Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania Institute of Social and Economic Research -- Osaka University

Similar documents
Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Network Competition, Product Quality, and Market Coverage in the Presence of Network Externalities

Price ceilings and quality competition. Abstract

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

Endogenous Timing in a Vertically D Title Duopoly with Quantity Competition. Citation Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics,

The Review of Economic Studies Ltd.

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS. Jonathan Vogel. Working Paper

FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 985

Chih-Chen Liu and Leonard F.S. Wang *

Quality Choice, Fixed Costs and Equilibrium in Models of Vertical Differentiation 1

American Association for Public Opinion Research

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Agglomeration in a vertically-linked oligopoly

Indivisibilities in the Ricardian model of trade

Industrial Organization 04

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Part II. Market power

Bonanno, G. (1987), Location Choice, Product Proliferation and Entry Deterrence, Review of

The Suntory and Toyota International Centres for Economics and Related Disciplines

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at

REGIONAL RESTRICTION, STRATEGIC DELEGATION, AND WELFARE

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Search markets: Introduction

Activity Rules and Equilibria in the Combinatorial Clock Auction

Entry and Quality Competition in Hotelling Model with Exogenous Prices

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Lecture 6: Profit reducing price discrimination, and product differentiation Tom Holden

Two-sided markets with multihoming and exclusive dealing

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

Tariff Policy Towards a Monopolist in the Presence of Persuasive Advertising

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Strategic Choice of Channel Structure in an Oligopoly

Microeconomic Theory -1- Introduction and maximization

Information Acquisition and Price Discrimination

Lecture 4 (continued): The Sutton Model of the Size Distribution

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment

Using Bill and Keep Interconnect Arrangements to Soften Network Competition

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

The Economics of Industry Exam Review. June 14, 2002

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers

1. Introduction. during Aizcorbe (2006) notes that quality adjusted prices of semiconductor chips fell at an annual rate of 36%

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Chapter 25: Monopoly Behavior

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Intellectual Property Right Protection in the Software Market

Uniform and Targeted Advertising with Shoppers and. Asymmetric Loyal Market Shares

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

December 3, Eric Rasmusen, Web: Mypage.iu.edu/ erasmuse. Class 29, G601. TIROLE, CHAPTER 7: Horizontal Differentiation

Demo or No Demo: Supplying Costly Signals to Improve Profits

Differentiation as innovation and the impact of competition

Pricing distortions in multi-sided platforms

Key words: Franchise Fees, Competition, Double Marginalization, Collusion

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

EconS Bertrand Competition

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

Pricing, Advertising and Trade Policy

Competing Payment Schemes

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

IS PERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION REALLY EFFICIENT? AN ANALYSIS OF FREE ENTRY EQUILIBRIA

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Pricing Game under Imbalanced Power Structure

Working Paper No Can By-product Lobbying Firms Compete? Paul Pecorino

Strategic Trade Policies and Managerial Incentives under International Cross Ownership 1

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Homogeneous Platform Competition with Heterogeneous Consumers

Expanding Demand through Price Advertisement

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

movement of goods and labor. According to Hatton and Williamson (2005), average industrial

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

Agility in Repeated Games: An Example

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission.

Solutions to Final Exam

The Bargaining Problem. John F. Nash, Jr. Econometrica, Vol. 18, No. 2. (Apr., 1950), pp

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand.

OPTIMAL RENTING/SELLING STRATERGIES IN OLIGOPOLY DURABLE GOODS MARKETS. Golovko Sergiy

Social Learning and Monopolist s Product. Launching Strategy. Job Market Paper

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

PIER Working Paper

CHAPTER II SEQUENCING MODELS

Quiz #4 Week 04/05/2009 to 04/11/2009

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Strategic Choice of Quality When Quality is Costly: The Persistence of the High-Quality Advantage

Transcription:

Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania Institute of Social and Economic Research -- Osaka University International Trade in Differentiated Products Author(s): J. Jaskold Gabszewicz, Avner Shaked, John Sutton, J. -F. Thisse Source: International Economic Review, Vol. 22, No. 3 (Oct., 1981), pp. 527-534 Published by: Blackwell Publishing for the Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania and Institute of Social and Economic Research -- Osaka University Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2526155 Accessed: 15/09/2008 07:37 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showpublisher?publishercode=black. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit organization founded in 1995 to build trusted digital archives for scholarship. We work with the scholarly community to preserve their work and the materials they rely upon, and to build a common research platform that promotes the discovery and use of these resources. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Economics Department of the University of Pennsylvania, Blackwell Publishing, Institute of Social and Economic Research -- Osaka University are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to International Economic Review. http://www.jstor.org

INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC REVIEW Vol. 22, No. 3, October, 1981 INTERNATIONAL TRADE IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS" BY J. JASKOLD GABSZEWIcZ, AVNER SHAKED, JOHN SUTTON AND J.-F. THISSE 1. INTRODUCTION The present paper is concerned with the problem of analyzing international trade in differentiated products. Since this involves the introduction of new goods in each market, we require some specification of consumer preferences over a range of actual or potential substitute goods. A general analysis of this problem involves familiar difficulties. Recent progress in the area has depended on various, particular, structures of preferences.' We here consider a special case whose salient features are that a number of firms produce rival products which differ in 'quality,' the 'quality' of each firm's product being fixed exogenously; that each consumer purchases (at most) one of the alternative products; and that market equilibrium is characterized as a noncooperative price equilibrium.2 Our central theme is that the number of products which can coexist at equilibrium in such a market is bounded (even though we assume a continuum of consumers, and no costs); and that, on joining two economies to form a 'common market,' there is a tendency for the total number of products coexisting at equilibrium to fall underfree trade; the lowest quality goods disappearfrom the market. No general analysis is offered; instead, we confine ourselves to providing a simple, but suggestive, example of a partial equilibrium type. This is outlined in Section 2, for the case of a single economy. The effect of international trade between two such economies is examined in Section 3. The implication of our central proposition, as well as some brief comments on how the analysis might be generalized, are given in the concluding Section 4. 2. INDUSTRY EQUILIBRIUM IN A SINGLE COUNTRY Consider an industry consisting of a number of firms producing at zero cost distinct, substitute, goods. We label their respective products by an index k= 1,..., n, where firm k sells product k at price Pk- Assume a continuum of consumers identical in tastes but differing in income; * Manuscript received August 5, 1980; revised January 5, 1981. I For example, the 'characteristics' model of Lancaster [1980], or the Dixit-Stiglitz model (Dixit and Stiglitz [1977], Krugman [1979]). 2 Our analysis rests on the model of Gabszewicz and Thisse [1980]. An analogous preference structure is postulated in Shaked and Sutton [1981]. 527

528 GABSZEWICZ, SHAKED, SUTTON AND THISSE incomes are uniformly distributed over some range, [a, b], a> 0 so that the density function of income t is I K a<t<b g(t) = ) = otherwise. Thus K(b -a) is a measure of the size of the economy. Consumers make indivisible and mutually exclusive purchases from among our n substitute goods, in the sense that any consumer either makes no purchase, or else buys exactly one unit from one of the n firms. We denote by U(t, k) the utility achieved by consuming one unit of product k and t units of 'other things' (the latter may be thought of as a Hicksian 'composite commodity,' measured as a continuous variable); and by U(t, 0) the utility derived from consuming t units of income only. Assume that the utility function takes the form (1) and U(t, k)= Uk- t k = 1,.., n U(t, 0) = u0e t with O<uo<u1<...<un (i.e., the products are labeled in increasing order of quality). Let Ck= = k Uk - Uk-1 (whence Ck> 1). Then we may define the income level tk such that a consumer with this income will be indifferent between good k at price Pk and good k- 1 at price Pk- 1 ViZ., (2) and tk = Pk-1(l - Ck) + PkCk tl= P1Cl This is easily checked by reference to (1). Assuming zero costs, the profit (revenue) of the k-th firm is, for any3 density function f(t), Rim = Pn fb f(t)dt t<n Rk = Pk "f(t)dt I < k < n. tk I It is only when discussing a single economy, in Lemmas 2 and 3, that we appeal to the assumption that the density function g(t) is uniform.

TRADE IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS 529 The expression for R1 depends on whether or not t1 as defined by (2) is greater than or less than a (on whether the market is covered, in the sense that all consumers buy one of the n products) or R= Pi f(t)dt t1 > a tj R, = P 2f (t)d t1 < a. a We may now proceed to characterize a non-cooperative price equilibrium (Cournot-Nash equilibrium) in which n firms have a positive market share, being a vector of prices (py,..., p*) such that no one firm k can improve its profit by deviating from pk, the other firms' prices being fixed. The following Lemma characterizes some properties of the market shares of the various firms in equilibrium. LEMMA 1. A necessary condition4for an equilibrium in which goods 1 to n have a positive market share is fb f(t)dt > f (tn) * tn; t 1t PROOF. t k f(t)dt > AO (t tk 1<k<n A necessary condition for profit (revenue) maximization by firm k is: Itk + I R ' Pk+ f (t)dt = :~'f(t)dt + p*f(tk+l)(l - Ck+l) - pkf(tk)ck tk = f (t)dt -f(tk)tk + Pk f(tk+l)(l - Ck+l) + Pk-lf(tk)(l Ck) 0. tkc But Ck, Ck+l>1, hence 5l f(t)dt>f(tk) tk. It is easily verified that this first t I order condition corresponds to a maximum. It is shown in an exactly similar fashion that for k=n, rb f (t)dt > AO )*tn Q. E. D. t n We next demonstrate that if the range of incomes is restricted in an appropriate The revenue function defined here for firm k refers of course to the situation in which the price of k is set at a level such that products k +1 and k-1 remain available, i.e., retain positive market shares. We stress that while this is a necessary condition for equilibrium, a full analysis of Nash equilibrium in the model requires that p4 be shown to be globally optimal.

530 GABSZEWICZ, SHAKED, SUTTON AND THISSE manner, the number of products which retain positive market shares, i.e., 'remain on the market,' at equilibrium, is at most two. This is part of a more general theorem established in Gabszewicz and Thisse [1980]. The intuitive explanation is as follows: if more goods enter, price competition between rival firms forces the prices of competing 'higher quality' goods down to a level at which some 'low quality' products would not be preferred by consumers, even at a price of zero. LEMMA 2. Let b<4a. Then for any equilibrium involving a sequence of n products, labelled in order of decreasing quality n, n-i,..., 1, at most two products (n, n-1) have a positive market share and charge a positive price, whereas the remaining products have a zero market share. PROOF. Applying Lemma I to the density function g(t), we obtain K(b - t) > Ktn, K(t,1 -t- 1) > Kt_1 or b > 2tl, tis > 2tn_ i.e., b > 4tn - II But since by assumption a> b/4, we have a > tn which means that goods n -2, n-3,..., 1 have zero market share. (Of course, if b<2a, the same proof can be adduced to show that only one good has a positive market share). The equilibrium market shares will depend in general both oln the income distribution and the relationship between the quality levels of the different goods. A useful measure of the difference in qualities for two goods 1, 2 is, LEMMA 3. If 2a<b<4a _= C2-1 U1 - Uo C1 U2 -U Q. E. D. and if U1, U2 are such that b - 2a 3a then both products I and 2 have positive market shares, and positive prices, at equilibrium; and t1 <a, so that the market is covered (each consumer buys one or other of the two goods). PROOF. we have Since tl = pici, t2 = P(l - C2) + P2C2 P2C2 = t2 + tla. Rewriting the first order conditions for equilibrium (Lemma 1), for products 1, 2, we have, in terms of a, for product 1: t2 - a =to t2-t1 =t1(1 + a) if t? < a if to ->a

TRADE IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS 531 while for product 2: b -t2 Solving these equations for t1 <a yields = t2 + t1a. Z 1 = 1-b-2a b- 3a +a _t2~ 9 2 = 3 (independently of the qualities of the two goods!) and P1 - b-2a b-a ' P2 3xC1 3C2 Now if 2a < b and a > (b-2a)/(3a) then t 1 < a < t2 and P I > O, P2 > O i.e., both products have positive market shares and prices and the market is covered. If on the other hand we attempt to solve the equations for t? >a we obtain a contradiction, viz., t1 <a. Q. E. D. Remark. While we have chosen a restricted range of a, the first part of the Lemma (that both products enjoy a positive market share and a positive price) remains true for all a. The proof of this is lengthy, however, and is not needed for our present example. 3. THE EFFECTS OF FREE TRADE Suppose we introduce free trade between two economies of the type characterized above. The outcome will clearly depend in general on the relationship between the qualities of the several goods initially available on each market, as well as on the relationship between the pattern of income distribution in each economy. Intuitively, it is clear that if, for example, the 'top' products in each of the two markets were very similar in quality, then competition between these two might drive out the remaining goods, in the manner of Lemma 2 above. In the following Proposition, we consider two economies, each of which satisfies the conditions of Lemmas 2-3, so that it supports two goods initially. Regarding the qualities of the goods, we assume only that they are distinct. We then present a condition on the distributions of income in the two economies -- requiring that they be 'sufficiently similar' - which ensures that at most three goods can survive in the combined economy. PROPOSITION. Given two separate economies in each of which incomes are distributed uniformly over some range [ai, bi], 2ai<bi<4ai, suppose each of these economies initially supports two goods, and that all four goods are distinct. Then if bl> b2, a 1> a2 and b1<2b2 a1<2a2 the combined economy supports at most three goods. Remark. From the above conditions on [ai, bi]

532 GABSZEWICZ, SHAKED, SUTTON AND THISSE a2 < a2 < a, <I < b2 < bl. The pattern of income distribution in the combined economy is shown in Figure I. K +K2 K2 IKK,1( a2 a, b2 b1 FIGURE 1: INCOME DISTRIBUTION IN THE COMBINED MARKET. PROOF. We proceed in stages, showing that the market share of the highest quality good n extends below b1/2 and that of good (n-i) extends below a1, while that of the third good (n -2) extends below a2. (i) t,,<b2 (i.e., the market share of the top quality product extends below b2). If t2? b2, then from Lemma 1, Kjdt > Kjt,, its, i.e., b1-tn>t,, whence (1/2)b1>tn but b2>(1/2)b1 by assumption, so that b2>tn which is a contradiction. Hence t,< b2 (ii) tn<(b1 /2). Suppose first that a1< tn<b2. Then by Lemma 1 5 (KI + K2)dt + Kjdt > (K1 + K2)tn its b2 Hence (b2k2+bk1)/[2(k1+k2)]>t,, but b1>b2, whence tn< b 1/2. If tn<a1, on the other hand, then by our assumption a1<b1/2, we have t,,<b1/2 as required. (iii) tn-1<a. This is obvious if tn<a1. Otherwise we have a1<tn<b1/2. Then, assuming that t_1, a1, we obtain from Lemma I (for k = n - 1) Moreover, from (ii), <on 2 2 4 so that ti- 1 <a1, which is a contradiction. Hence, t,, <a,1. (iv) tn-2<a2. Suppose tn-2>a2. Then, by Lemma 1 for k=n-2, tit - 2 < I tam 1

TRADE IN DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS 533 and from (iii) ~ ~ ~ - X < whence < whence tnl~ - 2 < a2 which is a contradiction. Hence t-2<a2. Q.E.D...D 4. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS We have here described a suggestive example of the manner in which international trade may impinge on a market for differentiated products. The central features of this example are that each consumer chooses (at most) one of a number of competing products of varying 'quality' supplied by rival firms, and that the outcome is characterized as a non-cooperative price equilibrium. We have shown how competition between rival producers can reduce the prices of higher quality goods to the point where some 'lower quality' goods are driven out of the market. The idea here is that, given the price of rival higher quality products, no consumer would prefer the low quality alternatives even at price zero, were they to be on offer. We have illustrated by means of an example how, when separate economies are combined in a common market, the outcome may involve the disappearance of certain goods hitherto produced. It is worth noting that the upper bound to the number of products which can survive in an economy, in the context of a model of this kind, is not associated with fixed costs, or increasing returns to scale, (as in Krugman [1979] for example). Indeed, we have here assumed costs to be zero. Instead, this upper bound follows intrinsically from the combination of our assumptions on consumer preferences, and our characterization of market equilibrium. In particular, this upper bound is independent of the size of the economy (all our equilibrium conditions are unchanged if the parameter K varies). Some special features of the present example which appear not to be fundamental to the result, and which might in principle be relaxed, are that ( i ) a particular 'linear' form of the consumers utility function is used; (ii) the distribution of incomes in each economy is uniform, and consumers are identical in tastes; (iii) the quality of good produced by each firm is given exogenously, rather than chosen in an optimal manner. It should finally be remarked that our analysis is a partial equilibrium one: no account is taken of the impact of consequent changes in output and employment, and so in relative unit costs, in each economy. University Catholique de Louvain, Belgium London School of Economics, England

534 GABSZEWICZ, SHAKED, SUTTON AND THISSE REFERENCES DIXIT, A. K. AND J. E. STIGLITZ, "Monopolistic Competition and Optimum Product Diversity." American Economic Review, 67 (June, 1977), 297-308. JASKOLD GABSZEWICZ, J. AND J. -F. THISSE, "Entry (And Exit) in a Differentiated Industry," Journal of Economic Theory, 22 (April, 1980), 327-338. KRUGMAN, P., "Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade," Journal of International Economics, 9 (November, 1979), 469-479. LANCASTER, K., "Intra-Industry Trade under Perfect Monopolistic Competition," Journal of International Economics, 10 (May, 1980), 151-176. SHAKED, AVNER AND JOHN SuTrON, "The Self-Regulating Profession," Review of Economic Studies, 48 (April, 1981), 217-234.