THE AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF

Similar documents
not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

LESSON 9. Economic Fluctuations: Balancing Aggregate Demand and Supply

The goods market. Screen 1

ECONOMICS ASSIGNMENT CLASS XII MICRO ECONOMICS UNIT I INTRODUCTION. 4. Is free medicine given to patients in Govt. Hospital a scarce commodity?

Chapter 2: The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply. Multiple Choice Questions

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 24. Perfect Competition

Economic Analysis for Business Decisions Multiple Choice Questions Unit-2: Demand Analysis

The Financial Market

Chapter 28 The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

Demand & Supply of Resources

Copyright 2017 by the UBC Real Estate Division

Bremen School District 228 Social Studies Common Assessment 2: Midterm

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

Theory of Employment

foundations of economics fourth edition Andrew Gillespie OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

1. If the per unit cost of production falls, then... A.) the supply curve shifts right (or down)

Law of Supply. General Economics

E.C.O.-6 Economic Theory

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

Commerce 295 Midterm Answers

LONG RUN AGGREGATE SUPPLY

MICROECONOMICS SECTION I. Time - 70 minutes 60 Questions

MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 10A/23 PERFECT COMPETITION. Professor Charles Fusi

Micro Economics M.A. Economics (Previous) External University of Karachi Micro-Economics

Economics. Synopsis. 1. Economic Concepts, Issues and Tools. 2. An Overview of Economics. Sections. Learning Summary. Sections

Analysis of Electricity Markets. Lennart Söder


INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

CHAPTER THREE DEMAND AND SUPPLY

The Heckscher Ohlin Model

Unit 5. Producer theory: revenues and costs

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Chapter 3 EXPANDED GAINS FROM TRADE WITH RESOURCE MOVEMENTS

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

1. T F The resources that are available to meet society s needs are scarce.

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Lecture 10: THE AD-AS MODEL Reference: Chapter 8

Notes On IS-LM Model: Application Econ3120, Economic Department, St.Louis University

Introduction Question Bank

Labour Demand Lecturer: Dr. Priscilla T. Baffour

JANUARY EXAMINATIONS 2008

Supply and Demand Basics

MPC MPC. Under a Pigouvian subsidy, s, the firm s MPC curve shifts up to MPC = MPC + s. This is less

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

Competitive Markets. Chapter 5 CHAPTER SUMMARY

ECON MACROECONOMIC PRINCIPLES Instructor: Dr. Juergen Jung Towson University. J.Jung Chapter Introduction Towson University 1 / 69

Chapter 33: Aggregate Demand and Aggregate Supply Principles of Economics, 8 th Edition N. Gregory Mankiw Page 1


Subtleties of the Supply and Demand Model: Price Floors, Price Ceilings, and Elasticity

Wallingford Public Schools - HIGH SCHOOL COURSE OUTLINE

Notes on Chapter 10 OUTPUT AND COSTS

ECON 201: Introduction to Macroeconomics Professor Robert Gordon Midterm Exam 1: October 17, 2016

PICK ONLY ONE BEST ANSWER FOR EACH BINARY CHOICE OR MULTIPLE CHOICE QUESTION.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Chapter 11. Microeconomics. Technology, Production, and Costs. Modified by: Yun Wang Florida International University Spring 2018

+ What is Economics? societies use scarce resources to produce valuable commodities and distribute them among different people

Graded exercise questions. Level (I, ii, iii)

BACHELOR OF BUSINESS. Sample FINAL EXAMINATION

Submit your scantron and questions sheet

ENGINEERING ECONOMICS AND FINANCIAL ACCOUNTING 2 MARKS

3 CHAPTER OUTLINE CASE FAIR OSTER PEARSON. Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium. Input Markets and Output Markets: The Circular Flow

Principles of Economics Final Exam. Name: Student ID:

Prices and Wages in Trade Theory

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

EC1010 Introduction to Micro Economics (Econ 6003)

Econ 001: Midterm 2 (Dr. Stein) Answer Key March 23, 2011

Reflections on Carbon Leakage

Productivity, Output, and Employment. Chapter 3. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Economics. In an economy, the production units are called (a) Firm (b) Household (c) Government (d) External Sector

Appendix A. The horizontal axis measures both GDP and Sales. The vertical axis measures the average price level.

Perfectly Competitive Markets

CLEP Microeconomics Practice Test

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Specific Learning Goals/Benchmarks and Student Assessment. AP Macroeconomics

International Economics, 9e (Husted/Melvin) Chapter 2 Tools of Analysis for International Trade Models. 2.1 Multiple-Choice Questions

Chapter 21. Consumer Choice

Gregory Clark Econ 1A, Winter 2012 SAMPLE FINAL

Chapter 1: The Ten Lessons in Economics

Come & Join Us at VUSTUDENTS.net

23 Perfect Competition

Fin 345: Lesson 2 (Part 3) Instructor Glenn E. Crellin Slide #1. Slide Title: Fin 345 Lesson 2 (Part 3)

Chapter 14. Chapter Outline

Chapter Outline McGraw Hill Education. All Rights Reserved.

Assignment 2: Supply and Demand

Microeconomics traditionally splits the consequences of

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

1. Demand: willingness to buy a good or service and the ability to pay for it; how much of an item an individual is willing to purchase at each price

Homework 4 Economics

OCR GCSE Economics Unit 1 How the Market works

Polar Cases of Elasticity and Constant Elasticity

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Chapter 4 DEMAND. Essential Question: How do we decide what to buy?

UNIT 4 PRACTICE EXAM

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Supply in a Competitive Market

Agenda. The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis, Part 3. Disequilibrium in the AD-AS model

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Transcription:

THE AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS VOL. 21 DECEMBER 1977 NO. 3 EFFECTS OF MINERAL DEVELOPMENT ON THE ECONOMY* RICHARD H. SNAPE Monash University R. G. Gregory s article on the effects of mineral discoveries on the Australian economy (Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, August 1976) has attracted much attention. While the partial-equilibrium nature of his model has enabled it to be absorbed readily, it has the usual theoretical limitations of such analyses. Allowing for general equilibrium repercussions, but still accepting his general assumpths, some of Gregory s conclusions regarding the impact of new mineral discoveries require modification or extension: (a) Although production of goods other than minerals can be expected to decline, the production of some goods in this category may rise; (b) A social gain is still possible even if outputs of other goods do not change; (c) While the price of non-tradeable goods can be expected to rise, production of non-tradeables may increase or decrease. We also show the magnified effect of mineral discoveries on the rents of factors specific to minerals, and the squeeze exerted on the rents of factors specific to other tradeables. I Introduction With unusual success, Bob Gregory (Gregory 1976) has captured the attention of the economics profession and the financial press in analysing the impact of mineral development on the Australian economy. The essence of his model is that mineral discoveries lead to an increase in export supply and that this brings an external surplus. The correction of this surplus by currency revaluation or by domestic inflation raises the price of non-tradeable goods relative to the price of exports and imports. As a consequence import-competing and pre-existing export industries are squeezed. The model is simple and appears to explain some of the difficulties experienced by import-competing industries in recent years. Gregory s basic model is reproduced in Figure 1. The relative price of traded to non-traded goods is shown on the vertical axis. It is assumed that there are constant international terms of trade and that import-competing goods are perfect substitutes for imports. Thus with given tariffs, export subsidies, etc., the relative prices of imports, importcompeting goods, exports and exportables consumed domestically are *Some of the material of this paper was presented to a Conference in Applied Eoonornic Research at the Reserve Bank of Australia in. September 1976 and to an Exchange Rate Workshop at the Centre for Applied Economic Research, University of New South Wales, March 1977. I have been assisted by discussions with Michael Porter and comments from members of a workshop at Monash and from a referee. A 147

148 AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS DEC. all constant. On the horizontal axis the quantities of exports and imports are measured; units are chosen so that a unit of exports exchanges for a unit of imports. The curves Xo and Mo indicate the supply of exports and the demand for imports, respectively, at various price ratios, prior to the mineral discovery. With constant international terms of trade all eriports which are offered at a given price will be purchased and all imports demanded will be supplied at a constant price; thus Xo and Mo can be regarded as showing actual exports and imports. Exports equal imports at the intersection of the two curves. Allowance can easily be made for capital flows so that overall external balance can be shown, but it is simplest to assume zero net capita1 movements. The upward slope of I Price of Traded Price of Non-Traded Goods I 0 Exports and Imports FIGURE 1 Xo derives from the increased profitability of producing export goods as the traded to non-traded price ratio rises and also from the decreased domestic demand, as this price rises, for goods which could be exported. The downward slope of Mo reflects the increased demand for importables (imports and domestically-produced substitutes), and the reduced profitability of producing substitutes domestically, as the price ratio falls. With mineral discoveries, the export curve shifts to the right to XI, leading to a lower equilibrium traded/non-traded price ratio and increased exports and imports; as indicated, domestic inflation or exchange rate revaluation could change the price ratio in the required manner. Gregory argues that both import-competing industries and preexisting exporting industries will be reduced in size and that The adjustments that need to be made depend on the extent of the mineral discoveries, the price elasticity of supply of minerals exports and the price elasticity of demand and supply of imports and traditional exports. (Gregory, p. 77.) He then undertakes a number of calculations of the

1977 EFFECTS OF MINERAL DEVELOPMENT ON ECONOMY 149 relevant elasticities, etc., and the price adjustments required to accommodate the Australian mineral boom. Gregory s thesis is an important one and he has shown great ingenuity in applying it. However, there are some difficulties associated with it. Apart from questions relating to the time period over which adjustment may occur, the difficulties spring from the partial equilibrium nature of his model. His import and export curves are not shifted as aggregate income and, hence, total demand changes. Again, the impacts of the mineral development on the costs of import-competing and pre-existing export industries are not considered. In short, general equilibrium questions are being considered and partial equilibrium tools, like Figure 1 and supply and demand elasticities that ignore the income and cost effects of mineral development, cannot handle them adequately. Of course the analysis will not mislead greatly if the effects taken into account are very strong relative to those omitted. However, it is dacult to accept that an export development that is judged large enough to have a significant effect on the balance of payments would not also have a significant effect on national income, on costs (as well as prices) of other industries and on the demand for imports. In passing it may be noted that Gregory s model has much in common with the Aukrust, EFO or Scandinavian model of inflation (see, for example, Edgren et al. 1973), which has gained considerable attention in recent discussions of sources of inflation. In this model it is also assumed that a division can be made between tradeables and nontradeables, that the country is small so that it cannot affect the international terms of trade, and that the tradeables sector is the main source of productivity growth. This growth corresponds analytically to the mineral developments in Gregory s model. The growth requires an increase in the price of non-tradeables relative to tradeables. At a constant rate of exchange and given international terms of trade this changed price ratio can only be secured by the price of non-tradeables rising in money terms-that is, with a period of domestic inflation. If the rest of the world is inflating or revaluing, so that the price of tradeabies is rising, then the price adjustment requires more rapid inflation in the country being considered. In the following sections, simple general equilibrium models are developed to explore the consequences of mineral development. Like Gregory, a before and after or comparative static analysis is adopted. In effect this assumes that the development is rapid enough for the other things being equal assumption to be made. In Section IV the paper extends beyond the questions attacked by Gregory. II All Goods Tradeable We start by assuming an even simpier model than Gregory s, one in which all goods are tradeables. They are divided into two categories, Minerals and Other Goods, the latter comprising exportables other than minerals, imports and the domestic production of import-competing goods. Constant international terms of trade are assumed. In Figure 2 the (equal) slopes of PP, P P and P*P* indicate the fixed price ratio between the two categories of goods. The mineral discoveries will increase the productivity of labour and capital in the mineral sector; the shift of the production transformation curve from AB to AB reflects

150 AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECQNOMICS DEC. this. Point Q indicates the optimum production point before the discoveries while Q is the optimum after the discovery. Could Q lie north of Q, so that Other Good production increases? Consider what may be thought of as a limiting case, this being that the effect of the mineral discovery is to increase the production of Minerals by the same amount at all levels of Other Good pr0duction.l In other words, the size of the increased production of minerals is not a Other Goods P* A G 0 Minerals B B F,cvP,z 7 fuaction of the inputs of factors other than the mineral resource itself. Under this assumption the production possibility curve shifts horizontally by the same amount at each point. At a point due east of Q on AB, the slope of AB would be the same as that of AB at point Q. In this case there would be unchanged production of Other Goods at the given terms of trade. If, however, the increased output of minerals is related to the use of actors of production, so the horizontal gap between AB and AB iizcreases as Other Good production declines (as illustrated in Figure 2), then the efficient production point Q will be southeast from Q. This occurs because with the gap increasing, the marginal opportunity cost of producing minerals, at any given level of Other Good production, is decreased. Thus at any given price ratio it will be 1 Such a change appears unrealistic in the region of point A in Figure 2, for it implies a horizontal section of the new transformation curve from this point, but we are not really concerned with what happens in the region of complete specialization. Note that nothing is assumed regarding the nature of production functions except that there are increasing opportunity costs for each category of goods. It is also assumed that marginal social costs are equated to prices.

1977 EFFECTS OF MINERAL DEVELOPMENT ON ECONOMY 151 profitable to use more mobile factors in mineral, rather than Other Good production. Hence it is unlikely that Other Good production would rise. Although the model here is simpler than Gregory s in that there are no non-tradeables, the conclusion supports him. However, we may note: (i) That even though it is likely that production of Other Goods as a whoie wouid fall, contrary to Gregory the production of some goods within this category could rise even if their relative prices do not change; thus the production either of exportables other than minerals or of importables could increase, the increase of one being outweighed by the decrease of the other. The differing effect could come through the cost side. To illustrate, suppose that mineral production prior to the discovery had been fairly labour intensive but the newly discovered deposits lead to a substitution of capital for labour and lower the demand for labour. Other industries could now hire labour more cheaply than before and may increase their production. This possibility is overlooked by a partialequilibrium analysis. (ii) That even if production of Other Goods is prevented from changing by policy, there is still a gain from development of the mineral resource. This is contrary to the suggestion (Gregory 1976, p. 77) that production of Other Goods must contract so that the gains from mineral development may be secured. The point may be illustrated by viewing PP in Figure 2 as an availability of goods frontier. Points between PP and the origin are achievable, those beyond PP are not. Point Q is the optimal production point and trade may occur along PP, with the domestic consumption point being determined by demand. If Other Good production was retained at its original level of OC, so that the production point on AB is Q*, then the availability frontier would be P*P*. There is still a gain from the mineral development, though not as great a gain as would have been obtained by letting Other Good production contract so that Q is the production point and P P the availability frontier, III Nun-Tradeables Introduced We now introduce another category of production, non-tradeables. Rather than attempt three-dimensional representation, we join importables and exportables (including minerals) into a composite good, again using the assumption of given international terms of trade, and introduce non-tradeables as a second good. Again the mineral discovery shifts the production frontier. As the tradeable/non-tradeable price ratio may alter, it is necessary to introduce demand to determine a production point; this is done in the usual way with a community preference map, the derivation of which is unspecified. What will happen to the price ratio and to the production of tradeables and non-tradeables? On what appear to be very reasonable assumptions we can establish: (a) that tradeable production will increase; (b) that the price of non-tradeables will increase; (c) that the production of non-tradeables could increase or decrease. The conclusions (a) and (b) are consistent with those of Gregory s partial equilibrium analysis, but the third conclusion is not consistent

~ 152 AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS DEC. NOTI- Tradeables R 0 Tradeables s s' 0 Tradeables S S' FIGURE 3

1977 EFFECTS OF MINERAL DEVELOPMENT ON ECONOMY 153 with his suggestion (p. 78) that the size of sectors will change in the same direction as prices. To explain these points, consider Figure 3. As a consequence of mineral discoveries the production frontier for tradeables and nontradeables shifts from RS to RS. Initially, consumption and production are at W. If the increase in tradeables production is the same at all levels of non-tradeables production (as in Figure 3 (a) ) then the marginal cost of tradeables is unchanged at any given level of non-tradeables production, and the slope of RS at a point due east of W (i.e. We) will be the same as the slope of RS at W. At all higher points along RS, the slope will be flatter. Unless non-tradeables are inferior goods their price will rise and thus the new equilibrium must be above We. However, it will not be above Wn, a point due north of W, unless tradeables are inferior goods, for such a movement would imply a reduction in the consumption of tradeables despite their lower price. Thus, excepting inferiority, the new equilibrium will be confined to the segment of RS that is north-east of W, i.e., between We and Wn. However it appears more Iikely that the increase in minerals and tradeables production will be greater, the greater the quantity of mobile factors of production that are used in minerals. This implies that the increase in tradeables production would be inversely related to nontradeables production. This case is illustrated in Figure 3 (b). Here it is possible for the new equilibrium to be south of We along RS (e.g., at W ). This may occur even when one retains the assumption of noninferiority of non-tradeables, for the slope of RS at We (and for some distance below We) in Figure 3 (b) is flatter than that of RS at W. That is, there could be reduced production of non-tradeables, even though their price increases, for their marginal cost has increased at their old level of production, OH. Thus, on the assumptions of non-inferiority and that the increase in production of tradeables is not positively related to non-tradeable production (i.e,, that it is not inversely related to the input of other factors of production), one can expect the price of non-tradeables to rise and production of tradeables to increase.2 There is no reason, however, to presume one way or the other regarding the change of output of nontradeables. While increased income encourages demand for them, their increased price and marginal cost discourage it. ZV Tradeubles, Nun-Tradeables, Labour and Rents We now consider some implications of mineral discoveries in a model in which factors of production are explicit. It is assumed that there are three goods-exportables, importables and non-tradeables-and at least three factors of production. However, only one factor of production, labour, is mobile between the three industries. It is assumed that nontradeables are produced by labour alone, while exportables and importtables require labour and other factors which, in the period considered, are assumed immobile. We assume decreasing returns to increasing 2This analycis is relevant to the concern some writers have expressed for the neglect of the role of demand in the rise in the relative price of non-tradeables in the Scandinavian model (e.g. Kierzkowski 1974; Flanders 1975). The required demand condition is much weaker than that investigated by Kierzkowski-homothetic community preferences.

154 AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL OF AGRICULTURAL ECONOMICS DEC. applications of labour to the specific factors while there are constant returns to labour in non-tradeables. The base OA of Figure 4 shows the amount of labour available. Use of labour in the production of the exportable goods and in tradeable goods as a whole is measured from the left hand side; use in nontradeables is measured from the right hand side. The left-hand vertical axis measures the marginal product of labour in exportables or tradeables (remembering the assumption of constant terms of trade), while the right-hand vertical axis measures the marginal product of labour in non-tradeables. Assuming tradeabies to be the numeraire, the marginal product in the non-tradeables industry is measured in tradeables. The curve LM shows the marginal product of labour in exportables, TW shows it in non-tradeables, assuming the equilibrium tradeables/nontradeables price ratio. We now introduce the marginal product of labour in the production of importables: this is drawn in relation to the movable axis BZ and is shown by the line NP. We assume an initial equilibrium with the three values of the marginal products of labour (given the equilibrium price ratio) equal and equal to the wage rate. OB of labour is in tradeables, of which OC is in exportables and CB in irnpor:ables, while AB of labour is used in non-tradeables. Assume now that there are mineral discoveries so that the specific factor in exportables is supplemented and that the marginal product of labour in exportables rises by the proportion k at every level of labour input, causing LA4 to shift to L'M'. (This is consistent with Figure 3(b) above.) It is apparent that the direction of response of several variables is determined by the extent to which the price of non-tradeables risesthis is reflected by the extent to which the 'marginal product of labour in non-tradeables' curve, TW, rises. Z' 2 L' L T' T" T 0 c C' B' B FIGURE 4 A

1977 EFFECTS OF MINERAL DEVELOPMENT ON ECONOMY 155 Consider first a rise in the price of non-tradeables by the proportion k. The marginal product of labour in non-tradeables (measured in tradeables) would increase in the proportion k from TW to T W, and the marginal product of labour in exportables and importables would also rise in proportion k. This would be achieved at an unchanged usage of labour in exportables, so that production increases by the proportion k, but with reduced production of importables. Use of labour in importables would decrease from CB to CB, while the use of labour in non-tradeables would increase to AB. In this case rents to the factors specific to exportables would rise in the proportion k, as do wages, while rents in importables would fall. Consider now the implications of a rise in price of non-tradeables just to an extent to keep production of non-tradeables, and its use of labour (AB), unchanged-we define this proportion as r (which equals TT /AT). The use of labour in exportables would increase to OC while that in importables would decrease by CC. In this case rents to factors specific to exportables would increase by more than the proportion k. (On the original Iabour input of OC the value of exportable production rises by the proportion k while wages increase by the lesser proportion r; additional rents are also earned on the extra labour input CC.) Rents to the factor specific to importables would decline less than in the previous case. Suppose now that prices of non-tradeables increase by less than the proportion r. Now non-tradeables production will decline despite the rise in price of non-tradeabies, and the importables axis, BZ, will move to the right. (This is not shown in the diagram.) Rents to exportables will increase even more than in the previous case while the decline in rents in importables will be further eased. However as long as the price of non-tradeables, together with the wages of labour, rises at all, rents in importables will be squeezed in this simple model. As these rents decline in terms of tradeables, they must decline in terms of all commodities. The simple model brings out the high sensitivity of rents in the exportable and import-competing industries, and suggests why interests in these industries appear to react rather strongly to changing industrial structures. Mineral discoveries have a magnified effect on rents in the mineral industry (cf. Jones 1971, p. 9), rising in greater proportion than does output per man, unless the price of non-tradeables rises in a proportion at least as great as the productivity of labour in minerals. V Summary Allowing for general equilibrium repercussions, but still accepting his general assumptions, some of Gregory s conclusions regarding the impact of new mineral discoveries require modification or extension: (a) Although production of goods other than minerals can be expected to decline, the production of some goods in this category may rise; (b) A social gain is still possible even if outputs of other goods do not change; (c) While the price of non-tradeable goods can be expected to rise, production of non-tradeables may increase or decrease. We also show the magnified effect of mineral discoveries on the rents

156 AUSTRALIAN JOURNAL QF AGRICULTURAL ECQNOMICS DEC. of factors specific to minerals, and the squeeze exerted on the rents of factors specific to other tradeables. Bibliography coda Edgren, Karl-Olof Faxh and Clas-Erik Odhner, Wage Formation and the Economy. (Allen and Unwin, 1973.) M. June Flanders, The Scandinavian Model and The Balance of Payments. Social Science Research Council, International Monetary Research Programme at the London School of Economics, mimeo. (August 1975.) R. G. Gregory, Some Implications of the Growth of the Mineral Sector. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics, August 1976, pp. 71-91. Ronald W. Jones, A Three-Factor Model in Theory, Trade, and History. In Jagdish N. Bhagwati, ef al. (eds.) Trade, Balance of Paymenfs and Growfh. Papers in Honour of Charles P. Kindleberger. (North-Holland: Amsterdam 1971.) Henryk I. Kierzkowski, Theoretical Foundations of the Scandinavian Model of Infiation. Social Science Research Council, International Monetary Research Programme at the London School of Economics, rnimeo. (September 1974.)