productivity levels and wages between the two countries. 1 Each Þrm then divides its sales between domestic and foreign consumers on the basis of the ratio of its country size to the size of the integrated economy. The balance of payments condition between the two countries is thus trivially satisþed. If the exposure of a country to trade does not affect the elasticity of substitution between varieties, then this exposure duplicates the effects of an increase in country size. As previously described, none of the Þrm level equilibrium variables change only the number of Þrms and available varieties are affected. Exposure to trade then increases welfare solely through the increased product variety effect. This result, also obtained by (Krugman 1980), is driven by the absence of 1 Although true in this instance, the equality of aggregate productivity between the trading countries is no longer a necessary consequence of technological similarity (as is the case with representative Þrms). Interestingly, the presence of trade costs in this model will break this equality and confer an aggregate productivity advantage to the larger country (along with a higher relative wage) 1

any link between an increase in the number of varieties consumed and the elasticity of substitution between the varieties. This is a well known property of Dixit-Stiglitz style models of monopolistic competition and is addressed in the original paper by the authors. 2 (Dixit & Stiglitz 1977) also show how to change the functional form of utility in order to generate preferences that exhibit the very plausible characteristic of a positive relationship between the number of varieties consumed and the elasticity of substitution. This type of preferences is used in (Krugman 1979) to show how trade can provide the additional welfare beneþts of an increase in the elasticity of substitution through lower prices (driven by lower markups). The number of varieties then increases from its autarky level, but not as much as in the constant elasticity case. It is also possible that a country s exposure to trade generates an increase in the elasticity of substitution through a different mechanism: the characteristics of individual varieties could change in such a way that they become closer substitutes. The monopolistic competition models of trade typically assume that any Þrm from one country producing the same variety as a Þrm from the other country will costlessly switch to the production of another unproduced variety when the two countries open to trade. Similarly, I will assume that exposure to trade induces a costless process of product modiþcations amongst all Þrms in both countries. On the other hand, I assume that Þrms can not just pick another variety and are forced to re-design their products. Firms are therefore unable to maintain the same level of product differentiation in a now more crowded product market space. I assume that the symmetry between goods is preserved, but that they are now all closer substitutes in the integrated world market. This is, of course, a quite speciþc and restrictive assumption. However, its goal is not to realistically model the Þrm s product selection decision nor to explain how trade will generate an increase in the elasticity of substitution. Rather, its goal is to analyze the effect of this increase (since this effect is quite plausible although the symmetry assumption is obviously a massive simpliþcation) on an industry comprised of heterogeneous Þrms. Hence, this reduced form approach is adopted in order to introduce the link between increases in product variety and substitutability between varieties while preserving the C.E.S. formulation of utility. Preserving the homotheticity of preferences in this model is necessary since Þrm heterogeneity precludes the use of cost symmetries to obtain equilibrium conditions in the way that was achieved by (Krugman 1979) and (Dixit & Stiglitz 1977). Instead, I rely on the construction 2 As implied by its name, the C.E.S. utility function obviously maintains a constant elasticity of substitution between varieties. This property, holding the number of varieties Þxed, is different than the one under examination, which refers to the relationship between the elasticity (constant between varieties) and the total number of varieties consumed. 2

of an aggregate price index that is only valid when the underlying preferences are homothetic. I henceforth assume that the opening of the countries to trade and the resulting merger of varieties on the world market induces an increase in the elasticity of substitution from its autarky level σ a to σ. I implicitly assume the existence of an increasing function relating the elasticity change to the change in product variety. Brießy returning to the benchmark case of representative Þrms, one can note that an increase in the elasticity of substitution applied to Krugman s ((1980)) model with C.E.S. utility produces thesameeffects as in his ((1979)) model with non-homothetic preferences: The increase from σ a to σ causes a rise in the output per Þrm and an increase in the number of varieties consumed (though not as big an increase as in the constant elasticity case). 3 On the other hand, by construction, aggregate productivity must remain Þxed at the productivity level common to all Þrms. I now show how Þrm heterogeneity introduces an additional beneþtfromtradethroughanincreaseinaggregate productivity. This increase is generated by the shifting of resources towards more productive Þrms. Although average output per Þrm increases as in the representative Þrm case, this increase is not equally spread across Þrms. In fact, only the more productive Þrms expand while the less productive ones contract or exit. Let ϕ a denote a country s equilibrium productivity cutoff level under autarky. If this country opens to trade with another identical country, it attains a new equilibrium that replicates the closed economy equilibrium of a country with twice the number of workers and a higher elasticity of substitution between varieties of σ > σ a. This increase in σ shifts up the k(ϕ)curve 4 and induces an increase in the equilibrium cutoff level to ϕ > ϕ a.thepercentagedifference between the market shares of the Þrms with average and cutoff productivity levels increases for two reasons: given the same ratio of productivity levels between any two Þrms ϕ 1 ϕ 2 > 1,theratioofthesetwoÞrms market shares is now higher due to the increase in the elasticity of substitution: r(ϕ 1) r(ϕ 2 ) = ϕ 1 σ 1 ϕ 2 > ϕ1 σa 1 ϕ 2. Furthermore, the increase in σ also induces an increase in the average productivity level relative to any given cutoff level ( ϕ(ϕ ) is higher for any ϕ ). There are thus two effects generating an increase in aggregate productivity: the Þrm selection effect, driven by the increase in the cutoff level ϕ (the least productive Þrms exit), but also a further reallocation: among the group of Þrms who remain in the industry after the transition to trade, market shares are further redistributed 3 The welfare effect of the increased product variety is ambiguous as I have assumed that the characteristics of the goods have changed. 4 k(ϕ) R 1 1 = (ln ξ ln ϕ) σ 1 G(ϕ) ϕ σ 1 ϕ ξσ 1 g(ξ) dξ > 0 3

towards the more productive Þrms. This redistribution can be analyzed more precisely by tracking the performance of a particular Þrm (with productivity level ϕ) who remains in the industry after the transition to trade (ϕ ϕ ). Let s(ϕ) =lnr(ϕ) ln r a (ϕ) denotethisþrm s percentage market share change where r a (ϕ) and r(ϕ) denote the Þrm s revenues before and after the transition to trade (percentage market share changes are equal to percentage revenue changes since aggregate revenue R = Y = L remains constant). This percentage change can then be written: s(ϕ) =ln " µ " ϕ σ 1 µ # ϕ σa 1 σf# ϕ ln ϕ σ a f a =(lnσ ln σ a ) (σ a 1)(ln ϕ ln ϕ a)+(σ σ a )(ln ϕ ln ϕ ) = σ (σ a 1) ϕ (σ σ a )pct(ϕ), where σ > 0and ϕ > 0 are the percentages increase in the elasticity of substitution and the cutoff productivity level, and pct(ϕ) 0 is the percentage difference between ϕ and ϕ. A Þrm s percentage market share change is thus an increasing function of its productivity level ϕ though this change need not be positive for all Þrms who remain in the industry. Naturally, this change is negative for any Þrm who no longer produces after the transition to trade ( s(ϕ) =,if ϕ a ϕ < ϕ )). There will thus exist another cutoff productivity level ϕ ϕ separating the Þrms whogainfromthosewholosemarketshare: 5 s(ϕ) 0 if ϕ a ϕ ϕ, s(ϕ) > 0 if ϕ > ϕ. Furthermore, the percentage market share gain of a Þrm with productivity ϕ > ϕ increases with the difference between ϕ and ϕ : the more productive the Þrm, the greater the market share gain. This market share reallocation will obviously also affect the distribution of proþts across Þrms. Since a Þrm s variable proþt isgivenby r(ϕ) σ, the percentage change in this Þrm s variable proþt 5 Depending on the sign of σ (σ a 1) ϕ (which can not be signed without making further assumptions), ϕ will either be equal to or strictly greater than ϕ. If ϕ = ϕ,thenþrms either remain in the industry and gain market share, or exit. 4

(denoted π v (ϕ)), provided it still produces, can be written: π v (ϕ) = s(ϕ) σ = (σ a 1) ϕ +(σ σ a )pct(ϕ). Note that a Þrm whose market share remains constant ( s(ϕ) = 0) will nevertheless incur a proþt loss. Of course, even if the new cutoff Þrm gains market share ( s(ϕ ) > 0), it must still lose proþts since these drop to zero. There will thus be yet another cutoff productivity level ϕ > ϕ such that ms(ϕ )= σ > 0and π v (ϕ) 0 if ϕ a ϕ ϕ, π v (ϕ) > 0 if ϕ > ϕ. Interestingly, all Þrms with productivity ϕ > ϕ will earn higher proþts in the integrated world economy, even though their common markup decreases. As in the case of market shares, the percentage proþt gain rises with the Þrm s productivity level. Finally, note that even though trade increases the product variety available to consumers, the number of Þrms producing in either country is lower than in autarky since the average Þrm proþt has increased (p in is lower). This section has highlighted a key difference between this model and its predecessors based on representative Þrms. If there exists a link between product variety and the elasticity of substitution, then the existence of Þrm level heterogeneity creates a new transmission channel for the effects of trade. Through this channel, the exposure to trade generates an increase in aggregate productivity without affecting the state of Þrm level technology (referenced by the distribution g(ϕ)). This aggregate productivity increase is driven by a Darwinian evolution within the industry: the more productive Þrms thrive and expand while the less productive ones contract or exit. Although this section has focused on the impact of trade, there also exist other phenomena that may affect the elasticity of substitution between varieties in a closed economy. These phenomena could either directly affect this elasticity or do so indirectly through an impact on product variety. In particular, economy wide productivity growth (which can be modeled as an increase in the effective labor force) will increase product variety. Given the assumed link between product variety and the substitutability between varieties, the ensuing increase in the elasticity of substitution will generate the same reallocations that were just described. Technological progress would then 5

engender reallocative productivity growth. The overall economy would grow, not just by adding Þrms, but also by shifting its resources towards more efficient Þrms. Larger economies (vis-avis smaller ones) would then exhibit a distribution of Þrms with a more concentrated range of productivity levels (because of the higher cutoff) but with a greater dispersion of Þrm sizes over this range: the large economy would have a greater share of production concentrated at a smaller proportion of Þrms. 6

References Dixit, A. & Stiglitz, J. (1977), Monopolistic competition and optimum product diversity, American Economic Review 67, 297 308. Krugman, P. (1979), Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and international trade, Journal of International Economics 9, 469 479. Krugman, P. (1980), Scale economies, product differentiation, and the pattern of trade, American Economic Review 70, 950 959. 7