Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1

Similar documents
Testing the long-run relationship between health expenditures and GDP in the presence of structural change: the case of Spain

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

Macroeconomic Modeling and Forecasting

The Crude Oil Price Influence on the Brazilian Industrial Production

Keywords: Devaluation, Money Supply, Co-integration, Error Correction Mechanism JEL Classification: C22, E51

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

Full terms and conditions of use:

Price-Level Convergence: New Evidence from U.S. Cities

Dynamic Linkages among European Carbon Markets: Insights on price transmission

THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN EMPLOYMENT AND REAL EXCHANGE RATE: THE CASE OF TURKISH APPAREL INDUSTRY

Investment in Education and Income Inequality: Testing Inverted U-Shaped Hypothesis for Pakistan

Asian Economic and Financial Review ISSN(e): /ISSN(p): OIL PRICE SHOCKS-MACRO ECONOMY RELATIONSHIP IN TURKEY

LABOUR PRODUCTIVITY, REAL WAGES AND UNEMPLOYMENT: AN APPLICATION OF BOUNDS TEST APPROACH FOR TURKEY

Economic Growth and Electricity Consumption in 12 European Countries: A Causality Analysis Using Panel Data

ECONOMETRIC ANALYSIS OF THE INTERACTION BETWEEN THE EUROPEAN EMISSION TRADING SCHEME AND ENERGY PRICES. Carlo Fezzi

The Relationship between Stock Returns, Crude Oil Prices, Interest Rates, and Output: Evidence from a Developing Economy

Energy-Saving Technological Change and the Great Moderation

Estimation of Short and Long Run Equilibrium Coefficients in Error Correction Model: An Empirical Evidence from Nepal

Higher Education and Economic Development in the Balkan Countries: A Panel Data Analysis

Is Monthly US Natural Gas Consumption Stationary? New Evidence from a GARCH Unit Root Test with Structural Breaks

No Bernd Hayo and Matthias Neuenkirch. Bank of Canada Communication, Media Coverage, and Financial Market Reactions

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) of Australian Dollar: Do Test Procedures Matter?

) ln (GDP t /Hours t ) ln (GDP deflator t ) capacity utilization t ln (Hours t

Euro Area and US Recessions,

Relationship between Overnight Interest Rates in the US and in Turkey: Some Evidence from Symmetric and Asymmetric Granger Causality Tests

Testing for oil saving technological changes in ARDL models of demand for oil in G7 and BRICs

Seasonal Tourism Demand Models from USA to Greece

Financial development and economic growth an empirical analysis for Ireland. Antonios Adamopoulos 1

Energy Consumption and Economic Growth Revisited: a dynamic panel investigation for the OECD countries

What Influences Bitcoin s Price? -A VEC Model Analysis

Factors that affect energy consumption: An empirical study of Liaoning province in China

Temporal Modelling of Producer Price Inflation Rates of Ghana

Research note: The exchange rate, euro switch and tourism revenue in Greece

Keywords: Oil Import, Inflation, Economic Growth JEL: C32, E31, E52. Bilal Kargi, Int.J.Eco. Res., 2014, v5i2, ISSN:

Energy Consumption and Economic Growth: A Panel Data Aproach to OECD Countries

COMUNICACIÓN III ENCUENTRO DE ECONOMÍA APLICADA VALENCIA DE JUNIO DE 2000 TOURISM AS A LONG-RUN ECONOMIC GROWTH FACTOR : THE SPANISH CASE

The Relationship between Oil, Exchange Rates, and Commodity Prices

Cointegration Analysis of the Money Demand in the Euro Area

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol. 8-1 (2008)

Islamic Banking-Growth Nexus: Evidence from Toda- Yamamoto and Bootstrap Granger Causality Test

Hyperbolic Discounting and Consumer Patience During Financial Crises in Korea *

MALAYSIAN BILATERAL TRADE RELATIONS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH 1

Interactions between business conditions, economic growth and crude oil prices

DYNAMICS OF ELECTRICITY DEMAND IN LESOTHO: A KALMAN FILTER APPROACH

FORECASTING THE GROWTH OF IMPORTS IN KENYA USING ECONOMETRIC MODELS

The Performance of Unemployment Rate Predictions in Romania. Strategies to Improve the Forecasts Accuracy

The Dynamics of Relationship between Exports, Import and Economic Growth in India

Functioning and Effectiveness of Monetary Transmission Mechanisms: Turkey Applications

TAMPERE ECONOMIC WORKING PAPERS NET SERIES

Electricity consumption, Peak load and GDP in Saudi Arabia: A time series analysis

Discussion Papers. M3 Money Demand and Excess Liquidity in the Euro Area. Christian Dreger Jürgen Wolters. Berlin, May 2008

Chor Foon Tang * and Hooi Hooi Lean

Department of Economics. issn Discussion paper 15/08

Crude Oil, Palm Oil Stock and Prices: How They Link 1

Asian Economic and Financial Review

The causal relationships between Brent and Urals oil price benchmarks

INTERNATIONAL TRADE, FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH NEXUS IN BANGLADESH: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM TIME SERIES APPROACH

Dynamic effects of Peanut Butter Advertising on Peanut Butter Demand

Assessment Report for the Department of Economics. Program: Bachelor of Economics

A Statistical Analysis on Instability and Seasonal Component in the Price Series of Major Domestic Groundnut Markets in India

Energy consumption, economic growth and CO 2 emissions: Empirical evidence from India

Renewable Energy, Pollutant Emissions and Economic Growth: Evidence from Tunisia

Dynamic Interrelationships between Sea Freight and Shipbuilding Markets

Available online at ScienceDirect. Procedia Economics and Finance 24 ( 2015 )

Validation of a Multiple Linear Regression Model

Archive of SID. The Law of One Price and the Cointegration of Meat Price in the Global Market: the Case of Iran s Market. Abstract

A Methodological Note on a Stochastic Frontier Model for the Analysis of the Effects of Quality of Irrigation Water on Crop Yields

PRICE AND NON-PRICE FACTORS AFFECTING ACREAGE RESPONSE OF WHEAT IN DIFFERENT AGRO-ECOLOGICAL ZONES IN PUNJAB: A CO-INTEGRATION ANALYSIS

Impact of US Crude Oil Inventory on West Texas Intermediate (WTI) Crude. Oil Prices. Using the Structural Dynamic Model

CHAPTER NINE EMPIRJCAL ANALYSIS AND EVALUATION

IETI Transactions on Business and Management Sciences, 2017, Volume 2, Issue 2, An International Open Access Journal

FINANCIAL DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: AN EMPIRICAL RESEARCH ABOUT GREECE -COINTEGRATION TEST. Abstract

The Money Demand Function for Jordan: An Empirical Investigation

Exchange Rates, Foreign Income, and U.S. Agriculture

DOES TRADE OPENNESS FACILITATE ECONOMIC GROWTH: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE FROM AZERBAIJAN

The relationship of energy consumption, economic growth and foreign. direct investment in Shanghai

Financial Development and Economic Growth in Poland in Transition: Causality Analysis *

Cointegration VAR and VECM and ARIMAX Econometric Approaches. for Water Quality Variates

CRUDE OIL PRICE FLUCTUATION AND THE NIGERIAN ECONOMY

Asymmetries in Yield Curves: Some Empirical Evidence from Ghana

Induced Innovation in Canadian Agriculture

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract

How sure are we about the Balassa-Samuelson hypothesis? Time Series versus Panel Data Approach for Asian countries

THE IMPACT OF BANKING SECTOR REFORMS AND CREDIT SUPPLY ON AGRICULTURAL SECTOR: EVIDENCE FROM NIGERIA

Economic Growth and Banking Credit in India

Econometrics 3 (Topics in Time Series Analysis) Spring 2015

COORDINATING DEMAND FORECASTING AND OPERATIONAL DECISION-MAKING WITH ASYMMETRIC COSTS: THE TREND CASE

Forthcoming in Empirical Economics Letters

ARTICLE IN PRESS. Available online at Mathematics and Computers in Simulation xxx (2008) xxx xxx

Sustainability Test of Iran s Agricultural Balance Trade

The Role of Honey Production in Economic Growth: Evidence from a Panel of Major Global Producers

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Issues in Political Economy, Vol 26(2), 2017,

Causality between exports and economic growth: the empirical evidence from Shanghai

University of Macedonia Department of Economics. Discussion Paper Series

Spreadsheets in Education (ejsie)

ANALYSIS OF INTEGRATION BETWEEN QUEENSLAND FEED AND MALTING BARLEY MARKETS

Volume-3, Issue-6, November-2016 ISSN No:

Model Stability Test of Money Demand by Monthly Time Series Using CUSUM and MOSUM Tests: Evidence from Turkey

The return of the Phillips curve and other recent developments in business cycle theory

Transcription:

Submitted on 19/Jan./2011 Article ID: 1923-7529-2011-03-46-06 Claudia Kurz and Jeong-Ryeol Kurz-Kim Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1 Claudia Kurz University of Applied Sciences Mainz Lucy-Hillebrand-Strasse 2, 55128 Mainz, Germany Tel: + 49 6131 6283233 E-mail: claudia.kurz@wiwi.fh-mainz.de Jeong-Ryeol Kurz-Kim (Correspondence author) Deutsche Bundesbank Wilhelm-Epstein-Strasse 14, 60431 Frankfurt am Main, Germany Tel: +49 69 9566 4576 E-mail: jeong-ryeol.kurz-kim@bundesbank.de Abstract: Based on a more realistic assumption, we modify the Taylor regression. The modified Taylor regression gives an explanation of why the (standard) Taylor regression is spurious (in the econometric sense, i.e. no stable relationship among the variables of interest) and, at the same time, a solution as to how central bank monetary policy can still be described by the Taylor rule. An empirical example using euro-area data confirms the compatibility of our modification with empirical data. JEL Classifications: C12, C51, E52, E58 Keywords: Taylor rule, Monetary policy, Inflation, Output gap, Cointegration 1. Introduction The well-known Taylor rule (Taylor, 1993) is given as i t = r * + π t + a(π t π * )+ by t (1) where i t represents the central bank policy rate, r * the equilibrium real interest rate, π t the 12-month inflation rate, π * the inflation target of the central bank, and y t the output gap. According to the Taylor rule, the policy rate of the central bank is decomposed into response to deviations of current inflation from its target rate and response to deviations of the output gap from its target of zero. 2 Taylor (1999) also estimated Equation (1) without arbitrarily setting r * and π * as i t = c + απ t + ßy t + u t (2) where c = r * - aπ *, α = 1+ a, ß= b, and u t is a disturbance. Our following econometric discussion will be based on this regression. One of the most important requirements for econometric analysis of the Taylor regression in (2) is that either all the three involved variables or the disturbance u t must be stationary. The latter means that the three variables must be cointegrated if they are non-stationary. Otherwise, the regression (2) is a spurious one, causing the estimated parameter vector to be inconsistent and t- and F-statistics to diverge (see Phillips, 1986 for a more detailed discussion of this 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the opinions of the Deutsche Bundesbank. 2 Taylor (1993) found that a rule with parameters set arbitrarily to r * = 2, π * = 2, α = 0.5 and ß = 0.5 tracked the actual federal funds rate fairly well between 1987 and 1992. ~ 46 ~

topic). In other words, any economic interpretation of the estimated parameters in the Taylor regression would not be allowed in the case of a spurious regression. The empirical results in the literature regarding the time series properties of the three variables are fairly mixed. Some authors just regard the variables as stationary (Clarida et al., 1998) and others document that, in general, i t and π t are non-stationary, while y t is stationary. Moreover, some authors find no cointegration relationship between the three variables. See Gerlach-Kristen (2003) and Österholm (2006) for a more detailed discussion of this topic and the references therein. In this paper, we introduce a modified version of Taylor regression based on a more realistic assumption described below. The modified Taylor regression provides an explanation of why the (standard) Taylor regression is spurious and, at the same time, a solution as to how central bank monetary policy can still be described by the Taylor rule. In other words, it combines the nonstationarity of the empirical data with the necessity of the existence of a cointegrating relationship for the economic theory. An empirical example using euro-area data demonstrates the compatibility of our modification with the empirical data. 2. The Modified Taylor Regression The basic assumption for an econometric modeling of the Taylor rule is that a central bank monetary policy is based on a double mandate, i.e. it takes into consideration both inflation and economic activity in its monetary policy. This corresponds to the tradition of US monetary policy from which the Taylor rule stems. In the standard formulation of the Taylor rule (at least in the Taylor regression as an econometric model), therefore, it is assumed that the central bank always takes both inflation and economic activity into consideration with one and the same weight. This is not necessarily very realistic at least from the viewpoint of European monetary policy; see footnote 3 for a more detailed comment on this topic and, hence, as will be shown, may cause the spurious problem. Therefore, we modify the standard Taylor regression by the following assumption: Assumption The central bank monetary rates are a function of inflation when the current inflation is higher than the threshold inflation and a function of economic activity, otherwise: This assumption states that the central bank gives an absolute priority to stabilizing inflation and supports economic activity only when the inflation situation allows this. 2 To capture this switching behavior by the central bank in its monetary policy as is assumed above, we incorporate an indicator function into the standard Taylor regression (2) as where is a usual indicator function, and 1, when and 0, otherwise. Because of unobservability of the current inflation rates, we use in the indicator function for our modified Taylor regression. The lower bound in the indicator function,, is probably a slightly higher positive (3) 3 This assumption is consistent with the earlier monetary policy tradition of the Bundesbank, which has been adopted by the European Central Bank. The tradition of the Bundesbank argues that the best and only way to contribute to economic growth is to guarantee price stability. Faust et al. (2001), however, find that, compared with the Bundesbank, the reaction function of the European Central Bank features a higher weight on the output gap relative to the weight on inflation. ~ 47 ~

ISSNs: 1923-7529; 1923-8401 2011 Academic Research Centre of Canada number than the target inflation ( ) and can be defined as a threshold inflation on which possible monetary policy support for economic activity depends. According to this modified formulation of the Taylor regression, the central bank concentrates on the reduction of inflation only when current inflation is higher than threshold inflation and has room for supporting economic activity when current inflation is lower than threshold inflation. From the econometric viewpoint (in the case that i t and π t are non-stationary, whereas y t is stationary), this means that i t and π t will, or rather should be cointegrated when. When, the two variables are not cointegrated, but the nonstationarity of the π t will not pass through into the residual process u t because of the zero weight on inflation by construction. Therefore, the residual process of the Taylor modified regression will be still stationary if the monetary policy behavior of the central bank follows our assumption. In other words, if the assumption for our modification corresponds to the monetary policy behavior of the central bank and the macroeconomic variables included in the Taylor rule are non-stationary, then the standard Taylor regression cannot be cointegrated (although monetary policy is still a function of inflation and the output gap), because it can be cointegrated only with either π t or y t and the non-stationary part will pass through into the residual process. This is an explanation of why the standard Taylor regression is empirically often not cointegrated contrary to the implication of the economic hypothesis about the central bank s behavior in its monetary policy. 3. Empirical Results Figure 1. Empirical data Data: The three variables for the euro area involved in the Taylor regression are three-month money market rates (i t ) as a measure of the central bank monetary rates, the 4 th -difference of the seasonally adjusted harmonized index of consumer prices (π t ) as a measure of the inflation rates and the output gap (y t ) constructed by calculating the percentage deviation of the seasonally adjusted real gross domestic product from its HP trend (Hodrick and Prescott, 1997) using a smoothing parameter λ = 1600. These are quarterly data covering the period from 1980 Q1 to 2007 Q4 (108 observations instead of 112 because of the 4 th - difference for constructing the inflation rates) and taken from the Bundesbank database. Figure 1 shows the ~ 48 ~

three variables, where the interest rates are marked as a dashed line (upper line), the inflation rates as a straight line (middle line) and the output gap as a straight line with a dot (lower line). The straight dotted line on 2.52 is, as will be explained, the estimated threshold inflation rate ( ). Figure 1 contains with respect to our modeling strategy an important piece of visual information: the relationship between the interest rates and the output gap is weak when inflation rates are high and vice versa. Especially in the the first one-third period in which the inflation rates are extremely high, the relationship between interest rates and the output gap seems to be very weak, while, in the other period, in which inflation rates are moderately high or low, the relationship between the two variables seems to become strong. This empirical fact supports the assumption for our modification, namely the central bank s switching behavior in its monetary policy depending on the current inflation rates. Time series property of the data: The ADF (Dickey and Fuller, 1979) test (assuming nonstationarity under the null) on the three variables gives test statistics of -1.85 (AIC=-1.62; lag=4); - 1.72 (AIC=-2.77; lag=9); and -2.70 (AIC=-1.80; lag=1) for i t, π t and y t, respectively. Critical values are -1.95 and -2.60 at the significance levels of 95% and 99%, respectively. The KPSS (Kwiatkowski et al., 1992) test (assuming stationarity under the null) gives test statistics of 1.54 (Bartlett=4.57), 1.29 (Bartlett=3.62) and 0.11 (Bartlett=2.31) for i t, π t and y t, respectively. Critical values are 0.46 and 0.74 at the significance levels of 95% and 99%, respectively. The test results show, in line with many empirical results, that the interest rates and inflation rates can be seen as non-stationary, while the output gap is stationary. Choice for : Before the modified Taylor regression in (3) can be estimated, the threshold must be known. To determine a threshold, the standard likelihood-ratio (LR) technique is usually employed as considered in Tsay (1989). Similarly to the LR technique, we choose as where Π = [x 0.15n:n ; x 0.85n:n ] with x k:n denoting the k-th order statistic from a sample of size n, meaning that 70% of the empirical density around the mean is used for detecting the threshold parameter 4. Moreover, in order to ensure a better fit of the model under the alternative of a threshold effect, we need a sufficient condition for determining the threshold value by the function in (4) as with being an estimated variance under the null. 5 The estimated value of, where (4) 4 Andrews (1993) proposes a sample range of 70% as optimal to control the trade-off between zero power when and, and zero detection of a possible threshold effect when. 5 We perform a simulation study to check how well the detection technique works. For the data generating process, we use two tri-variate triangular cointegrated models (Phillips and Hansen, 1990) with the same residual process as follows: with the same exogenous I(1)-variables for the both models, where, for our purpose (because the output gap is usually stationary variable), we use a stationary process for the second exogenous variable as ; and, where. We set ; c = 0; without loss of generality. Furthermore, we set with ~ 49 ~

ISSNs: 1923-7529; 1923-8401 2011 Academic Research Centre of Canada, which is smaller than. The number of the inflation rates higher than the estimated is 53 from the whole number of 108 observations. The value 2.52 as the estimated threshold ( ) seems to be reliable from the viewpoint of the central bank s empirical behavior. This finding of a threshold inflation supports the view that European monetary policy conforms to our modification of the standard Taylor rule. 6 Estimation and cointegration test: As shown in Figure 1, both the inflation rates and the interest rates have a negative trend for the whole sample period. To take these trends into consideration, we use a linear time trend term for our estimation 7 as τ = 10.7: 0.1 : 0. 8 The estimated model without threshold parameter is given as i t = 0.95 + 0.74τ + 0.61π t + 0.77y t + t (5) (4.38) (20.1) (10.1) (5.68) The ADF test for cointegration (assuming no cointegration under the null) on t in (5) gives a test statistic of -2.24 (critical value -2.76 at 95% and -2.45 at 90% for T = 500; see Phillips and Ouliaris, 1990) and the KPSS test (assuming cointegration under the null) 0.35 (critical value 0.55 at 95% and 0.32 at 90% for T = 500; see Harris and Inder, 1994). To sum up, the results from the tests for integration and cointegration show that two of the three variables are integrated but the relationship is not cointegrated. The estimation using the pre-estimated threshold parameter, =2.52, results in (9.82) (19.1) (11.9) (2.54) The ADF test for cointegration on in (6) gives a test statistic of -2.70 and the KPSS test 0.31. The results of cointegration test in the modified Taylor regression show that both of the tests give higher significance to a cointegrating relationship than that in the standard Taylor regression. Consequently, the relationship among the three variables in the modified Taylor regression can now be seen as cointegrated at the usual significance level, which results from the switching monetary policy behavior of the central bank. (6) 4. Concluding Remarks In this paper, we modified the Taylor regression by a more realistic assumption on the central bank s behavior that the central bank gives an absolute priority to stabilizing inflation and supports economic activity only when the inflation situation allows this. This modified Taylor regression for all i, j =1, 2, 3; and with when i = j and 0, otherwise (the results for other designs of M and Σ are very similar to those presented). The results shows detection rates of 71.97%, 79.80%, 91.71% and 95.74% based on 10,000 replications for T = 50, 100, 250 and 500, respectively. 6 As expected (because of the Feds double mandate), we find no threshold inflation in the US data covering the period from 1960 Q1 to 1999 Q4 used in Ö sterholm (2005). 7 The estimation without the (negative) linear time trend term would give a negative relationship between i t and y t because of the negative trend in it, which stands in contrast to the economic theory. 8 The construction of the trend is arbitrary, but the estimation results are almost the same for other constructions. ~ 50 ~

enables us to give a possible explanation at least for the euro-area data for the alleged conflict between the economic theory (necessity of a stable relationship in the Taylor rule) and the usual empirical results (non-existence of a cointegrating relationship). For further research, the next step would be to model a smooth transition (instead of a threshold transition) by which the central bank takes into consideration both inflation and economic activity simultaneously when current inflation is not very far from the target inflation. Other modifications using non-linear cointegration are possible as well. References [1] Andrews, D.W.K. (1993). Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica, 61: 821 856. [2] Clarida, R., J. Gali and M. Gertler (1998). Monetary policy rules in practice: Some international evidence. European Economic Review, 42: 1033 1067. [3] Dickey, D.A. and W.A. Fuller (1979). Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74: 427 431. [4] Faust, J., J.H. Rogers and J.H. Wright (2001). An Empirical Comparison of Bundesbank and ECB Monetary Policy Rules. FRB International Finance Discussion Paper No. 705 [5] Gerlach-Kristen, P. (2003). Interest rate reaction functions and the Taylor rule in the euro area. European Central Bank, Working Paper 258. [6] Harris, D. and B. Inder (1994). A test of the null hypothesis of cointegration. In: Non-stationary Time Series and Cointegration Analysis. C. Hargreaves (Ed.). Oxford University Press, New York, 133 152. [7] Hodrick, R. and E.C. Prescott (1997). Postwar U.S. Business Cycles: An Empirical Investigation. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 29: 1 16. [8] Kwiatkowski, D., P. C. B. Phillips, P. Schmidt and Y. Shin (1992). Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root. Journal of Econometrics,54: 159 178. [9] Österholm, P. (2005). The Taylor rule: a spurious regression? Bulletin of Economic Research 57: 217 247. [10]Phillips, P.C.B. (1996). Understanding Spurious Regressions in Econometrics. Journal of Econometrics, 33: 311 340. [11]Phillips, P.C.B. and B.E. Hansen (1990). Statistical inference in instrumental variables regression with I(1) Processes. Review of Economic Studies, 57: 99 125. [12]Phillips, P.C.B. and S. Ouliaris (1990). Asymptotic properties of residual based tests for cointegration. Econometrica, 58: 165 193. [13]Taylor, J.B. (1993). Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 39: 195 214. [14]Taylor, J.B. (1999). A historical analysis of monetary policy rules. In: Monetary Policy Rules, Taylor, J. B. (ed.), Chicago: Chicago University Press. [15]Tsay, R. (1989). Testing and modeling threshold autoregressive processes. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 84: 231 240. ~ 51 ~