Keywords: GMOs; biotechnology; labeling policy; trade disputes.

Similar documents
(Gives background and presents arguments for both sides) by P. Byrne, D. Pendell, & G. Graff* Quick Facts...

Agricultural Outlook Forum For Release: Monday, February 23, 1998 SETTING INTERNATIONAL STANDARDS FOR FOOD AND AGRICULTURAL TRADE

Contents. In this pack you will find: Contents page (version 1. Mar2017) Non-GMO Project Proof Points (version 1. Mar2017)

The Ten Commandments of the Sanitary and Phytosanitary Agreement of the World Trade Organization

Post-Market Oversight of Biotech Foods

Importance and Limits of the Cost-Benefit Analysis for GMOs Regulation

New technologies and food labelling: the controversy over labelling of foods derived from genetically modified crops

How Labeling of Safety and Process Attributes Affects Markets for Food

Domestic Import Regulations for Genetically Modified Organisms and Their Compatibility with WTO Rules

Guidance Document. Meeting Requirements as a Registered Food Importer. A guidance document issued by the Ministry for Primary Industries

CONSUMER RESPONSE TO GMO FOODS: BRANDING VERSUS GOVERNMENT CERTIFICATION

Rules and Regulations on GMO-derived food products in the European Union Lynn Insall UK Food and Drink Federation

In the upcoming November election,

November 15, Division of Dockets Management (HFA-305) Food and Drug Administration 5630 Fishers Lane Room 1061 Rockville, MD 20852

Will developing countries adopt policies that promote the planting of genetically. Governing the GM Crop Revolution

ECONOMIC IMPACT STUDY: POTENTIAL COSTS OF MANDATORY LABELLING OF FOOD PRODUCTS DERIVED FROM BIOTECHNOLOGY IN CANADA

Sampling and Detection Methods and the Biosafety Protocol: Views of the Global Industry Coalition 1

RE: Proposed Rule Questions Under Consideration for GMO Disclosure and Labeling

QUALITY SYSTEMS IN THE FOOD SECTOR IN MAURITIUS

Capacity Building Assistance: Moral Imperative or Common Sense?

Partnered by. STANDARDS CONCLAVE Role of Standards in International Trade: Challenges, opportunities & issues

Dr. Makarim Wibisono Direktur Eksekutif ASEAN Foundation Training Workshop Kemen.LH. Bogor, 30 Juli 2012

Nagoya Protocol on Access and Benefit Sharing -Technical Brief

Food Safety Modernization Act An Industry Perspective

Fair and equitable benefit sharing

FDA FSMA Timeline. July 29, 2009 House version passed. Nov. 30, 2010 Senate version passed. Dec. 19, 2010 Senate revised version passed

CABINET DIRECTIVE ON STREAMLINING REGULATION

Implementing an Employee Engagement Programme

The Role of Regulatory Affairs in Product Development

Michael Robach Vice President, Corporate Food Safety and Regulatory Affairs Cargill incorporated Minneapolis, Minnesota, USA

trade knowledge network

Outsource or in-house? The evolving role of analytical services in pharmaceutical manufacturing

SQF 2000 Code. 6th Edition AUGUST A HACCP-Based Supplier Assurance Code for the Food Manufacturing and Distributing Industries

The Economics of GM Food Labels: An Evaluation of Mandatory Labeling Proposals in India

The SPS Agreement: maximising the benefits

IS THE US FDA REGULATION AND EVALUATION OF GENETICALLY ENGINEEERED FOODS SUFFICIENT? Teresa Marek FOOD REGULATION IN THE UNITED STATES

Position Statement. Product compliance and evidence of suitability

IFOAM EU Group. International Federation of Organic Agriculture Movements - EU Regional Group. Rue d'arlon 82, BE-1040 Brussels Tel

RAISING THE STANDARD THE NEW ISO RISK MANAGEMENT STANDARD

P R E F A C E THE CODEX ALIMENTARIUS COMMISSION STRATEGIC PLAN

Project on Organic Agriculture

ISO Gestión y buenas prácticas en el sector alimentos

Transparency and sustainability of the EU risk assessment process

A Regulators Perspective on U.S. Trade Policy Coordination

WHOLE FOODS MARKET GMO Labeling Policy

TTIP- EU proposal for Chapter: Regulatory Cooperation

The Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures

FSC36 SAFE FEED/SAFE FOOD GUIDANCE DOCUMENT

BT s response to Ofcom consultation document. Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts

TTIP AND REGULATION: AN OVERVIEW

Key words: non-gm foods; risk and benefit perception; willingness-to-pay.

HUNGER AND ENVIRONMENTAL NUTRITION DPG

Overview of the U.S. Standardization System

World Trade Organization Activity

AUSTRALIAN CERTIFIED NON-GMO STANDARD. Version 1.0, 2016, Australian Organic Limited

Summary of the WTO Interim Report in EC-Biotech

Cost Benefit Analysis LSA Document #17-180

Australian grain a quality product

AUSTRALIAN CONSUMER LAW REVIEW

White Paper April 23, 2018

Non-tariff Barriers to Trade in Goods, Services and Investment

Consolidated Biotechnology and Biosafety Issues in Africa

ISO 9000 Certification

Testimony of the Biotechnology Industry Organization. Submitted to the California Assembly Committee on Agriculture.

THE CALIFORNIA RIGHT TO KNOW GENETICALLY ENGINEERED FOOD ACT

ISO INTERNATIONAL STANDARD. Risk management Principles and guidelines. Management du risque Principes et lignes directrices

Local Food Consumers: How Motivations and Perceptions Translate to Buying Behavior

Management System Manual International Compliance Group

Choosing Delivery Method

Electronic Sanitary and Phytosanitary (SPS) certification

Project on Organic Agriculture

Drafting conventions for Auditing Guidelines and key terms for public-sector auditing

THE ENERGY DEVELOPMENT CYCLE

Domtar Due Care Program Under the Lacey Act

Understanding and Proactively Preparing for Carbon Management

Certified Human Resources Professional (CHRP) Competency Framework

Food Fight: FSMA and the FDA s New Era of Enforcement. July By Sandra J. Wunderlich

7 Ways Food and Beverage Manufacturers Are Putting Data to Work to Build Profits

Non-GMO Project Product Verification Guide

GROUP HUMAN RIGHTS POLICY

NONPROFIT ACCOUNTABILITY: TO WHOM AND FOR WHAT? AN INTRODUCTION TO THE SPECIAL ISSUE

RGI Strategic Plan. 1. Background. 2. The Role of RGI. RGI Strategic Plan 2016

Annex 1 STANDARDS AND SPS MANAGEMENT: BASIC CONCEPTS

IFAP Cairo; May Keynote Speech

Coal-fired China: Rethink the Precautionary Principle

Developing and Improving Food Safety and Pesticide Monitoring (PRM) Programme - FAO Regional Perspective

Responding to RFPs. Slide 1 Responding to RFIs and RFPs Welcome this module on responding to RFIs and RFPs.

Chapter 11. Non-tariff Measures in Thailand. Chedtha Intaravitak Thailand Development Research Institute. April 2016

Source: USDA FAS. The U.S. is the world s top exporter of food and agricultural products.

STANDING COMMITTEE ON FINANCE AND ECONOMIC AFFAIRS. Consideration Of Bill 148 (Fair Workplaces, Better Jobs Act, 2017)

A FRAMEWORK FOR AUDIT QUALITY. KEY ELEMENTS THAT CREATE AN ENVIRONMENT FOR AUDIT QUALITY February 2014

Our Sustainable Supply Chain

Introduction to RRG Drafting Team Proposal

GMO and non GM coexistance implications in Poland as a New Member State of EU

A Framework for Audit Quality Key Elements That Create an Environment for Audit Quality

CHOICES The magazine of food, farm, and resource issues

The Food Safety Modernization Act: What Exporters to the U.S. Need to Know. Erik R. Lieberman Prepared for AgroBalt 2014 April 4, 2014

Managing in the Global Environment

CHAPTER 2: MARKETS AND MARKETING

International Sustainable Purchasing Charter

Transcription:

AgBioForum Volume 3, Number 1 2000 Pages 53-57 LABELING POLICY FOR GMOS: TO EACH HIS OWN? 1 Julie A. Caswell 1 GMO labeling policy for foods is under intense development. Countries are choosing mandatory labeling or adherence to voluntary labeling. Challenges to mandatory labeling are unlikely to be successful under current World Trade Organization (WTO) rules. Marketers and trade negotiators should recognize this and move toward living with diversity in labeling policy. Keywords: GMOs; biotechnology; labeling policy; trade disputes. We are at another important crossroads on the path that will determine the market acceptance of foods produced with the use of biotechnology. Individual governments are managing a range of policies that affect biotechnology, including those on research and development, intellectual property rights, regulatory approval (safety assessment), and labeling requirements. They are taking divergent policy paths that make for market uncertainty. At the same time, companies are announcing their intentions regarding the use or non-use of genetically modified organisms (GMOs) in their products. These intentions make the market less uncertain for sales to those companies but raise the stakes in predicting the choices of other companies. Labeling policy for food products is currently under intense development in several countries. What are the basic requirements for such labeling programs and what policies are countries adopting? What are the consequences of each country s pursuit of the policy that best seems to fit its needs? Finally, is it likely that these policies could be successfully challenged under WTO rules? Why Labeling Policy? Labeling is often used to deliver information to consumers on characteristics of products that they are not able to evaluate. Economists refer to this type of characteristic as a credence attribute (Darby & Karni, 1973; Caswell & Mojduszka, 1996). Whether a product is produced with the use of biotechnology or genetic engineering is frequently difficult or impossible for the consumer to judge. Labeling can transform such a credence characteristic into a search attribute that consumers can learn about by inspecting the product s package (Caswell, 1998; Caswell, 2000). 1 Julie A. Caswell is a Professor in the Department of Resource Economics at the University of Massachusetts at Amherst. 2000 AgBioForum.

Labeling affects the entire supply chain for food products. It requires definition of the attribute to be labeled (i.e., what is a GMO?) and segregation of products with and without the characteristics throughout the supply chain from seed inputs to the supermarket shelf. Because of this effect, labeling policy can be, and is even more frequently perceived to be, a Trojan horse bearing a broader policy and attitude toward the acceptance of GMOs in food products. Companies will voluntarily label use or non-use of GMOs if the private benefits of doing so exceed the costs. Thus, a market has developed for non-gmo products with companies incurring the costs of segregation and identity preservation in return for a higher price or sustained market share. Similarly, a GMO product with special characteristics can be voluntarily labeled to allow the sellers to capture the consumers willingness to pay for those characteristics. Governments may regulate labeling if they believe a certain type of information is important to consumers and is not being adequately supplied by the private market. Governments can choose a wide range of polices from simple prevention of fraud in labeling to instituting standards for voluntary labels or mandating labeling. What Labeling Policies Are Countries Choosing? Labeling policy often appears simple and straightforward. However, the policy is complex, particularly for process attributes (those that relate to how a product was produced rather than its final use characteristics). In choosing GMO labeling policy, a government must address the long series of questions shown in table 1. This list can serve as a useful framework for comparing policies. Broadly speaking, the labeling choices being made by countries fall into two broad camps. One camp, including the European Union, Japan, Australia, and New Zealand, among others, is pursuing mandatory labeling programs for GM food products, although in some cases voluntary labeling is retained for non-gm products. The other camp, which includes the United States (U.S.), has voluntary labeling as its main strategy, with labeling being required if important end characteristics of the product, such as its allergenic potential or nutritional content, are changed. Genetically modified organism labeling is a prime example of a quick moving policy area where individual countries are not willing to take the time necessary for development of international consensus on the best approaches. The strategy is to regulate now and worry about coordination or harmonization later. The recent record of discord and gridlock in the relevant Codex Alimentarius committees reinforces the everyone for themselves approach. An example of the developing differences in policy, even within the mandatory labeling camp, can be seen in provisions on when labeling requirements are triggered. The European Commission is proposing that mandatory labeling be triggered if more than 1% of an ingredient in a product is GM. Japan is proposing to require labeling only for selected products and for those products, only for important ingredients. Legislation has been introduced in the current session of Congress in the U.S. House of Representatives (Kucinich Bill, H.R. 3377) and Senate (Boxer Bill, S. 2080) to require mandatory GMO labeling in the United States. The Kucinich Bill is more detailed and specifies a selfcertification approach to labeling a product s GMO status. While it is unlikely either bill will pass in this session of Congress, they suggest the mix of policy choices being thought about by some U.S. legislators. In early May, the U.S. Food and Drug Administration reconfirmed its policy of voluntary labeling for GMO products, when they are not significantly altered, and for non-gmo products. Voluntary labeling will be actively supported through issuance on labeling guidelines and provision of certification and reference testing services by the U.S. Department of Agriculture.

Table 1: Elements Of GMO Labeling Policy. Policy Questions How are genetic engineering, genetic modification, or biotechnology defined? Some Policy Options Broadly By specific techniques used Is program voluntary or mandatory? Which products are covered by the policy? Which ingredients are covered? When are labeling requirements triggered? How are products made from animals fed with GM inputs handled? How are restaurant, take-out, bulk, and institutional foods handled? What label statements must/can be made? How are companies required to verify GM status? Can non-gmo labeling be used on products where there are no GM alternatives? Voluntary for non-gmo and/or GMO Mandatory for GMO Mandatory for GMO and non-gmo All food products Only key food products Only certain food categories All ingredients Only most important ingredients All ingredients except preservatives, additives, etc. X% of product is GM Most important ingredients are GM Important characteristics are altered Labeling required if feed is GM Labeling not required if feed is GM Included in labeling requirements Excluded from labeling requirements Does contain GMOs (genetically modified) May contain GMOs (may be genetically modified) Non-GMO Does not contain GMOs Self-certification by seller is acceptable Testing Third-party certification Yes No To Each His Own? Implications Of Differing Labeling Policy What are likely to be the benefits, costs, and market implications as each country pursues its own labeling policy in the short run? Proponents of biotechnology fear that the diverse labeling requirements, and particularly the mandatory requirements, will harm market acceptance of GMOs. They argue that in this uncertain environment companies may choose an easy route of simply going

non-gmo. However, going non-gmo is not simpler than going GM if both require certification and labeling. Certifying the absence of GMOs in a product may, in fact, be more costly. Thus, the marketlevel acceptance rather than the labeling itself determines whether companies choose to use GMOs. Each country is making complex decisions about the use of biotechnology and its labeling based on its perceptions of benefits and costs. A key tenet in countries that have adopted mandatory labeling policies is that consumers have a right to know whether biotechnology was used to produce the foods they consume. The extent of this right to know is defined based on a country s culture, economics, and politics. If a country feels there is a right to know, it often believes that benefit/cost analysis is not really relevant or assumes that the benefits of consumers knowing will be so large that they will outweigh the costs. In their view, the right to know is not circumscribed by safety considerations or notions of sound science. A country may believe consumers have a right to know regardless of safety concerns. If safety concerns are unresolved, the right to know argument is strengthened. Policy makers and analysts want to know whether the benefits of labeling outweigh the costs. We know that this balance depends on the type of program adopted and market conditions. For example, voluntary labeling programs may deliver benefits more efficiently when a small segment of the population is interested in the GM status of food products and is willing to pay more for products carrying this information. On the other hand, if most people want to know, then mandatory programs may be more effective. On the cost side, the supply chain requirements for segregating product will be the main determinant of costs. Overall, identity preservation is becoming a much more frequent and integral part of quality assurance in the supply chain. The issue is not whether this segregation is feasible for GMOs but how costly it is, which in turn will depend on how much of the supply chain needs to be segregated for both domestic and export markets. Of course, these costs will also differ depending on the time frame for adoption of segregation and the rigor of the certification process. Few studies have yet appeared regarding the costs of GM labeling. In a study commissioned from KPMG by the Australia New Zealand Food Authority (ANZFA), the cost to industry of the proposed mandatory labeling program was estimated to be 6% of turnover (sales) in the first year of implementation and 3% in subsequent years (ANZFA, 1999). However, ANZFA did not accept these estimates because the study assumed a much more elaborate system of private certification/testing and government oversight than ANZFA envisioned (ANZFA, 1999). An updated economic and financial assessment is being prepared. An important issue in the ultimate benefits and costs is how effectively labels convey information that consumers want (Runge & Jackson, 2000). This depends on the certainty of the labeling (e.g., does contain versus may contain ) and the actual ability of the supply chain to provide high levels of integrity in the segregation process. Effective labeling, whether voluntary or mandatory, can facilitate product differentiation and efficient specialization of different segments of industry within or across countries in producing GM or non-gm products. The Trade Environment Labeling programs allow countries to tailor policies to their own needs. For example, a country can go slow in allowing genetically engineered crops to be grown within its boundaries, while allowing such crops and food products grown elsewhere to be imported as long as they are labeled. As noted, several key trading partners of the U.S. are instituting mandatory labeling policies. There has been much discussion of whether these policies might be challenged under the WTO as illegitimate nontariff barriers to trade. A WTO challenge is unlikely to be successful as long as it is feasible to comply with the regulations and they are applied equally to domestic and foreign products.

If mandatory labeling policies were challenged under the Agreement on the Application of Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures as a food safety-related policy, the challenged country would argue that the policy is warranted in the short run in the absence of definitive evidence of the technology s safety and while further evidence in being developed. However, if this defense were unsuccessful, the country would have a very strong fall back position under the Agreement on Technical Barriers to Trade, which has less rigorous rules. The country would only have to show that the policy is intended and designed to achieve a specific legitimate objective and the costs of implementing the labeling are proportional to the purpose of the standard. In this case, the country would argue that the objective is the consumer s right to know and the mandatory labeling policy is effectively designed to achieve the goal. Thus, labeling programs for GMOs are unlikely to be subject to successful challenge under the WTO. For the United States, the current voluntary labeling policy may well deliver the best balance of benefits and costs. Certainly FDA s recent policy announcements reconfirm its commitment to voluntary labeling. However, given their own circumstances, mandatory labeling is viewed to be the best choice for trading partners such as the European Union. Marketers and trade negotiators should recognize this and move toward living with diversity in labeling policy. In the longer run, labeling policy may converge but this will not occur any time soon. It is also important to consider that labeling might enhance market acceptance of GMOs. Consumers increasingly want to buy food products based on a wide variety of food attributes, including how the product was produced. The marketing system has to provide this choice, either through effective voluntary or mandatory labeling. References Australia New Zealand Food Authority (ANZFA). (1999). ANZFA October resolution. and Report on the compliance costs facing industry and government regulators in relation to labelling genetically modified foods. Available on the World Wide Web: http://www.anzfa.gov.au/documents/gen24_99.asp. Caswell, J.A. (2000). An evaluation of risk analysis as applied to agricultural biotechnology (With a case study of GMO labeling). Agribusiness, 16(1), 115-123. Caswell, J.A. (1998). Should use of genetically modified organisms be labeled? AgBioForum, 1 (1), 22-24. Available on the World Wide Web : http://www.agbioforum.org. Caswell, J.A., and Mojduszka, E.M. (1996). Using informational labeling to influence the market for quality in food products. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 78(4), 1248-1253. Darby, M.R., and Karni, E. (1973). Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud. Journal of Law and Economics, 16(1), 67-88. Runge, C.F., and Jackson, L.A. (in press). Labeling, trade, and genetically modified organisms (GMOs): A proposed solution. Journal of World Trade.