Consultation response: Cost of Energy Review

Similar documents
The Commission's Energy Roadmap 2050

Climate change and EU policy -

Prof. John Fitzgerald. The Citizens Assembly

European Power sector s perspective on the role of the EU ETS

Investing under regulatory uncertainty

1. EXECUTIVE SUMMARY AND KEY RECOMMENDATIONS

About Energy UK. Introduction

EVA grossly miscalculates Wind s Capacity Factor:

8. Confusion About Renewable Energy. Gail Tverberg Energy Economics and Analysis Modeling

PAGE 38 THOMAS KUSTERER THE GERMAN ENERGY TRANSITION

White Rose CCS Project

Energy policy at the crossroads. Finding the road to a competitive, low carbon and energy efficient Europe

Lessons from UK energy policy & Energy Market Reform

Status and Challenges of the German Energiewende

Lessons to be learnt from the German Renewables Experience

Efficient regime for the expansion of renewable energies, further development of the energy-only market and preservation of EU-ETS

Methodology for calculating subsidies to renewables

Wind Energy in Canada

The EU energy targets leading to 2050, the transition to a low-carbon economy and the role of energy regulation

National Energy Outlook Summary

GHG emissions per capita. (tco 2. e/cap) Source: UNDP, data for 2015 Source: World Bank Indicators, data for 2012 Source: IEA, data for 2013

Sustainable Energy Roadmap & Implementation Plan (SERIP) Alexander Ochs Senior Director of Climate and Energy

A Brief Introduction to the Economics of Climate Change

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy

Analysis of What Goes Up Ontario s Soaring Electricity Prices and How to Get Them Down. CanWEA

Nuclear-renewable hybrid energy systems for non-electric applications

GHG emissions per capita. (tco 2. e/cap) Source: UNDP, data for 2015 Source: World Bank Indicators, data for 2012 Source: IEA, data for 2013

Consultation response: Building a market for energy efficiency. Samuela Bassi and Daire McCoy

Improving the way we price our network services. Consultation paper

Climate Change Position Statement and 2020 Action Plan

WIND POWER TARGETS FOR EUROPE: 75,000 MW by 2010

Renewable energy in Europe. E-turn 21 workshop Cologne, 10 May 2006

Cost of Service and Public Policy. Ted Kury Director of Energy Studies, PURC

Some highlights of the Victoria study include: A large untapped resource: The modelling results show strong growth in

Proposal of draft summary & conclusions

The value of local electricity storage in a smart grid: How important is intermittency?

Power Perspectives 2030

The year ahead in energy Some potential issues, uncertainties and priorities for the Australian National Electricity Market

Client Briefing. A matter of definition

Flexible energy for efficient and cost effective integration of renewables in power systems

TODAY S ORGANIZED MARKETS A STEP TOWARD COMPETITION OR AN EXERCISE IN RE-REGULATION?

Setting the Energy Bid Floor

Electricity Markets. Rapid Conference May 17, Mike Rencheck Rencheck Consulting LLC

Jordan Assessment Report

Policy Instruments for Renewable Energy: An Introduction

ENERGY MARKET REFORM IN WA A PROGRESS REPORT

GHG emissions per capita. (tco 2. e/cap) Source: UNDP, data for 2015 Source: World Bank Indicators, data for 2012 Source: IEA, data for 2013

Electricity Network Economic Regulatory Framework Review. Response to the AEMC Approach Paper

CONTENTS TABLE OF PART A GLOBAL ENERGY TRENDS PART B SPECIAL FOCUS ON RENEWABLE ENERGY OECD/IEA, 2016 ANNEXES

Low-Carbon Jobs in an Inter-Connected World

How achievable are the UK s 2020 renewable energy targets?

Indonesia's Energy Transit: Struggle to Realize Renewable Potential

29/07/2015. Rintaro Tamaki Deputy Secretary-General, OECD. ISAP July Agenda CONTEXT KEY MESSAGES CONCLUSIONS AND NEXT STEPS

G7 Kitakyushu Energy Ministerial Meeting Kitakyushu Initiative on Energy Security for Global Growth Joint Statement

IBERDROLA 27/07/2016 IBERDROLA S SUBMISSION ON THE ROAD MAP FOR GLOBAL CLIMATE ACTION

JLL Energy & Infrastructure Advisory. Corporate PPAs: The Devil s In The Detail

UK Electricity Market Reform: Lessons from a policy and regulatory journey

Royal Society response to Defra review of the UK Climate Change Programme

CEOs OF LEADING EUROPEAN ENERGY COMPANIES CONTRIBUTION TO THE EUROPEAN COUNCIL, MARCH 2014

UK Electricity Market Reform: Lessons from a policy and regulatory journey

Climate Change and Energy Sector Transformation: Implications for Asia-Pacific Including Japan

SUSTAINABLE USE OF OCEANS IN THE CONTEXT OF THE GREEN ECONOMY AND THE ERADICATION OF POVERTY, PRINCIPALITY OF MONACO, NOVEMBER, 2011

THE GLOBAL COMMISSION ON THE ECONOMY AND CLIMATE

GHG emissions per capita. Share of global GHG emissions. e/cap) (tco

Energy Transition and Renewable Energy in Korea

Quantifying the capital requirement: 19% RE by 2030

CCS - Commercially Viable but a Political Priority?

Does the EU renewable energy sector still need a guarantees of origin market?

Nuclear Power Economics and Preservation. Presentation Prepared for NARUC Subcommittee on Accounting and Finance Michael Purdie March 29, 2017

Wind Power in Denmark. Steffen Nielsen Head of Section Danish Energy Authority Ministry of Climate and Energy

Coal After the Paris Agreement

Wind Power in Context A clean Revolution in the Energy Sector

Internationalization and Export Promotion Programs: Perspectives and Challenges. Growth of Exporting

Market Responsive Pricing Policy Mechanism Brief

with Fatih Birol, IEA Executive Director

Nuclear Energy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Avoidance in the EU

Perverse Incentives and Outcomes. George Smith, FRS, Emeritus Professor of Materials, Trinity College, Oxford

Energy Efficiency and Renewables: Conflicting Targets?

Country profile: Austria

Boundary Dam - Cash & Carbon flows. Abstract, Recommendations & Executive Summary.

An independent assessment of the Clean Growth Strategy

How to secure Europe s competitiveness in terms of energy and raw materials? The answer, my friend, is blowing in the wind

COST Action ES1002 WIRE WEATHER INTELLIGENCE FOR RENEWABLE ENERGIES

Europe s Coming Challenges in Meeting Decarbonisation Objectives

GE OIL & GAS ANNUAL MEETING 2016 Florence, Italy, 1-2 February

Madrid 23. July of course. Industry, They also. new challenges. energy in. Spain lies in. connecting

Energy Efficiency and Climate Change Policies & Actions in the EU. RIETI, 7April 2010

Consultation on an EU strategy for liquefied natural gas and gas storage

An independent assessment of the Clean Growth Strategy

Zero Net Carbon Portfolio Analysis

How can the next Chief Executive build on Government s Climate Action Plan and encourage renewable energy uptake?

We appreciate your feedback

WAKING UP TO AMERICA S ENERGY FUTURE

Climate change policies and the UK business sector: overview, impacts and suggestions for reform. Policy paper

Danish Energy and Climate 2015

AFFORDABLE AND CLEAN ENERGY

RENEWABLE POWER GENERATION COSTS IN 2014

Renewable Portfolio Standards

World Energy Scenarios 2016

The Role of Microgrids in Grid Modernization Initiatives Sima Seidi Principal Consultant, Microgrids and Distributed Energy Resources Tetra Tech

Transcription:

Consultation response: Cost of Energy Review Bob Ward and Sini Matikainen January 2018

The Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy (CCCEP) was established in 2008 to advance public and private action on climate change through rigorous, innovative research. The Centre is hosted jointly by the University of Leeds and the London School of Economics and Political Science. It is funded by the UK Economic and Social Research Council. More information about the ESRC Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy can be found at: www.cccep.ac.uk The Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment was established in 2008 at the London School of Economics and Political Science. The Institute brings together international expertise on economics, as well as finance, geography, the environment, international development and political economy to establish a world-leading centre for policy-relevant research, teaching and training in climate change and the environment. It is funded by the Grantham Foundation for the Protection of the Environment, which also funds the Grantham Institute for Climate Change at Imperial College London. More information about the Grantham Research Institute can be found at: www.lse.ac.uk/grantham This paper is intended to inform decision-makers in the public, private and third sectors. The views expressed represent those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the host institutions or funders.

Consultation response: Cost of Energy Review This is a submission by the ESRC Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy and the Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment at the London School of Economics and Political Science to the consultation on the independent Cost of Energy Review by Professor Dieter Helm, which was published on 25 October 2017. The UK Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy initiated a call for evidence in November 2017, seeking views on the matters that the Government should take into account in considering how to reduce the cost of energy in the longer term. Our responses to certain areas of the Review are set out below. The author s approach to the Review The Cost of Energy Review by Professor Dieter Helm represents a personal manifesto for the UK power sector, rather than a synthesis of the best expert analysis. The author is transparent about this, stating in the Preface and Acknowledgements that: The review is not, and was never intended to be, a comprehensive summary of the views of the experts, professionals, energy businesses, customers, and the many vested interests that have grown up around the electricity industry. As such, the analysis has many strengths, but also suffers from some significant weaknesses that may have been addressed by the author if he had consulted other experts in the field. Some of the major conclusions and recommendations should not be a surprise to the Government as they are drawn from the author s previous pronouncements about the energy sector. The phase-out of coal from electricity generation The Helm Review criticises the size of the expenditure to date on subsidies for the deployment of immature renewable technologies. However, it does not offer any alternative mechanisms that potentially would have been more cost-effective. His argument that decarbonisation of the power sector should have focused on phasing out coal for natural gas does not address the issue of how deployment of renewables should have been managed. Indeed a focus on the transition from coal to gas might have meant that a much smaller proportion of electricity would be generated by renewables today. The observation that the cost of renewables has dropped is, puzzlingly, presented by the Helm Review as a criticism of earlier investments, which he labels legacy costs. He does not explain how the costs would have dropped without the initial investments. On an output basis, the percentage of total electricity generated by coal fell from 22.4 per cent in 2015 to 9.0 per cent in 2016. This compares with 39.2 per cent in 2012. Although the proportion of electricity generated by renewables rose from 8.1 per cent in 2012 to 25.7 per cent in 2016, the share from natural gas increased from 27.5 to 42.2 per cent over the same period. The latest projections published by the Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy (2018) show, in the reference scenario, that coal will be phased out completely by 2025 and the proportion of total UK electricity supply annually from natural gas is due to decrease from 47.4 per cent in 2017 to 27.2 per cent in 2025 and 15.2 per cent in 2035. Hence, coal will have been phased out using natural gas as a bridge to a low-carbon power sector dominated by nuclear and renewables. The costs of renewable electricity generation The Helm Review is correct in identifying a mismatch between the market failures that hinder new low-carbon alternatives to fossil fuels, and the implementation of the subsidies that are intended to help overcome them. Most renewable technologies are capital-intensive: most of the costs are incurred during the construction of the wind turbines or solar panels, while the ongoing operating 1

and maintenance costs are relatively low. The subsidies are not paid upfront, but are promised as a revenue stream in return for electricity generation over an extended period. The Helm Review suggests that a more efficacious approach would be to offer capital grants and special tax regimes for capital expenditure. It suggests that after the existing contracts for lowcarbon electricity generation have been honoured, feed-in tariffs and low-carbon Contracts for Difference should be restructured according to their three phases (the construction and projectdevelopment phase, the operation of the plant, and decommissioning), with capital support and tax concessions for the project development and construction phases. The Helm Review suggests a refinancing arrangement would be put in place after the completion of a project so that customers can benefit from the relatively low marginal cost of electricity generation from renewables. Such an arrangement makes some sense, because separating out the fixed costs of project development from the relatively low marginal costs associated with renewable energy production could offer some benefits for electricity consumers if their bills did not include subsidies to cover the capital costs. However, the wholesale price of electricity, which is a major determinant of the price that consumers pay, currently depends on fossil fuels, which create a higher marginal cost for electricity generation. It is unclear, therefore, that changing the pricing structure for renewables only will result in significant benefits for consumers, particularly given how quickly the levels of subsidies for renewables are falling. The results of the second auction of Contracts for Difference revealed a strike price for offshore wind of 57.50/MWh (in 2012 prices) for delivery in 2022 23, compared with 119.89/MWh hour (in 2012 prices) for delivery in 2017 18 through the first auction. Renewables are quickly approaching the point at which they will not need subsidies, particularly if fossil fuels are subject to a strong carbon price. If consumers are to benefit from the low operating costs of renewables, the Government will need to reform the electricity market so that the wholesale price is not dependent on the marginal costs of fossil fuels. Addressing the intermittency of renewable electricity generation The Helm Review recommends that renewable electricity generators should eventually be made responsible for managing the costs of intermittent output, an idea that the author has proposed many times before (e.g. Helm, 2015). This would be the result of combining the auctions for lowcarbon deployment with those for capacity, to create a single equivalent firm power capacity auction. To do so would require, for instance, the owners of offshore wind farms to enter into arrangements to provide power to the network from alternative sources at times when wind speeds are too low to do so. However, this would likely create unnecessary additional costs, as balancing costs arise at a system level rather than for individual wind farms. Nonetheless, renewables with variable electricity generation output, such as wind and solar, do create further system costs. The size of such costs is context-specific, depending on climatic factors, demand profiles and the wider mix of generation. A systematic review undertaken by the UK Energy Research Centre (Heponstall et al., 2017) found that, in UK conditions, these costs would be of the order of 10 per megawatt-hour of intermittent renewable output if 30 per cent of electricity were supplied by variable renewables. About 14 per cent of electricity in the UK was generated by variable renewables in 2016. Costs rise at higher penetrations and are significantly larger if the system is inflexible. At present these costs are socialised and not directly borne by renewables generators. In future, it is possible that at least some of these costs could be reflected in the network charges faced by variable renewable generators. This would improve cost-effectiveness much more efficiently than requiring individual wind or solar farms to balance their output. 2

Carbon pricing The Helm Review is correct to recommend that a uniform, economy-wide carbon price would be more efficient and should be the aim of future UK government policy. Inconsistent implicit and explicit carbon prices across the UK economy and between different types of user are an economically inefficient way of reducing emissions of greenhouse gases as they do not focus abatement on the most cost-effective options. The Helm Review proposes a border carbon tax to protect UK firms against the economic impact of a higher domestic carbon price. This is something that the author has advocated for some time (Helm et al., 2012). However, the Helm Review s promotion of high-carbon protectionism is inconsistent with the narrative of low-carbon prosperity contained, for instance, in the Government s Clean Growth Strategy. The UK has very big growth opportunities in low-carbon trade. The global demand for low-carbon goods and services could rise by a factor of ten between now and 2030, according to an analysis by Ricardo AEA (2017) for the Committee on Climate Change. Exploiting these opportunities would be much more rewarding than starting a trade war over the UK s remaining high-carbon industries, important though they are. Moreover, the threat from carbon policies to UK competitiveness is declining. The Helm Review is wrong to claim that the UK s carbon targets are unilateral. It is true that they are anchored in UK law and therefore not affected by the UK s departure from the European Union. But the UK is not acting alone. There are about 1,400 climate change laws and related policies worldwide (Nachmany et al., 2017) and, putting aside recent changes in policy in the United States, almost every country has signed up to the Paris Agreement. The stronger the carbon policies in these countries, the lower will be the competitiveness impacts of the UK s domestic targets. Competitiveness concerns are further lessened by the fact that low-carbon electricity is becoming cheaper. References Department for Business, Energy & Industrial Strategy [BEIS] (2018) Updated Energy and Emissions Projections. London: BEIS. Available at: https://www.gov.uk/government/publications/updatedenergy-andemissions-projections-2017 Helm D, Hepburn C, Ruta G (2012) Trade, climate change, and the political game theory of border carbon adjustments. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 28: 368-394. Available at: https://academic.oup.com/oxrep/article/28/2/368/460923 Helm D (2015) The first 100 days of Conservative energy policy. Available at: http://www.dieterhelm.co.uk/energy/energy/stranded-assets-a-deceptively-simple-and-flawed-idea- 2/ Helm D (2017) Cost of Energy Review. London: BEIS. Available at: https://www.gov.uk/government/uploads/ system/uploads/attachment_data/file/654902/cost_of_energy_review.pdf Heponstall P, Gross R, Steiner F (2017) The costs and impacts of intermittency 2016 update. London: UK Energy Research Centre. Available at: http://www.ukerc.ac.uk/asset/1f122957-0444-4ca3- BD72B195B3EFED16/ Nachmany M, Fankhauser S, Setzer J, Averchenkova A (2017) Global trends in climate change legislation and litigation: 2017 snapshot. Policy brief. London: Grantham Research institute on Climate Change and the Environment and ESRC Centre for Climate Change Economics and Policy. Available at: http://www.lse.ac.uk/granthaminstitute/ publication/global-trends-in-climate-change-legislation-and-litigation-2017-snapshot/ Ricardo AEA (2017) UK business opportunities of moving to a low carbon economy. London: Committee on Climate Change. Available at: https://www.theccc.org.uk/publication/uk-energy-prices-and-bills- 2017-report-supporting-research/ 3