The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs

Similar documents
Renewable Energy Consumption: Initiatives in Colorado and Washington

An Institutional Analysis Of the Transition to Renewable Energy

The Effects of Land Conservation on Productivity

CHAIRMAN S SUMMARY. Renewable Energy: a Route to Decarbonisation in Peril?

EFFECTIVENESS OF STATE FINANCIAL INCENTIVES AND REGULATIONS IN PROMOTING SOLAR ENERGY TECHNOLOGIES

Keywords: commercial solar PV, solar incentives, renewable energy policies

IssuesLetter. Making Room for Renewables

The National Academy of Sciences

The Berkeley FIRST Program: A life-cycle assessment of the costs and greenhouse gas emissions. Christian Lazzarini

The impact of Environmental Policy on U.S. Job Growth and Unemployment

KEY MARKET FORECASTS: APPLICATIONS: TECHNOLOGIES: GEOGRAPHIES:

Making Sense of U.S. Energy Markets

Renewable Portfolio Standards U.S. Overview

Projecting Domestic Energy Use into the Future

Distinguish between different types of numerical data and different data collection processes.

The relationship between innovation and economic growth in emerging economies

REA response to DECC Consultation on the Renewable Heat Incentive Non-domestic scheme early tariff review

Oregon Renewable Energy Resources

State Support for Solar Energy: Policies, Programs & Trends

A TOOL TO MARKET CUSTOMER-SITED SMALL WIND SYSTEMS

Changes in Gasoline Prices and Consumer Sentiment

The Economic Impact of Wind Power Development

Profound changes underway in energy markets Signs of decoupling of energy-related CO 2 emissions and global economic growth Oil prices have fallen pre

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

Chapter 1. An Introduction to Econometrics. 1.1 Why Study Econometrics?

Issues in Political Economy, Vol 26(2), 2017,

Dominion Virginia Power and Clean Power Plan Costs: A brief review of the Dominion s 2015 Integrated Resource Plan compliance cost estimates

Addressing the Climate Crisis: The Current Energy Policy Landscape of Oregon & the U.S.

The State of Play for Renewable Energy

Submission to the Senate Standing Committee on Environment, Communications and the Arts

Load Forecasting: Methods & Techniques. Dr. Chandrasekhar Reddy Atla

Renewable Power and Energy Efficiency: Policies in Iowa and Other States

Memo on the Renewable Energy and Climate Change Package

Using Real-Time Pricing and Information Provision to Shift Intra-Day Electricity Consumption: Evidence from Denmark *

WREF2012: CALCULATING A NATION S ECONOMIC SOLAR POTENTIAL A GENERAL METHODOLOGY AND RESULTS FOR THE UNITED STATES

Would Energy Tax Policy Significantly Influence the Diffusion. Rate of The Renewable Energy Portfolio in The United States?

Wind Energy in Canada

The Cost of Adapting to Climate Change: Evidence from the US Residential Sector

Incentivizing Solar Energy:

How Much Ethanol Can Be Consumed in E85?

Microgeneration An Energy Revolution?

Three State Regional Analysis Creating Solar- Ready Communities Minnesota - Wisconsin Illinois

The Effect of GDP per capita on Renewable Energy Production in China

Speech by Jillian Broadbent AO, Chair, Clean Energy Finance Corporation to the CEDA Energy Series, Renewable Energy Financing Models

Incentive Programs in the United States. Stephane de la Rue du Can International Energy Studies Group Lawrence Berkeley National Laboratory

Global and National JULY 8, 2010

Submission to the Victorian Competition and Efficiency Commission Feed in Tariff Inquiry

Solar PV in ASEAN Challenges and Opportunities. Peerapat Vithayasrichareon Centre for Energy and Environmental Markets (CEEM), UNSW Australia

Levelized Cost of New Generation Resources in the Annual Energy Outlook 2012

NIEIR Review of EDD weather standards for Victorian gas forecasting

Energy-Efficiency Programs: A Supplemental Guide for Small Manufacturing Businesses.

Keynote Address By. Mr. Adnan Amin Director-General International Renewable Energy Agency. to the

DTE Proposed Plant Clean Portfolio Total 5, Wind 2, Solar 2,335 18

The Impact of Ethanol and Ethanol Subsidies on Corn Prices: Revisiting History

19 November Dr Lynne Williams. Review of Climate Change Act PO Box 500 East Melbourne 8002

THE ROLE OF OLSON S INTEREST GROUPS THEORY IN EXPLAINING THE DIFFERENT LEVEL OF AGRICULTURAL SUPPORT IN COUNTRIES WITH DIFFERENT DEVELOPMENT LEVEL 1

Renewable Energy in Alaska. Micah Chelimo, Carrie Haisley, & Tanya Komakhuk PADM A628: Spring 2018

Lessons to be learnt from the German Renewables Experience

Long Island Institute for Socio-Economic Policy

INDIA S ENERGY BASKET ANALYSIS: Dr. DC Patra Bharat Petroleum

South Australia Energy Transformation (Riverlink) RIT-T Total Environment Centre Submission

The Economic Impacts of Renewal Energy on Local Economies: The Case of Solar Energy in Japan

The Impacts of the Green Communities Act on the Massachusetts Economy:

G EA. Green Energy Alliance of Alberta

Electric Power from Sun and Wind

Key Findings (English)

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Energy Policy 2012 Annual Update

Technology Executive Committee

Determination of the Parameters That Effect the Residential Electrical Consumption of Turkey

Geothermal Heat Pumps and Direct Use

CLEAN ENERGY FOR ALL EUROPEANS

Policy Support for Renewable Energy Continues to Grow and Evolve

Industrial Engineering Prof. Inderdeep Singh Department of Mechanical and Industrial Engineering Indian Institute of Technology, Roorkee

Impact of Electricity Crisis on Industrial Growth in Pakistan: A Multiple Regression Analysis Approach

Bank of America Corporation Estimated economic benefits of the Environmental Business Initiative September 2017

Evaluating predictive models for solar energy growth in the US states and identifying the key drivers

An Empirical Exploration of the Effects of Natural Gas Prices on Solar Energy Growth

Energy Matters The Little Green Book

Nuclear Power A Vital Part of a Balanced Energy Future Platts Nuclear Energy Conference Bethesda, MD February 17, 2011 (11:00 a.m.

Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy

Individual Water Reduction in Accordance with California State Water Mandate. Becker, Jake Karabinos, Brian Smith, Kyle

Do the BRICs and Emerging Markets Differ in their Agrifood Trade?

6 THINGS ECONOMISTS THINK JOURNALISTS SHOULD KNOW ABOUT GHG REDUCTION POLICY

AN ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION AND ECONOMIC GROWTH IN ZIMBABWE

Electricity Scenario Analysis. for the. Vermont Comprehensive Energy Plan 2011

REGULATORY POLICY AND RESIDENTIAL MAIN EXTENSIONS

Environmental Kuznets Curve Hypothesis? or Pollution Haven Hypothesis? A Comparison of the Two

/JordanStrategyForumJSF Jordan Strategy Forum. Amman, Jordan T: F:

UNDP S WORK ON SUSTAINABLE ENERGY

TREASURE COAST REGIONAL PLANNING COUNCIL M E M O R A N D U M. To: Council Members AGENDA ITEM 8

Small Wind All Things Considered DWEA 2013

1 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY. Executive Summary 1-1

Modelling the UK's CO2 Emissions. BEIS September 2018

Does Energy Consumption Cause Economic Growth? Empirical Evidence From Tunisia

Chapter 26 Answers to Short-Answer, Essays, and Problems

The economics of distributed generation. Zoltán LONTAY Energy expert

Corporate renewable energy procurement survey insights

Venezuela Renewable Energy Policy Handbook Power

Transcription:

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby Volume 4 Issue 1 Article 9 2017 The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs Fred Bower Colby College, fmbower@colby.edu Follow this and additional works at: http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec Part of the Economics Commons, Environmental Studies Commons, Oil, Gas, and Energy Commons, and the Sustainability Commons Recommended Citation Bower, Fred (2017) "The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs," Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby: Vol. 4 : Iss. 1, Article 9. Available at: http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 This Article is brought to you for free and open access by Digital Commons @ Colby. It has been accepted for inclusion in Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby by an authorized editor of Digital Commons @ Colby. For more information, please contact mfkelly@colby.edu.

The Long-Term Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs Abstract Abstract: Renewable energy is praised for its environmental benefits and long run energy savings, however, for the average consumer, the up-front cost of this infrastructure deters investment. On the Federal and state level, incentive programs have been implemented to break down these initial barriers and give easier access to renewable energy. Studies have shown that these incentive programs have been successful at the consumer level (Crago, 2014). What policy makers and government officials should maybe be more concerned with though, is the long-term effect of these programs. This paper will analyze the long-term effect of renewable energy incentive programs beyond the household level, to establish whether these programs are mere individual aids or true drivers for prolonged and significant production of wind and solar energy sources. This paper s results suggest that state funded renewable energy incentive programs can be drivers for commercial renewable production. Results show that the most influential policies for long-run renewable production provide educational and technological resources to consumers and businesses, rather than simple monetary and financial incentives. Keywords state renewable energy incentives, incentives, renewable energy, financial incentives, regulatory policy, technological resources, renewable energy growth, renewable energy production This article is available in Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby: http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/ iss1/9

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs Introduction: According to the United States Energy Information Administration, of the total energy that the US currently produces, 11% is from renewable energy sources (EIA 2017). While on a levels basis this makes the United States one of the renewable energy leaders in the world, this share amounts to only 10% of the total energy consumption in the US. Therefore, the country instead is one of the least clean on a share of renewable energy consumption basis (World Bank 2017). This, combined with increasing awareness of negative externalities associated with fossil fuels, has policy makers in the US looking for ways to quickly grow their renewable energy production. Policy makers have two choices, the first being to mandate, and the second being to incentivize. The second option is arguably a more free market approach. This method has been utilized at the both the federal and state level through the implementation of various incentive policies. These renewable energy incentive programs are generally aimed towards the individual and household, and fall under the three categories of 1) financial incentives, 2) technological resources, and 3) regulatory policy (DSIRE 2017). These incentive programs have increased greatly in popularity, causing the impact of these programs to be studied in depth. Economists Christine Crago and Ilya Chernyakhovskiy examined the effect of financial incentive programs specifically on residential solar photovoltaic capacity. The results showed that rebate programs had the largest effect of photovoltaic growth causing a 50% jump in residential solar output in the Northeast (Crago, 2014). Furthermore, economists Christoph Bauner and Christine Crago in a different study found that without incentive programs at all, median adoption time for household solar photovoltaic is 8 years longer than with the programs (Bauner, 2015). Thus, there is evidence that these policies are effective at the household level, particularly with respect to solar technology. However, another study, which observed incentive policies influence on mobilizing households to invest in low carbon technology, was largely inconclusive and discovered that households do not always operate in economically rational manners (Curtin et. al., 2017). Therefore, existing literature studying the effect of renewable energy incentives has lacked in three ways: the first, being that there is mixed evidence regarding their effect at the household level; the second being that there has been little discussion about the effect of these policies beyond households, on a more commercial and national level; and the third being that most studies are focused to a small region of the country, such as California or the Northeast (Kwan, 2012) (Crago, 2014). Thus, this paper aims to address the question of whether these programs are effective beyond the household, for increased production of all renewable energy at the state and national level. When a policy maker is deciding how to help grow renewable energy production in their state, it is important to have a clear Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 1

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby, Vol. 4 [2017], Iss. 1, Art. 9 understanding of what greater impact an incentive policy will have in the long run. This paper analyzes differences in state renewable energy production caused by their specific financial incentives, technological resources, and regulatory policies. Contrary to previous findings, this paper s results suggest that for state wide renewable energy production, technological resources are the most influential incentive category. This insight is tested in an expansion, where different models are utilized to examine technological incentives in depth. The paper proceeds as follows: Section 1 discusses the data used for analysis and presents basic summary statistics at the state level, Section 2 includes the empirical framework and methodology used to address the research question, Section 3 analyzes the specific results and insight from the findings, and Section 4 concludes the paper. Data: In this paper the two main data categories under examination are renewable energy production and state renewable incentive programs. For information concerning energy production and consumption, data was sourced from the US Energy Information Association. For information on state incentive programs, data is sourced from the Database of State Incentives for Renewables and Efficiency. There are 50 states, each with renewable energy production levels from 1960 through 2014, total energy production levels, current number of incentive programs are separated into the three categories (financial incentives, regulatory policy, and technological resources), and basic growth rates and levels on a total and per capita basis. Financial incentives are any program that offers monetary discounts for renewable development. These include corporate tax incentives, feed in tariffs, grant programs, green building incentives, loan programs, performance based incentives, rebate programs, and more (DSIRE, 2017). Regulatory policies are any program that establishes a minimum standard or rule for green consumption and production. These can include building standards, appliance standards, net metering, solar and wind access policies, renewable energy licensing, and more (DSIRE, 2017). Technological resources are programs that provide information or knowledge about renewable energy developments. These programs include energy analysis, training and information, or easier access to renewable experts (DSIRE 2017). Ultimately, there are roughly 3,350 important observations. Through this data framework, the resolution is on the state level and on an annual basis. Unfortunately, DSIRE does not provide starting and ending dates with overall program data, thus the ideal set of panel data was not collected and the data operates simply as cross sectional data. To build an argument suggesting causality, more specific panel data regarding starting dates for these programs was collected during a shorter period http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 2

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs from 2010 to 2012. DSIRE begins the technological resource incentive category in this period, therefore it offers a good starting point to examine policy effects. Using DSIRE to manually discover a collection of states which implemented policies in this period, a small set of panel data was created for this extension. Figure 1 shows visually the number of incentive programs that each state has implemented that are currently operating. The first choropleth shows total incentives in each state, and the subsequent choropleths show the breakdown of financial incentives, technological resources, and regulatory policies, as each state has varying ratios of the three types. To highlight the basic research question, Figure 2 shows the positive correlation between number of incentives and the renewable energy output of each state. The fact that states with higher numbers of incentive programs have higher renewable energy production begs the question of if these programs are causing directly and purposefully the increased output. Lastly, looking at Figure 4, one can observe a sample of five states that highlights the huge difference between states in their evolution of renewable energy production over this time period. The variety of growth and levels between states shows that there are definite factors that cause some states to grow very quickly, while some states do not grow, or even fall off. This paper will look at the extent to which these jumps and lags are caused by renewable incentives and regulatory policy. Figure 1. Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 3

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby, Vol. 4 [2017], Iss. 1, Art. 9 Figure 2. Figure 3. Summary Statistics Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Number Incentives 50 78.76 50.82726 15 268 Renewable Production 14 50 151476.2 175310.4 4189 928071 Average Growth 50 2.085299 1.616173 -.3205396 8.756782 No. Financial Incentives 50 39.22 28.48006 3 135 No. Regulatory Policies 50 12.24 8.338649 3 48 No. Technological Res 50 26.84 18.63983 1 85 Total Consumption/Cap. 50 358.2 176.0347 190 921 Renewable Prod/Cap 50 49.06742 57.77247 4.070821 260.3472 Population 50 6414932 7228713 586107 3.91e+07 *(All energy production and consumption values in Million Btu) http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 4

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs Figure 4. Empirical Strategy: The first part of this paper will examine the strength of the three different incentive programs. The hypothesized linear model for renewable energy production is given by the following equation: Pi = β0 + β1fi + β2ri + β3ti + β4si + β5li + β6e + εi (1) Here, Pi represents per capita renewable energy production in 2014. β0 represents a constant. β1, β2, and β3 all represent the influence of a one program increase in financial incentives, technological resources, and regulatory policies respectively on renewable energy production. Li represents population, and Si represents the renewable output level from the initial 1960 starting point in the data. Including each state s starting point allows the difference in levels of each state to be largely accounted for, to allow the specific effect of the incentives to be more accurate. E represents energy expenditure per capita for each state to control for budget differences. Due to the fact that Equation 1 is only observing changes between states, this equation is not time sensitive. The lack of time sensitivity in equation 1 makes it difficult to test for causality. As the paper will later discuss, technological resources seem to be the most important category of incentive to drive state renewable production. In an extension of this first test, this paper employs three unique models to check for the specific effect of technological resources. The below equation represents the Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 5

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby, Vol. 4 [2017], Iss. 1, Art. 9 methodology behind the thinking: β * = (PI1-PI0) (PN1-PN0) (2) Equation 2 aims to calculate an incentive effect, β *, by finding the change in renewable energy production over a period of time in a state that just started an incentive program and subtracting the change in renewable production from a state that did not implement a policy during this time period. Thus, (PI1-PI0) is the change in a state s renewable energy output during a new policy and (PN1-PN0) represents the renewable production change in a state that did not implement any new incentives. This broadly will indicate whether these policies and incentives specifically are driving renewable energy production changes. For the distinct three different models, starting in 2010, each one represents a variation of quantifying technological resource incentives. One models observes simply if there was any technological sources at all, the other looks at how many technological resources there was in 2010, and the third represents how many technological resources there was enacted for non-residential use. Results: Beginning with the first linear regression model we can observe that not all renewable energy incentive programs are created equal. Both financial incentives and regulatory policies are statistically insignificant, meaning that they have no influence on the state renewable energy output on the whole. While this may seem contrary to previous literature and research, there are a few explanations. The first explanation is that these policies may not be aimed at larger commercial renewable energy production. Previous literature has shown the effect of financial incentives on household renewable investment, but no studies have examined their impact at a larger scale. It is possible that these two types of incentives are more focused on changing household level energy behavior, in which case the production of renewable energy at the state level would look largely unchanged. Furthermore, regulatory policies are not incentives at all; they are forced changes. In other words, regulation may force households and businesses to comply with the new regulation, offering no incentive or benefit to go any further. Regulatory policies may certainly be causing change, but do not encourage continuous and significant development of energy at the larger level. Moving to technological resources, Table 1 shows a statistically significant and positive relationship between these incentives and per capita renewable energy production. An increase in one technological resource in a state is associated with an increase in per capita renewable energy production of 1.24 million Btu per year. This is statistically significant at 95% confidence interval, thus, we must reject the null hypothesis that technological resources have no influence over state renewable energy production in favor of the alternative hypothesis, that these resources are positively related to renewable production. One explanation for why this incentive type is more effective than the others is http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 6

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs that they increase the overall accessibility of renewable energy. If we remember the specific resources that they provide, they are energy analysis, training, and information programs. These policies are education and access focused, so it is logical that they would help boost renewable energy production as people learn more about the energy, and are given easier access to its technology. This regression also includes population. Population is statistically significant at the 95% confidence interval, indicating that for every additional 1 million people in a state, there is a reduction in per capita renewable energy production of 3.93 million Btu. Part of this may be explained by the fact that the dependent variable is on a per capita basis. However, there may also be other factors behind this. One explanation would be that renewable energy developments are large projects that take up large sections of often very rural areas. In other words, the more dense a population, the less likely a developer would be able to insert a renewable energy source such as a wind farm, solar array, or hydro-electric dam. For an extreme example, in New York City, it would be near impossible to construct a substantial wind farm. In northern Maine, however, it would be quite easy, cheap, and inoffensive. From this, we also interpret the significant coefficient on energy expenditure suggesting that an increase in per capital energy spending of 1 dollar is related to a 12,900 Btu increase in per capita renewable energy production. Lastly, this regression includes the initial 1960 s level of renewable energy production. While at first one would expect this to be closely related to the current level of renewable energy production, the variable is statistically insignificant. This could be a positive sign that a state s starting point may not be such a defining factor of its future renewable energy production. It could indicate that some states have been more successful in their policy choices, and have been able to drastically change their renewable output. Table 1. VARIABLES Model 1 Financial Incentives -0.329 (0.487) Regulatory Policy 0.964 (1.547) Technological Resource 1.246** (0.581) Population -3.93e-06** (1.67e-06) Initial Level 1960 0.000188 (0.000114) Expenditure per Capita 0.0129*** (0.00461) Constant -32.71 (30.63) Observations 50 R-squared 0.362 Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 7

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby, Vol. 4 [2017], Iss. 1, Art. 9 Now that it has been established that technological resources are most effective for state renewable energy production, this paper builds three models around those specific policies. As discussed in Section 2, Empirical Strategies, the states that implemented a technological resource policy in 2010 are categorized in binary form (Model 1), numerical form (Model 2), and non-residential form (Model 3). In Table 2, we can examine these results. Ultimately the goal of model 1, is to establish a relationship between states which started these programs and their energy output. There exists a positive relationship significant to the 95% confidence level, which allows us to reject the null hypothesis in favor of the alternative hypothesis that technological resources are important for renewable energy production. The same is true in model 2, where a 1 technological resource increase is associated with a 73.99 billion Btu increase in renewable energy production. Model 3 seeks to explore the differences between household and commercial scale incentives. As traditional research has shown, the households have been a favorite for policy incentive makers. However, one could hypothesize that commercial and business level energy production is likely a bigger influencer for state wide renewable production, so by looking at non-residential policies, it should indicate if the target audience for these incentives is important. The value in this model is statistically insignificant unfortunately, so we cannot interpret it. Table 2. TREATMENT (1) (2) (3) VARIABLES Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 2010 Resource (0/1) 126,448** (52,890) 2010 Resource (No.) 73,985* (42,365) 2010 Non Residential 90,567 Resource (0/1) (73,447) Constant 99,597*** 107,131*** 115,830*** (23,653) (23,965) (23,226) Observations 50 50 50 R-squared 0.106 0.060 0.031 Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 This exercise can be extended one step further to evaluate the longer term effects http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 8

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs of such policies. Using lags, we can estimate if there is a lasting effect from technological resource incentives. In Table 3, there are a series of lags. The first, Lag 0, represents the coefficient from Model 1 of Table 2. From this point forward, the horizon is extended in 1 year intervals to see if these 2010 policies are effecting renewable energy production in the long run. Table 3. VARIABLES Lag 0 Lag 1 Lag 2 Lag 3 Lag 4 2010 Policy Resource 126,448** 134,135** 125,849** 141,888** 144,058** (52,890) (66,068) (61,236) (58,269) (59,071) Constant 99,597*** 115,686*** 112,516*** 118,594*** 122,665*** (23,653) (29,547) (27,386) (26,058) (26,417) Observations 50 50 50 50 50 R-squared 0.106 0.079 0.081 0.110 0.110 Standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 In every one of the lags, there exists a positive and statistically significant value. In short, this suggests that states which were the first to begin the implementation of technological resources for renewable energy development experienced larger output of renewable energy 4 years into the future. While this does not prove causality directly, it certainly shows the strong relationship between the two variables of interest. Conclusion: This paper addresses the broader effect of state renewable energy incentive programs. Ultimately, the results suggest that for state wide renewable energy production, technological incentives are the strongest type of program. Previous research has shown the success of financial incentives, with a particular attention given to rebate programs at the household level. This paper breaks away from the concentration of research on financial incentives, and household level analysis, to examine the effect of all types of state renewable energy incentive policies on state production of renewables. The contribution of this paper is showing the break between household adoption of renewable technology and state and national adoption of renewable energy. Policy makers can make the most difference at the state level through technological resources, rather than financial incentives, which may be more suited for household adoption. With that said, the methodology of this paper can be much stronger. While Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 9

Journal of Environmental and Resource Economics at Colby, Vol. 4 [2017], Iss. 1, Art. 9 intuitive in its approach, shear number of policies is not the best way to categorize the strength of a state s renewable energy incentives. Future research in this area will be challenged to find a different numerical strategy to gauge the strength of a state s technological resources and regulatory policies. However, for the interim, the results are quite positive: rather than financial incentives being the largest driver for growth, technological resources are. It is not money that causes increased production of renewable energy. It is education. http://digitalcommons.colby.edu/jerec/vol4/iss1/9 10

Bower: The Effect of State Renewable Energy Incentive Programs Works Cited: Bauner, Christoph. Crago, Christine. 2015. Adoption of residential solar power under uncertainty: Implications for renewable energy incentives Energy Policy 86: 27-35. Science Direct. Crago, Christine, and Ilya Chernyakhovskiy. 2014. "Are Policy Incentives for Solar Power Effective? Evidence from Residential Installations in the Northeast." Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 81: 132-51. Science Direct. Curtin, Joseph, Celine McIrnerney, and Brian Gallachoir. 2016. "Financial Incentives to Mobilise Local Citizens as Investors in Low-carbon Technologies: A Systematic Literature Review." Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 75: 534-47. Science Direct. DSIRE. "Database of State Incentives for Renewables & Efficiency." Web. May 2017. Kwan, C.L., 2012. Influence of local environmental, social, economic and political variables on the spatial distribution of residential solar PV arrays across the United States. Energy Policy 47 (2), 332 344. New Jersey. 2017. Department of Labor and Workforce Development Gross Domestic Product by State (formerly Gross State Product-GSP) US Energy Information Administration. 2017. U.S. Energy Facts - Energy Explained, Your Guide To Understanding Energy - Energy Information Administration. World Bank. 2017. Data Indicators. Renewable Energy Consumption share. Published by Digital Commons @ Colby, 2017 11