Chapter 9 Shocks. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 145

Similar documents
Chapter 11 Market-Clearing Models of the Business Cycle 108

Problem 1 / 25 Problem 2 / 20 Problem 3 / 10 Problem 4 / 15 Problem 5 / 30 TOTAL / 100

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 4

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

Chapter 5. Market Equilibrium 5.1 EQUILIBRIUM, EXCESS DEMAND, EXCESS SUPPLY

Demand, Supply, and Price

LECTURE April Tuesday, April 30, 13

MACROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY ANALYSIS

LECTURE NOTES. HCS 112 Fundamentals of economics INTRODUCTION. After completing this part, students should be able to:

Ch. 1 LECTURE NOTES Learning objectives II. Definition of Economics III. The Economic Perspective CONSIDER THIS Free for All?

Cambridge University Press Modeling Monetary Economies, Second Edition - Bruce Champ and Scott Freeman Excerpt More information.

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Module 18 Aggregate Supply: Introduction and Determinants

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

LESSON 9. Economic Fluctuations: Balancing Aggregate Demand and Supply

October 25, Your Name: Midterm Exam Autumn Econ 580 Labor Economics and Industrial Relations

Real Business Cycle Models Chapter 10

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

Practice for Master Class 3 Chapter 5

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Chapter 3. Productivity Output and the Demand and Supply of Labour. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Chapter 17: Labor Markets

More-Advanced Statistical Sampling Concepts for Tests of Controls and Tests of Balances

1 Competitive Equilibrium

ECONOMICS 103. Dr. Emma Hutchinson, Fall 2017

PART ONE. Introduction: Markets and Prices

Topics in Labor Supply

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

Chapter 16 The Labor Market Effects of International Trade and Production Sharing

AGGREGATE DEMAND AND AGGREGATE SUPPLY

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

LECTURE NOTE 2 PREFERENCES

Business Cycle Theory

1 Preliminaries. 1.1 What is Macroeconomics?

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

Stylized Facts about Growth

Copyright 2017 by the UBC Real Estate Division

Lecture 11: Real Business Cycles

Last Name First Name ID#

An equilibrium is an important economic concept. If we are not in equilibrium, we

Managerial Accounting Prof. Dr. Varadraj Bapat Department of School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

Click to return to In this Lesson

Thinking Like an Economist

Microeconomics: MIE1102

ECO 103, Winter 2015, Exam #1. i. Explain all of your answers. Unsupported answers will receive little or no credit.

Managerial Accounting Prof. Dr. Varadraj Bapat Department of School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay

Appendix A. The horizontal axis measures both GDP and Sales. The vertical axis measures the average price level.

Aggregate Demand & Aggregate Supply

Classifying the Effective Factors on Productivity of Human Resources by Using AHP and TOPSIS Methods

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

2014 $1.75 $10.00 $ $1.50 $10.50 $ $1.65 $11.00 $ $2.00 $11.50 $150

LEIBNIZ SHIFTS IN DEMAND AND SUPPLY

LECTURE NOTE 2 UTILITY

Getting ready for the AP Macroeconomics Exam Lesson 2

Topics in Macroeconomics 2 Econ 2004

Macroeconomics II Unemployment

What is Economics? / Define Economics / Introduction to Economics

Solutions. Question 1. Given what we have learned in class, which of the following statements are true and which false? (1 point each 6 points total)

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

The goods market. Screen 1

Introduction to Economics, ECON 100:11 & 13 Economic Growth, Business Cycles, Unemployment, and Inflation. Macroeconomics

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

DOWNLOAD PDF JOB SEARCH IN A DYNAMIC ECONOMY

Keynes' Labor Market: A Reply. By Allan H. Meitzer

AGGREGATE DEMAND CURVE. Dongpeng Liu Department of Economics Nanjing University

Brown University ECON 1130, Intermediate Microeconomics (Mathematical) Spring 2017 Class meets Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30 p.m.

Chapter 1- Introduction

Problem Set #3 Revised: April 2, 2007

Study Guide Final Exam, Microeconomics

Economics 1012A Introduction to Macroeconomics Spring 2006 Dr. R. E. Mueller First Midterm Examination September 28, 2006

Chapter 1: What is Economics? A. Economic questions arise because we face scarcity we all want more than we can get.

Economics 323 Microeconomic Theory Fall 2016

Economics 323 Microeconomic Theory Fall 2016

1 of 14 5/1/2014 4:56 PM

I. Introduction to Markets

REVIEW FOR TEST I (Chapters 1-4 of Case, Fair, Oster text) HCCS Spring Branch Campus Instructor: J.H. Ewing. What Economics is About

1. (40 points, 5 points each) For the following questions, refer to the figure below.

ECON Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model (Part 1)

****** 1. How is the demand for an input dependent upon the demand for an output? 2. Given a wage, how does a firm decide how many people to hire?

Coordination in Economics 1. What & How much to produce? 2. How to

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

Principles of Macroeconomics

Section 1 Guided Reading and Practice: Basic Economic Concepts

Wallingford Public Schools - HIGH SCHOOL COURSE OUTLINE

How the AD/AS Model Incorporates Growth, Unemployment, and Inflation

Chapter 9. The IS LM/AD AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Chapter 14. Chapter Outline

Chapter Outline McGraw Hill Education. All Rights Reserved.

AP Microeconomics Chapter 3 Outline

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Unit 2: Theory of Consumer Behaviour

Government Policy, Efficiency, and Welfare

ECONOMIC ENVIRONMENT LEVEL 1 PAPER 3 STUDY TEXT

Transcription:

Chapter 9 Shocks The demand and supply relationships in the frameworks we have studied have been developed from microeconomic foundations, which, in general, are optimizations of some objective function subject to some constraint function(s). The demand and supply relationships can shift (in price-quantity space) if either or both the objective function and constraint function(s) experience some change. Much of economic analysis concerns the consequences of sudden changes in constraints for example, prices or taxes in consumer analysis. But we can also easily imagine that the objective function of whichever framework we are studying may experience sudden changes. This latter idea is the focus of this chapter in particular, we study here sudden changes in an appropriate utility function if consumer analysis is the focus, and an appropriate profit function if firm analysis is the focus. The reason why an objective function might change (apart from examples provided below) will be studied more deeply soon. From an analytical perspective, though, these changes in foundations lead to precise shifts (that is, a resulting set of changes ) in the accompanying demand and/or supply curves. To introduce formal terminology, the changes that we study here are termed shocks. Heuristically, a shock is an unexplained or unexplainable alteration in some basic element of an economic framework, which in turn causes optimal choices to be affected. If taking a supply-and-demand perspective, these alterations manifest themselves in shifts of supply and/or demand in appropriate markets. On the side of consumer analysis, we can study shocks to the consumption-leisure framework, or shocks to the consumption-savings framework, or shocks to both the consumption-leisure and consumption-savings framework (in which case we are considering the intertemporal consumption-leisure framework). For some parsimony, we consider only the consumption-leisure framework below. Specifically, by varying either the wage or the price of consumption (and holding the other constant), we traced out a single labor supply and consumption demand function. However, much of macroeconomic fluctuations are attributed to shifts, not movements along, the aggregate demand function, which in turn can be attributed to shifts of the consumption demand function. We need to consider now why this function might shift. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 145

The most natural explanation of such shifts is that consumer tastes change over time, perhaps due to evolving cultural norms or society-wide unexpected events. 61 Given our study of consumer theory, we have a ready way of modeling such changes in consumer preferences, namely by supposing that an individual s utility function changes occasionally that is, the utility function is subject to periodic shocks. We will briefly consider one way of introducing this feature into our theoretical model and see that it does indeed induce shifts in the consumption demand function (and thus by extension the aggregate demand function). Production Shocks Just as we extended our frameworks for consumer analysis by augmenting an individual s utility function with unexpected shocks, we can extend our model of firms to suppose that the aggregate production function sometimes also suffers unexpected shocks. 62 The introduction of a shock to the production function has the effect that for any given amount of both capital and labor, total output depends on the level of the shock. Such a shock is most commonly interpreted as a technology shock. The most usual way of introducing production function shocks is to suppose that it simply multiplies the production function. Letting A denote this shock affecting the production function, we would now write the production function as Afkn (,), where A is simply some constant over which a firm has no control but may change over time. It should be clear that if we set A 1 always, then we recover the model we have just discussed. If A rises, then the production function depicted in Figure 31 is modified as in Figure 44. This technology shock to the production function will be important to our later study of real business cycle theory. 61 For example, based on some macroeconomic evidence since the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, one could make the case that, broadly speaking, the average American individual s preferences over consumption and leisure changed at least for a little while, towards valuing leisure more highly. 62 In fact, TFP shocks are a much more common theoretical modeling device than preference shocks. For reasons beyond the scope of this text, however, this approach has failed to capture at a theoretical level some important features of macroeconomic data, especially regarding the behavior of inflation. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 146

Figure 44. An increase (decreased) in A t causes output to increase (decrease) for any given quantity of capital and labor. Preference Shocks Shocks don t occur only on the technology side of the economy; they can also on the utility side of the economy. To illustrate this, recall our usual one-period consumption-leisure model. We now slightly augment the utility function in that framework to be ubcl (, ), (1.1) in which B is some given constant over which the individual has no control. The constant B simply multiplies whatever consumption level the individual chooses in the final determination of utility. For example, the utility function may be ubcl (, ) Bc l. With this formulation, it is clear that our baseline consumptionleisure model simply had B 1 all the time. For any given value of B then (not only B 1 ), the indifference map over consumption and leisure is just as before, as illustrated by the solid indifference curves in Figure 45. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 147

consumption Indifference curves with high value of B Indifference curves with low value of B leisure Figure 45. As B falls, the individual s indifference map steepens because the individual is willing to trade more consumption for leisure. Now suppose all of a sudden B falls due to some unexplained event. The fact that B multiplies consumption in the utility function means that a lower value of B makes the consumption utility component of the utility function stronger for an unchanged level of consumption. For example, if initially B 1 and the consumer were optimally choosing c* 10, the consumption utility component of the above utility function would be 110 10 3.16. If all of a sudden B falls, to B 0.5 say, and the consumer did not change his level of consumption, then his consumption component of utility would be 0.5 10 5 2.23. This means that each unit of consumption is now less valuable in utility terms. 63 Because the individual decides both how much consumption and how much leisure he takes, the fact that consumption is now less valuable in utility terms means that he is willing to give up more units of consumption for a given increase in leisure. Thus the indifference curves of the individual steepen in Figure 45 due to the fall in B. Now let s think about how the individual s optimal consumption choice changes as a result of the fall in B. The situation is presented in Figure 46. With the wage rate W, the price P, and the labor tax rate t all held constant, the new optimal choice features less consumption and more leisure the latter implying that the individual now works fewer hours. 63 More properly speaking, in terms familiar from microeconomics, the fall in B means that the marginal utility of consumption has decreased, and at an unchanged price of consumption the individual will optimally choose less consumption. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 148

consumption 168(1-t)W/P Initial c* New c* Indifference curves with high value of B Indifference curves with low value of B Initia l l* New l* 168 leisure Figure 46. Following a decline in B (with the nominal wage W, the nominal price P, and the tax rate t held constant), the new optimal choice features less consumption and more leisure (and hence fewer hours worked). The change in the optimal choice in Figure 46 occurs with no change in the price P. It should be clear that such a reduction in consumption would occur for any given price P. Thus, for any given price P, optimal consumption is now lower, which is precisely what it means for the consumption demand function to shift inwards, as shown in Figure 47. For convenience, the shift in Figure 47 is shown to be a parallel shift, but in general the nature of the shift will depend on the exact shapes of the initial and new indifference curves. But the general point is that the consumption demand curve shifts (and hence the aggregate demand curve shifts) due to changes in consumer tastes. One further observation follows from this analysis: because the individual chooses to work fewer hours following the fall in B, the entire labor supply curve must shift inwards. 64 Finally, such utility function shocks can also be introduced in the consumption-savings model. An important result of doing so is that such shocks would cause the aggregate 64 Verify for yourself that this is true. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 149

savings function to shift. 65 The analysis of this effect proceeds completely analogously as the above, except we would examine the indifference curves in c 1 c 2 space rather than in c l space. P c(p) under high B c(p) under low B Figure 47. The consumption demand function shifts following the preference shock. c The example we just went through was for the consumption-leisure framework. But this entire preference shock analysis can also be recast in the consumption-savings framework, which is left as an exercise for you to work through. 65 For example, interpreting the events of September 11, 2001 as causing a preference shock to U.S. consumers, we could explain why consumption demand in the present has decreased while savings for the future has increased. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 150