CPI Antitrust Journal October 2010 (2)

Similar documents
Response to Gopal Das Varma s Market Definition, Upward Pricing Pressure, and the Role of Courts: A Response to Carlton and Israel

Should New Merger Guidelines Give UPP Market Definition?

Unilateral Effects In Horizontal Mergers. Jeffrey Prisbrey Charles River Associates April 28, 2016

CPI Antitrust Chronicle March 2011 (1)

Vertical Restraints and the Effects of Upstream Horizontal Mergers

Pass-Through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers

Merger Simulation in an Administrative Context

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

THE ECONOMICS OF PASS-THROUGH WITH TWO-PART TARIFF PRICING Dov Rothman Analysis Group Working Paper October 2014

Robert Willig Professor Emeritus of Economics and Public Affairs Princeton University Senior Consultant, Compass Lexecon June 19, 2017 Lisbon

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES WHY WE NEED TO MEASURE THE EFFECT OF MERGER POLICY AND HOW TO DO IT. Dennis W. Carlton

Unilateral Effects in Differentiated Product Markets

Antitrust Issues Involving Mergers, Acquisitions & Exclusive Licensing in Pharma and Biotech

Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for Economic Analysis: Interpreting Data Under the Guidance of Economic Theory

cguppi: Scoring Incentives to Engage in Parallel Accommodating Conduct

THE E.C. GREEN PAPER ON VERTICAL RESTRAINTS: OPTION IV DEFENDED. Trinity Economic Paper Series Paper 99/8 JEL Classification: L42

vguppi: SCORING UNILATERAL PRICING INCENTIVES IN VERTICAL MERGERS

First impressions on the Revised US and UK Merger Guidelines

Analysis Group vguppi Online Tool Detailed User Guide. Revised August 13, 2014

Incentive Scoring in Merger Review

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

The B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics

Client Briefing. A matter of definition

An Examination of New Theories on Price Effects of Cross-Market Hospital Mergers

index 527 customer/market sharing 338, 340 1, infra-marginal customers 35 6, 76 7 marginal customers 35, 76 7, 94 5 overlapping customers 184 5

Drawing vertical lines. Bulletin

Merger Analysis and Anti-Trust

MEASURING MARKET POWER IN MULTI-SIDED MARKETS

Roundtable Interview with Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro

CPI Antitrust Chronicle July 2013 (2)

The Analysis of Efficiencies in Horizontal Mergers

The CPI Antitrust Journal July 2010 (2)

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Mergers. Horizontal Merger - this is a merger between two competing companies in the same industry

The antitrust treatment of horizontal

Report on the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry

Post-Merger Product Repositioning

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group

CPI Antitrust Chronicle Dec 2014 (1)

Merger Simulation: A Simplified Approach with New Applications

The Unilateral Conduct Working Group: You Be the Judge Scrutinizing a Loyalty Discount & Rebate Case

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

Mergers, market definition, merger simulation. 220B, spring 2008

Critical Loss vs. Diversion Analysis: Clearing up the Confusion

Cambridge David Newbery Richard Green Karsten Neuhoff Paul Twomey

Managing Your Global Antitrust Risk (and Rewards)

Message from the Chair. Summer 2017 Issue. Message from the Chair David L. Meyer

LESSON FIVE MAINTAINING COMPETITION

Conglomerate and vertical mergers in the light of the Tetra Judgement Götz DRAUZ, Directorate General Competition, Deputy Director-General

Armstrong, Mark, and Robert Porter, Handbook of Industrial Organization, volume 3, Amsterdam: North-Holland, 2007

ABA Brownbag Series Market Definition

SAFE HARBORS FOR QUANTITY DISCOUNTS AND BUNDLING

Private Labels and Relevant Markets

Exam #2 (100 Points Total) Answer Key

Quantitative Methods for Evaluating Unilateral Competitive Effects in Differentiated Products Mergers

TWO-SIDED PLATFORMS AND ANALYSIS OF SINGLE FIRM CONDUCT

Instructions: must Repeat this answer on lines 37, 38 and 39. Questions:

Antitrust law rule. Infineon Technologies AG.

THE HYPOTHETICAL MONOPOLIST TEST IN SYSCO: A LITIGATION MUDDLE NEEDING ANALYTIC CLARITY. Gregory J. Werden

VERTICAL MERGERS: THEORY AND POLICY

Know The Capacity Closure Analysis In Horizontal Mergers

THE COMPETITIVE EFFECTS OF LOYALTY DISCOUNTS IN A MODEL OF COMPETITION IMPLIED BY THE DISCOUNT ATTRIBUTION TEST

Overview of ECO410H and Introduction to Horizontal Merger Assessment ECO410H1F. Organizing Questions for Today. Class 1

CPI Antitrust Chronicle May 2015 (2)

Turning the Coin: A Competition Model to Evaluate Mergers

Question Collection. European Competition Policy Chair of Economic Policy

Collusion and Unilateral Price Announcements. Antonio Capobianco Senior Expert on Competition Law, OECD Competition Division

Complexity in Antitrust: The Accuracy-Simplicity Tradeoff

Lesson-9. Elasticity of Supply and Demand

DOJ/FTC Merger Guidelines and Review Process

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition. 25 November Joseph Farrell and Carl Shapiro * Abstract

Theory of harm in unilateral effects cases in oligopolistic markets

Unless otherwise stated, the questions concern unilateral conduct by a dominant firm or firm with significant market power.

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction:

Does Technology Create Jobs?

UNITED STATES V. H&R BLOCK:AN ILLUSTRATION OF THE DOJ S NEW BUT CONTROVERSIAL APPROACH TO MARKET DEFINITION. Joseph J. Simons & Malcolm B.

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

APPROACHES FOR CUTTING COSTS: A THOUGHT-STARTER

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

REVISITING MARKET DEFINITION AND CONCENTRATION. ONE SIZE DOES NOT FIT ALL

Public Interest Cartels: Sustainability and Collusion

Volume 12 No.1 Fall 2014

Antitrust and Healthcare. Cory A. Talbot (4 15)

The Economics of EC Competition Law: Concepts, Application and Measurement

Welcome to the LIMUN Crisis

Graduate Industrial Organization

Porter and Weller: An Antitrust Odd Couple?

Merger trends in innovation markets. Pablo Ibanez Colomo London School of Economics

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Antitrust Policy in Health Care: Searching for a Strategy That Works Roger Feldman July 16, 2009

Mergers and Acquisitions

What Is Organizational Culture? And Why Should We Care?

Collusion. Sotiris Georganas. February Sotiris Georganas () Collusion February / 31

Market Definition and Market Power in Payment Card Networks

Econ 101, section 3, F06 Schroeter Exam #2, Red. Choose the single best answer for each question.

Trends in Telecommunications: Implications for Regulation

Econ 001 Levinson -- Fall 2009

Transcription:

CPI Antitrust Journal October 2010 (2) WARNING: Improper Use of the New Horizontal Merger Guidelines Can Result in Overly Narrow Markets, Mistaken Inferences of Market Power, and Wrong-Headed Analyses Michael Doane (Competition Economics, LLC), Luke Froeb (Vanderbilt University), & Steven Tschantz (Vanderbilt University) www.competitionpolicyinternational.com Competition Policy International, Inc. 2010 Copying, reprinting, or distributing this article is forbidden by anyone other than the publisher or author.

WARNING: Improper Use of the New Horizontal Merger Guidelines Can Result in Overly Narrow Markets, Mistaken Inferences of Market Power, and Wrong-Headed Analyses Michael Doane, Luke Froeb, & Steven Tschantz 1 I. INTRODUCTION Every first-year law student has heard the story of the man who was mowing his lawn when he realized that his hedge also needed trimming. Since he didn t own a hedge trimmer, he lifted the lawnmower up, turned it on its side, and then accidentally cut off his fingers. He sued the manufacturer, claiming that the label should have warned him not to trim his hedge with a lawnmower. With all of the tools in the new Guidelines natural experiments, merger simulation, market delineation, and Upward Pricing Pressure ( UPP ) to name a few it is easy for an antitrust practitioner to feel a little like the protagonist of this urban legend. We are given a lot of tools, but no warning label on how or when to employ them. Predictably, economists have jumped into this void by coming up with cases or examples of when the tools would give the wrong answer. 2 Most of the criticism is directed against UPP, but the criticism could just as easily be directed against any of the tools mentioned in the guidelines. Some of this criticism is over-stated as there is little in the Guidelines to suggest that the agencies are going to misuse the tools in the way that the critics suppose. But since the new Guidelines are a little short on guidance, and since they did not come with a warning label, we are going to try to clear up some confusion by providing one. WARNING: Improper use of the New Horizontal Merger Guidelines can result in overly narrow markets, mistaken inferences of market power, and wrong-headed analyses. But they can just as easily do the opposite. It depends on how you use them. Incidentally, the same was true of the old Merger Guidelines. 1 Michael Doane is Director, Competition Economics LLC, mdoane@competitioneconomics.com. Luke Froeb is William C. Oehmig Associate Professor in Entrepreneurship and Free Enterprise at the Owen Graduate School of Management at Vanderbilt University, luke.froeb@owen.vanderbilt.edu; he acknowledges useful discussions with Ken Heyer, Dennis Liu, Tim Muris, and Gregory Werden. Steven Tschantz is Associate Professor, Department of Mathematics, Vanderbilt University, tschantz@math.vanderbilt.edu. 2 See the Roundtable Discussion: Merger Guidelines Revisited in Antitrust (Fall 2009) vol. 24(1) pp. 7-21 available at http://www.abanet.org/antitrust/at-mag/toc/09/fall09-tocc.pdf and Panel on the Proposed Revision of the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, Third Annual Research Symposium on Antitrust Economics and Competition Policy ( September 24-25, 2010) Searle Center at Northwestern Law, available at http://www.law.northwestern.edu/searlecenter/uploads/searle_3rd_annual_antitrust_competition_policy_agen da.pdf 2

II. TOOLS ARE USEFUL FOR SOME TASKS, BUT NOT FOR OTHERS The first thing to understand about the tools in the Guidelines is that they are based on economic models. And just as you should not trim your hedge with a lawnmower, so too should you not analyze a merger with a model that misses significant features of competition within the industry. We have said this before, 3 but it is worth repeating. Any model used to predict the effects of a merger must fit the facts of the industry in the sense that the model explains past market outcomes reasonably well. A useful merger model will allow an economist to isolate the factors that determine the extent of competition between the merging firms and to determine how much competition would be lost by merger. Models tell us what matters, why it matters, and how much it matters. III. THERE ARE NO SHORTCUTS Most of the criticism directed towards UPP comes from the belief that the agencies want to use the tool as a shortcut to make it easier to bring merger cases in industries where there are high margins and big diversion ratios. Indeed, when they introduced the tool, Joe Farrell and Carl Shapiro, now chief economists at the FTC and DOJ, almost seemed to suggest as much. 4 But the Guidelines step back from this linkage. They mention UPP as only one of many tools that the agencies will use, and caution that whichever analysis is used, it should fit the evidence. In a more recent article, Professors Farrell and Shapiro would say only that mergers generating positive net upward pricing pressure warrant, at least, further scrutiny. 5 If you want to know when and how the agencies are going to use UPP, you first have to recognize that the tool is built on a model of static price competition between the merging parties. While there is some debate about how well the UPP tool generalizes beyond the Bertrand model, 6 it is clear that before the agencies would apply a tool or a model to help them analyze a merger, they would make sure that it captures the significant features of competition in an industry. If it didn t, then it could give misleading predictions. With all the attention paid to the UPP tool, it is important to understand that the agencies will not view all mergers through the lens of differentiated products price competition. The Guidelines also mention bidding models, bargaining models, and capacity constraints, but the more general point is that their analysis will take account of the significant facts and evidence. So how do you know which facts and evidence are significant? To help answer the question, we put together a simple checklist to document significant departures from standard models of price or quantity competition. In each of the following settings, economists have 3 Greogy J. Werden, Gregory J., Luke M. Froeb, and& David T. Scheffman, A Daubert Discipline for Merger Simulation, 18(3) ANTITRUST, 18:389-95 (Summer, 2004) pp. 89-95.). 4 Joseph Farrell and& Carl Shapiro (2010), Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition,, 10(1) THE B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Vol. 10: Iss. 1. (Policies perspectives), Article 9. (2010). Available at: http://www.bepress.com/bejte/vol10/iss1/art9 5 Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro, Upward Pricing Pressure and Critical Loss Analysis: Response, CPI ANTITRUST CHRONICLE, available at http://faculty.haas.berkeley.edu/shapiro/uppcritical.pdf (February, 2010). 6 Professor Farrell and Shapiro claim that the insights of UPP are broader than the insights that come from a Bertrand model, Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro (2010), Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition,, 10(1) THE B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Vol. 10: Iss. 1. (Policies perspectives), Article 41. (2010). Available at: http://www.bepress.com/bejte/vol10/iss1/art41 3

recognized that simple models (and the tools associated with them) can give misleading merger predictions. a) REPOSITIONING: If firms can change their locations in product space, in addition to price, the merging products will move apart to avoid cannibalizing each other s sales. Since this reduces the incentive to raise price, ignoring such repositioning overstates the effects of a merger. 7 b) CAPACITY CONSTRAINTS: Capacity constraints on the merging firms attenuate merger effects (because a capacity-constrained merged firm has less incentive to raise price) while capacity constraints on the non-merging firms amplify them (because they limit expansion). Since the former effect is typically bigger than the latter, ignoring the effects of capacity constraints likely overstates the effects of a merger. 8 c) VERTICAL RELATIONSHIPS: Downstream price effects of upstream manufacturing mergers are determined, in part, by the nature of the vertical relationship between manufacturers and retailers. 9 Upstream merger effects can be amplified, attenuated, or completely absorbed by the downstream retail sector. d) PROMOTIONAL COMPETITION: Ignoring promotional competition can lead Bertrand models to understate the price effects of merger. 10 Most of the bias can be attributed to estimation bias (estimated demand is too elastic because price reductions are correlated with increases in promotional activity), with the remainder due to extrapolation bias from assuming post-merger promotional activity stays constant (instead it declines). e) SWITCHING COSTS: The presence of switching costs can complicate the analysis of mergers. For price-setting competition, switching costs can lead to an installed base of captive consumers which makes big firms less aggressive competitors than smaller ones. 11 But for auctions, the situation is reversed. 12 Consequently in industries where firms compete on price, mergers that eliminate small competitors can have bigger effects than mergers which eliminate large competitors. And for auctions, the situation is reversed. f) BARGAINING, BIDDING, OR QUANTITY COMPETITION: If firms bargain, bid, set quantity, or choose capacity, merger effects can be significantly different from those in 7 Amit Gandhi, Amit,Luke Froeb, Luke, Steven Tschantz, Steven,& Gregory Werden, Gregory, 2008. Postmerger product repositioning. Journal of Industrial Economics, 56 (1),) J. INDUS. ECON., 49 67. (2008). 8 Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz, & Philip Crooke, Bertrand competition with capacity constraints: mergers among parking lots, 113(1) J. ECONOMETRICS, 49 67 (2003). 9 Daniel P. O'Brien & Greg Shaffer, Bargaining, bundling, and clout: the portfolio effects of horizontal mergers, 36(3) RAND J. ECON., 573 595 (2005); and Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz, & Gregory Werden, Vertical restraints and the effects of upstream horizontal mergers, THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF ANTITRUST, (Vivek Ghosal & Johann Stennek, Eds.) (2007). 10 Steven Tenn, Luke Froeb, & Steven Tschantz, Mergers when firms compete by choosing both price and promotion, 28(6) INT L J. INDUS. ORG., 695-707 (November 2010). 11 J. Farrell, J. and & P. Klemperer, P. 2007. Coordination and lock-in: Competition with switching costs and network effects, in M. Armstrong and R. Porter (eds), HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION, Vol. 3, Elsevier, chapterchapter 31, pp. 1967 2072.. (M. Armstrong & R. Porter, Eds.) (2007). 12 Luke M. Froeb, Mikhael Shor, & Steven T. Tschantz, Mergers in Auctions with an Incumbent Advantage, Vanderbilt Law and Economics Research Paper No. 08 24 (2008), available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1262519. 4

price-setting models. 13 Different kinds of evidence will inform the analysis in each of these cases. To an extent, each new merger presents a unique set of facts. So the list above is necessarily incomplete. However, it is also important to realize that it would be too high a burden for a model to capture all the features of an industry. The art of model building is figuring out which features are significant--and should be included in a model--and which should be left out. You can bypass the ugly art of model building only by rejecting economics. Indeed, models provide the basis for all economic reasoning. IV. CAN WE DO BETTER THAN UPP? Once we have a determined which model is appropriate, most of the heavy lifting is done. At this point, the model will tell us what kinds of evidence to gather, and then how to interpret it. For example, if the static Bertrand model captures the significant forces of competition within an industry, then prices, shares, and elasticities will tell you most of what you want to know. You can get the same information from margins and diversion ratios. But if the Bertrand model captures the significant forces of competition within an industry, a more direct method of determining whether a merger is anticompetitive is available. One can benchmark the parties efficiency claims against what economists call the compensating marginal cost reductions. COMPENSATING MC REDUCTIONS (CMCR s) are the reduction in marginal costs necessary to offset the incentive of the merged firm to raise price. The advantage of this tool over UPP is that it gives us a way to balance the costs of a merger against its benefits, i.e., the merger synergies. If the reductions in marginal costs are bigger than the compensating MC reductions, then the merged firm has no incentive to unilaterally raise price. Because they are both related to the same Bertrand model, the compensating MC reductions are closely related to UPP. To see this, imagine two merging products (1 and 2), and let and be the reductions in marginal cost on each of the merging products that offset the incentive of the merged firm (1+2) to raise price. It can be shown that the UPP taxes, are related to the compensating marginal cost reductions 14 as follows: 13 Gregory Werden & Luke Froeb, Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers II: Auctions and Bargaining, ISSUES IN COMPETITION LAW AND POLICY, ABA SECTION OF ANTITRUST LAW, Vol. 2, 1343, (W. Dale Collins (Ed.) (2008), available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=956400; Gregory J. Werden & Luke M. Froeb, Unilateral Competitive Effects of Horizontal Mergers, HANDBOOK OF ANTITRUST ECONOMICS, 43-104 (Paolo Buccirossi, Ed.), ( 2007), available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=927913; Weyl, Glen (2010a), Pass-Through and Merger Analysis, Harvard University, available from the author upon request, quoted in Joseph Farrell & Carl Shapiro (2010), Antitrust Evaluation of Horizontal Mergers: An Economic Alternative to Market Definition,, 10(1) THE B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics: Vol. 10: Iss. 1. (Policies perspectives), Article 41. (2010). Available at: http://www.bepress.com/bejte/vol10/iss1/art41 14 Froeb, Luke, Steven Tschantz, and Gregory Werden, Compensating Marginal Cost Reductions vs. UPP. Manuscript (2010). 5

where is the UPP on product 1 and where is the diversion ratio from product 1 to product 2; and similarly for the UPP on product 2. So both UPP and compensating MC reductions can be constructed from the same data, and both share the advantage that neither requires information about the curvature of demand. 15 The advantage of UPP over the compensating MC reductions is that the UPP taxes can be computed separately for each product, while the compensating MC reductions have to be computed jointly. But as the formulas above show, once you have both UPP s, you can easily compute both compensating MC reductions. We prefer the compensating MC reductions because, as mentioned above, they give the agencies an explicit way to balance the costs of a merger against its benefits, i.e., the merger synergies. The methodology can also be used for different models of competition, though the formulas differ, according to the underlying model. Compensating marginal costs reductions were introduced for Bertrand models by Werden, 16 and have since been applied to models of quantity competition, 17 to auctions, 18 and to models of price and promotional competition. 19 In each of these situations there is a version of UPP 20 that can be derived, but again, it is hard to interpret. V. CONCLUSION: THERE IS NOTHING NEW UNDER THE SUN We had expected the new Merger Guidelines to speed the natural evolution of merger practice away from inference based on shares in a delineated market towards direct measurement of competitive effects. But they didn t do that. The new Guidelines did not put competitive effects first. They did not bypass market delineation, although they mention the possibility. And they did not say that high margins and big diversion ratios would lead a presumption against the merger. Taken as a whole, they exhibit much of the same tension between an approach based on shares and concentration and one based on competitive effects as did the old Merger Guidelines. So while the words of the Guidelines have changed, we are led to conclude that the substance remains the same. The agencies will continue using economic models, either formally 15 Crooke, Philip, Luke Froeb, Steven Tschantz, and Gregory Werden The Effects of Assumed Demand Form on Simulated Post-Merger Equilibria, Review of Industrial Organization, 15(3), (November, 1999) pp. 205-217. 16 G. J. Werden, A robust test for consumer welfare enhancing mergers among sellers of differentiated products, 44 J. INDUS. ECON. 409 413 (1996). 17 Luke M. Froeb & Gregory J. Werden, A Robust Test for Consumer Welfare Enhancing Mergers Among Sellers of a Homogeneous Product, 58 ECON. LETTERS, 267-269 (1998); and Maarten Pieter Schinkel, Marie Goppelsroeder, & Jan Tuinstra, Quantifying the Scope for Efficiency Defense in Merger Control: The Werden-Froeb-Index, LVI (4) J. INDUS. ECON. VOL. 778-808 (2008); Amsterdam Center for Law & Economics Working Paper No. 2006-10, available at SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=916556. 18 Lance Brannman & Luke Froeb, Mergers, Cartels, Set-Asides and Bidding Preferences in Asymmetric Second-price Auctions, 82(2) REV. ECON. & STATISTICS, 283-290 (2000); and Steven Tschantz, Philip Crooke, & Luke Froeb, Mergers in Sealed vs. Oral Auctions, 7(2) INT L. J. ECON. OF BUSINESS, 201-213 (July, 2000). 19 Steven Tenn, Luke Froeb, & Steven Tschantz, Mergers when firms compete by choosing both price and promotion, 28(6) INT L J. INDUS. ORG. 695-707 (November 2010). 20 Moresi, Serge, Bidding Competition and the UPP Test, HMG Review Project Comment, Project No. P092900, available at http://www.ftc.gov/os/comments/horizontalmergerguides/545095-00040.pdf. 6

or informally, to first determine how firms compete, and then to predict how merger is likely to change competition. And they will keep delineating markets and computing shares. If you want a better idea of what that looks like in a practice, consult the enforcement statistics 21 and re-read the under-appreciated Commentary on the Merger Guidelines. 22 And don t forget the warning that is in the title of the paper. That hasn t changed either. 21 FTC Enforcement Database, available at http://www.ftc.gov/bc/caselist/index.shtml. 22 Commentary on the Horizontal Merger Guidelines, (March, 2006) available at http://www.justice.gov/atr/public/guidelines/215247.htm. 7