Some Simple Economics of Climate Change

Similar documents
Uncertainty, Ethics, and the Economics of Climate Change

US climate change impacts from the PAGE2002 integrated assessment model used in the Stern report

The Challenge of Global Warming

The Economics of Climate Change C 175. Learning. Spring 09 UC Berkeley Traeger 5 Risk and Uncertainty 39

WWF IPCC WG3 Key Findings

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University

GCAM Modeling of Bioenergy and Carbon Emissions from Land Use Change

TAXES, TARGETS, AND THE SOCIAL COST OF CARBON

Explaining and Understanding Declines in U.S. CO 2 Emissions

Pacing the rollout of renewable energy in the face of climate change risk

The Economics of Climate Change

TECHNICAL ANNEX. Uncertainty in the Determination of Public Policies to Fight Climate Change

SUSTAINABLE URBAN TRANSPORTATION - SUTRA D08/B: ECONOMIC ASSESSMENT

SOCIETAL RISK AVERSION AND THE GOVERNMENT SUPPORT OF GEOENGINEERING. 1. Introduction

Climate Change: Economics and Policy

The Marshall Institute has addressed several issues identified by the Review as pertinent to its analysis.

GEOENGINEERING FOR DECISION MAKERS. Bob Olson Senior Fellow Institute for Alternative Futures

STERN CRITIQUE: THE CLIMATE CHANGE DEBATE IS FAR FROM OVER

Stop and Switch Suicidal Subsidies and The Climate Solution

The Economics of Climate Change. Temperature anomaly

Combining price and quantity controls to mitigate global climate change

- A person who directs resources to achieve a stated goal. - The science of making decisions in the presence of scarce resources.

Session 31, Statistical Techniques for Fund Mapping and Other Applications. Moderator: Douglas L. Robbins, FSA, MAAA. Presenter:

Consequences of climate change impacts for economic growth: a dynamic quantitative assessment Presentation

UNCERTAINTY, EXTREME OUTCOMES, AND CLIMATE CHANGE POLICY

What does IPCC AR5 say? IPCC as a radical inside the closet

In mid-february President Bush unveiled his administration s climate-change policy

AGEC 604 Natural Resource Economics

Lecture 7 - Food Stamps: The Whitmore Study

Science and Decision-Making: the Role of IPCC Assessments insights on Rio +20

Energy Resources Status Check

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

Risk awareness in conducting business. Why is it worth to implement risk management progamme? - Marcin Marczewski, Konrad Roziewski - SASMA TEAM

Introduction to Baseline Setting: Why, What and How?

Chapter Six{ TC "Chapter Six" \l 1 } System Simulation

It is a unique privilege for me to speak before this august gathering at time when

A Guide to. Cogeneration. Plant Solutions. Plant Solutions A Guide to Cogeneration

10 Energy consumption of buildings direct impacts of a warming climate and rebound effects

Are Renewable Portfolio Standards Effective to Reduce CO 2 Emissions?

Montreal v. Kyoto. Scott Barrett Columbia University

Accelerating the energy transition: cost or opportunity? A thought starter for the Netherlands

Getting in touch with reality

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES ESTIMATES OF THE SOCIAL COST OF CARBON: BACKGROUND AND RESULTS FROM THE RICE-2011 MODEL. William D.

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

AVIATION IS THE KEY TO REDUCING CLIMATE EMISSIONS

Analyze different types of non zero sum games. Hawk vs. Dove game. Advertising problem. Problem of companies polluting the environment.

Scenario analysis: what is it and how can it help business deal with climate risk?

Economic models of climate change

The Social and Behavioural Aspects of Climate Change

Chapter 6 How do we set the reference levels for REDD payments?

WAVES, Natural Capital Accounting Highlighted at Trondheim Conference on Biodiversity

CLIMATE CHANGE, DEVELOPMENT, POVERTY AND ECONOMICS

Climate Change: The 5th IPCC assessment report (AR5)

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

Environmental management: challenges and opportunities for the resource sector in PNG

TIMEBOXING PLANNING: BUFFERED MOSCOW RULES

Climate Goals and CCS

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

Why Increase Electricity Prices?

Royal Society response to Defra review of the UK Climate Change Programme

GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: STRATEGIC INTERACTIONS OR UNILATERAL GAINS?

Review of the «Global and Russian energy outlook up to 2040»

The Basics of Supply and Demand

Preparing for the Midterm Review of the Fuel Economy and Greenhouse Gas Emissions Rate Standards for Light-Duty Vehicles

CMA Students Newsletter(For Foundation Students)

Chapter 6. Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost

THE ECONOMICS OF THE ENVIRONMENT Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

GUEST ESSAY The Scientific Consensus About Global Warming John Harte

The Lazy Man s Guide to 80 x 50 in NYC Laurie Kerr, FAIA, LEED AP Urban Green Council, Policy Director

The Effect of CO2 Emissions Reduction on the U.S. Electricity Sector

Cyber Security and the Probability Challenge

Incorporating Social Justice in Climate Change Solutions. Dr. Christie Klimas

-SUBMISSION BY MEXICO REDUCING GREENHOUSE GAS EMISSIONS FROM DEFORESTATION IN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Part II: Economic Growth. Part I: LRAS

Proactive Listening: Taking Action to Meet Customer Expectations

Analysis conducted by Pedro Piris-Cabezas, Ruben Lubowski and Gabriela Leslie of the Environmental Defense Fund (EDF)*

Tuesday Dec 2nd TOPIC # 13 Global Warming Wrap Up TOPIC #14 IMPACTS & ISSUES

2010 Pearson Education Canada

Where is moving the electricity sector and how are Electric. Industry Investment Decisions Influenced by Potential

Evaluations on the emission reduction efforts of Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) in cost metrics

Climate Policy in the Post-Kyoto World. Incentives, Institutions and Equity

Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets

The Pause in Global Warming: Climate Policy Implications. Ross McKitrick Professor of Economics University of Guelph

The Basics of Supply and Demand

Strategies to Prevent Global Warming After the Effectuation of the Kyoto Protocol

Techno-Economic Modelling of Energy Systems: Possible CEEM contributions

Energy Economics. Overview of EMF 22 U.S. transition scenarios

How things work college course/cumulative global warming exam/testbank

AmCham EU Position on Shale Gas Development in the EU

Hi, I'm Derek Baker, the Executive Editor of the ibm.com home. page, and I'm here today to talk with Dan Pelino, who Is IBM's General Manager for

Uncertainty Analysis and Impact Assessment

Thursday, October 13: Short and Long Run Equilibria

The Economics of Climate Change Nicholas Stern. Second IG Patel lecture New Delhi 26 October 2007

The costs and benefits of benefit-cost analysis

The PSB Review Stage 1 document has attracted criticism for its optimistic assessment of

Earth Science & Society T. Perron

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

CLIMATE CHANGE, HUMAN SYSTEMS, AND POLICY Vol. III - Integrated Assessment of Policy Instruments to Combat Climate Change - Hans Asbjorn Aaheim

Transcription:

Some Simple Economics of Climate Change Kevin M. Murphy The University of Chicago September 7, 2008 Climate Change Climate change has emerged as a significant policy issue. In the U.S. both Presidential candidates have promised plans to cut greenhouse gas emissions by 50-80% by 2050. There is a substantial risk that costly policies to mitigate global warming will be initiated in the near future. Is such a response supported by sound economic analysis? Goals of Today s Talk Provide some perspective on and insight into the economics of climate change. Analyze some of the key features of the economics of climate change and climate change policy. Provide simple and transparent models rather than an integrated analysis. Determine some possible focus for policy. Economic Literature Wide range of models o Many models are large "black-box" type models with many moving parts. o Difficult to asses the key assumptions and interactions. o High levels of parameter uncertainty. Wide range of implications: o Climate ramp (DICE-model) such as Nordhaus recommends incremental response to climate change. o The Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change calls from "dramatic action" and a carbon tax of $311 per ton. Important Economic Questions Discounting how much should we value costs/benefits in the distant future? How large are the costs likely to be? How will markets respond to the threat of climate change and climate change policy? How does uncertainty about the prospects for climate change affect the analysis? What about the dependence on government?

Discounting What makes discounting important? Many actions such as the emissions of GHG may have very long-term consequences (flow effects on the stock of atmospheric GHG concentrations). Simple model: current emissions = permanent change GHG concentration. If cost = C(GHG concentration) then this would imply the shadow cost of current emissions would be some form of a perpetuity. If costs of climate change are largely adjustment costs, that would shorten the horizon. When costs accumulate after climate change then the horizon gets longer. Many of the effect of GHG concentrations on climate/environment occur with a lag: o Rate of sea level rise is affected by the temperature may take substantial time to equilibrate to its new level o Thermal expansion effects are particularly long (centuries) Costs that accumulate with the level of environmental change have an upward sloping profile making discounting even more important. If costs are convex in climate change then economic impacts are even upward sloping than climate change making discounting even more important. Examples of Different Orders of Effects Impact of Discounting with Various Order Effects Ratio of PV (r = 4.0% normalized to 1.00) Discount Rate Order 0.10% 0.50% 1.00% 2.00% 3.00% 4.00% 5.00% 6.00% 8.00% Adj. Costs 1.76 1.64 1.50 1.29 1.13 1.00 0.90 0.82 0.69 Zero Order 40.00 8.00 4.00 2.00 1.33 1.00 0.80 0.67 0.50 First Order 69.24 12.87 5.91 2.55 1.49 1.00 0.72 0.55 0.35 Second 122.15 21.05 8.87 3.27 1.68 1.00 0.65 0.45 0.24 Third Order 215.56 34.44 13.30 4.21 1.89 1.00 0.59 0.37 0.17

The Appropriate Discount Rate Given the potential long term impact of climate change many have argued for using a low or essentially zero rate of discount. For example, the Stern Review uses a rate of time preference of 0.1 % per year based on an ethical stand that it is indefensible to use a positive social discount rate. However, the choice of the discount rate is not fundamentally about the weight we put on future generations. It is about opportunity costs. An Example Investment cost in 2008 = $1 B Benefit in 2108 = $20B r=6.0% Do future generations want us to make the investment in climate change mitigation? NO! they would prefer we would invest the $1B in other assets which would yield $339B in 100 years leaving them with the $20B to deal with climate change and $319B left over. Alternatively, we could invest just $59M at 6%, give them the $20B in 100 years and have $941 M left for ourselves. Implications We should use the market rate as the discount rate because that is the opportunity cost of climate mitigation. Using a lower discount rate unnecessarily harms current and/or future generations. With market discount rates the costs of climate change are greatly reduced relative to the claims of Stern and others. If We set Policy Based on Market Rates Will Future Generations be Impoverished by Climate Change? Unlikely based on past experience. Should people 100 years ago have adjusted their behavior so we could have more today? In fact the Stern model assumes individuals 200 years from now will be more than 10 times as rich as us even without climate change mitigation! Should we tax the poor (today's generation) to benefit the rich (future generations)? If we are concerned about future generations we should encourage all forms of intergenerational transfers not just transfers of climate wealth. Is there any justification for a low discount rate? One can justify a lower discount rate if climate mitigation has less systematic

risk than other capital investments (i.e. a low beta). Can justify a lower long term rate if long term returns are uncertain: o For example if the long term returns are equally likely to be 4% and 8%, the appropriate 100 year rate is 4.7% rather than the simple average of 6%. o For very long horizons this approaches the minimum possible return of 4%. The Environment as an Exhaustible Resource A simple framework is to think of climate mitigation in terms of limiting GHG concentrations to a particular level (say 650 002 equivalent ppm) in 100 years. The difference between the limit 650 and current levels (roughly 380) is then an exhaustible resource. To fix ideas, 0 will let c(x(t),t) be the cost of reducing emissions in year t by the amount x(t). The Economic Problem is Then The solution to this problem is: This implies that the incremental costs of emissions reduction should rise at the interest rate. Implications With a shadow price of carbon of $300 per ton in 100 years and r=6% the prices for carbon would be: o $93.54 in 80 years o $16.29 in 50 years o $2.84 in 20 years o $0.88 today With r=4% the corresponding prices for carbon would be: o $136.92 in 80 years o $42.21 in 50 years o $13.02 in 20 years o $5.94 today With productive capital the return to waiting is large.

With a fixed mitigation technology, the amount of mitigation, z(t), will rise over time according to: where y(z) is the elasticity of mitigation costs w.r.t. the amount of mitigation (the inverse of the elasticity of supply). With technical progress in mitigation at rate a this becomes: Without technical progress the rate of mitigation increase is proportional to the interest rate. With technical progress mitigation grows at a rate proportional to the interest rate plus the rate of technical progress. Given the technological nature of climate mitigation a is likely to be important making waiting more valuable. When marginal costs of mitigation rise slowly, y is low, mitigation is greatly postponed. When marginal costs of mitigation increase quickly then it pays to spread mitigation out 99 more mitigation early on. Example r=6% a=2%, 20% reduction in emissions over 100 year horizon (baseline growth=1.5%): Conclusions on Discounting & Timing With costs due to climate in the distant future (e.g. 100+ years) and productive capital: o It pays to wait for climate mitigation and ramp up policy over time due to discounting. o The expectation of technical progress further postpones mitigation. o One exception to waiting would be if incremental mitigation costs rise very steeply with the amount of mitigation.

o With "scalable" technologies, y will tend to be low since costs will then rise slowly with mitigation activity. What About Estimates of Costs and the Level of Mitigation Needed? Estimates of costs will tend to be exaggerated: o Substitution tends to reduce costs perhaps greatly. o May be more costly to do what we are doing now but can easily be less costly to do something else. o Avenues for substitution not always obvious ex-ante. o Economic activity will shift to areas/activities where costs increase less or even decrease: Move toward currently colder locations. Move toward less environmentally sensitive activities indoors. Shift techniques for given activities change crops and growing techniques in agriculture. Evidence from the Marketplace GDP is similar in places with very different average temperature (Minnesota & Florida). Ability to deal with the environment has grown over time: Impact of air conditioning Dealing with sea-level rise in the Netherlands GDP has become less energy intensive over time (energy usage growing much slower than GDP in the developed world). GDP less environmentally dependent over time agriculture etc. has become a smaller share of GDP over time What about Uncertainty? Uncertainty might matter a lot. Several kinds of uncertainty matter: o Uncertainty over timing o Uncertainty over magnitudes o Uncertainty over returns on investment Example A permanent loss of 1 % of GDP that happens 100 years from now r=6%, g=1.5% PV of loss = 0.25% of current GDP WTP is.01 % of GDP per year to avoid the risk What if timing is random with same expected time of 100 years (i.e. 1% chance each year)? PV = 4.04% of GDP (a 16 fold increase) What if the loss is 1% in expectation but it is a small probability of large

catastrophic loss? Evidence from the value of life says multiply market loss by a factor of roughly 4-8. Using the midpoint of a 6x multiple implies potential loss now valued at 6*4.04% = 24.1 % of GDP (an increase of roughly 100 fold from the certainty case with the same expected loss and expected timing). This corresponds to a WTP to eliminate the risk of 1.1% of GDP per year. Implications A small chance of a large loss with very uncertain timing (even if expected waiting time is large) can generate substantial WTP. Uncertainty can matter a lot. Current action should focus on eliminating the worst case scenarios that could happen quickly (develop a contingency plan). Example this implies high value on a scalable carbon capture/reduction technology. Would be highly valuable even if expensive only used in worst case truncates the left (worst) tail of outcomes. Related Economic Issues Bad climate outcomes that lower the return to capital may limit our ability to compensate future generations for environmental change making things even worse. Mitigation against modest climate change likely to have a positive beta biggest gains in highest GDP states since costs of climate change likely to rise with GDP. Mitigation against very bad climate outcomes likely to have a negative beta (pays off most in the worst states). This too says focusing on extreme outcomes makes sense. Other Economic Issues Policy needs to be aware of market responses. Example: o Unilateral switch to a lower GHG emissions technology o Reduces demand for existing fuel sources o Lowers price of existing fuel sources o Encourages consumption of existing fuels by others o Total emissions could go up if the elasticity of supply of fuels is sufficiently low Question: can we prevent reserves hydrocarbon fuels from being used by somebody? This and other substitution problems create headaches for unilateral policy action. May be less substitution problems for GHG capture solutions no direct substitution though effects through policy incentives.

Coordinated government action has its own problems. Implementing the climate ramp policy requires commitment to pricing of carbon. Governments are not good at long term policy commitments. Governments are likely to be particularly bad at creating incentives to mitigate worst case scenarios. Mitigating these scenarios requires high payoff in bad states. Governments unlikely to honor property rights of private providers in worst states (e.g. nationalization). Difficult for governments to plan for low probability events very difficult to monitor and measure performance Examples: o Pre-war preparedness o Disaster management Conclusions Important to use market rates when discounting effects of climate change. Optimal response to the threat of modest climate change with future costs should be gradual. Technical change enhances the gain to waiting. Many estimates of the costs of climate change likely to be too high due to the tendency to understate our ability to substitute in mitigation and adaptation. Even catastrophic change that is unlikely and uncertain could be important. Governments unlikely to be good at solving these problems particularly the possibility of extreme change.