Factor Market Distortions: Input Subsidies and Compensation

Similar documents
Grain Transportation Policy and Transformation in Western Canadian Agriculture

Review of Agricultural Economics Volume 24, Number 2 Pages

Manitoba Pig and Pork Industry

Agricultural Policy, Agribusiness, and Rent-Seeking Behaviour

The Estey Centre Journal of. International Law. and Trade Policy. Transformative Change in Agriculture: The Canadian Wheat Board

AGRICULTURAL TRADE AND ITS IMPORTANCE

CANADIAN AGRI-FOOD TRADE ALLIANCE

Situation and Outlook of the Canadian Livestock Industry

Grain Monitoring Program Report for: January 2017

CAIRN. CAIRN Policy Brief. Toll Goods and Agricultural Policy. By Murray Fulton and Richard Gray

CANADIAN TRANSPORTATION AND GRAIN HANDLING: ISSUES AFFECTING THE NORTH AMERICAN BARLEY SECTOR

An Economic Analysis of Removing the. Canadian Wheat Board s Single Desk Authority. and Rail Deregulation in Western Canada

Jason Henderson Vice President and Branch Executive Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Omaha Branch April 25, 2012

Rethinking US Agricultural Policy:

CANADA TRANSPORTATION ACT REVIEW INITIAL SUBMISSION FOCUSED ON THE GRAIN INDUSTRY. Infrastructure, Efficiency, Transparency

THE CANADIAN GRAIN HANDLING SUPPLY CHAIN IN THE POST CANADIAN WHEAT BOARD ERA

Producer Recommendations on the Future of Canada s Transportation Act

Determinants of Brazil s Ethanol Sugar Blend Ratios

SOME ASPECTS OF AGRICULTURAL POLICY IN AUSTRALIA

attack Under The Canadian Wheat Board is in an intense battle to maintain its wheat and barley trading monopoly FEATURE

Cheap Grain and Tariffs. A note on O Rourke and the late 19 th century Grain Invasion in Europe.

Project on Organic Agriculture

TPP and Canada s Dairy Sector: How Reducing Protection Can Increase Rents. Richard Barichello

A lost opportunity? Ian Sheldon Department of Agricultural, Environmental and Development Economics

IN CANADA 2017 GROWING SEASON Canadian Wheat Crop in Review

Railroads and Grain. Association of American Railroads June Summary

Focus. Panhandle Model Farms - Case Studies of Texas High Plain Agriculture. Diana Jones Dustin Gaskins Jay Yates

Agriculture: issues of the past resurface

An Overview of the Canadian Agriculture and Agri-Food System

Agriculture: expansions highlighted developments

Farm Economics brief

Competitive Pressure and Technology Adoption: Evidence from a Policy Reform in Western Canada

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

Commodity Value Enhancement Fund Analysis

2012 STATE FFA FARM BUSINESS MANAGEMENT TEST PART 2. Financial Statements (FINPACK Balance Sheets found in the resource information)

Marketing Contracts, Overconfidence, and Timing in the Canadian Wheat Market

e-brief Pulling the Plug on Monopoly Power: Reform for the Canadian Wheat Board June 23, 2011

China s Role in World Livestock and Feed-Grain Markets?

EC2004: International Trade Revision Topics.

Agriculture in Northern Alberta

U.S. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE ECONOMIC RESEARCH SERVICE August 1972 FCR-83 cooperating with New Mexico State University COSTS NOV

Agriculture: farm income recovers

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

Project on Organic Agriculture

Reform of the Common Agricultural Policy Ulrich Koester, University of Kiel

After Hong Kong: Potential Impacts of the WTO Doha Round SPECIAL REPORT. Larry Martin, Al Mussell, and Terri-lyn Moore.

Thank you for this opportunity to present the concerns of the U.S. cotton industry.

AGEC 429: AGRICULTURAL POLICY LECTURE 24: U.S. AGRICULTURAL TRADE POLICY

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

GIEWS Country Brief Malaysia

Dynamics of Wheat and Barley Shipments on Haul Roads to and from Grain Warehouses in Washington State

Catalogue no X. Statistics on Revenues and Expenses of Farms

RETUR COSTS A 8 R R. and 96 LI6R R

Table 1. U.S. Agricultural Exports as a Share of Production, 1992

Outline. L8- Agricultural Research Policy. Why is research important? Competitive firms adopt cost saving technologies 1/29/09

Soy Canada SOYBEAN PROCESSING WORKSHOP PRESENTATION NOVEMBER 16, 2017 BRANDON, MANITOBA

Challenges and Opportunities for Canada s Freight Railways

An Economic Comparison of Organic and Conventional Dairy Production, and Estimations on the Cost of Transitioning to Organic Production

Wheat Processing in Canada

Future perspectives and challenges for European agriculture

Canfax Research Services A Division of the Canadian Cattlemen s Association

Southern Alberta: Growth of Import and Export Opportunities for West Coast Ports

Chapter 9. The Instruments of Trade Policy

2017 Beef Cattle Market Outlook

ANALYSIS AND COMMENTS

A Short History of U.S. Freight Railroads

October 20, 1998 Ames, Iowa Econ. Info U.S., WORLD CROP ESTIMATES TIGHTEN SOYBEAN SUPPLY- DEMAND:

EU support of its processing tomato industry and the competitive consequences for California

A paper presented at the. International Agricultural Trade Research Consortium annual meeting. Aukland, New Zealand. January 2001

A Tax Incentive for Certified Seed: An Assessment

Statistics for Manitoba Pig Industry

Research Drive Saskatoon, SK S7N 3R2 T (306) F (306)

Impact of China s Agriculture Policies on Domestic and World Commodity Markets

Trade Impacts of Common Agricultural Policy

Philippine Agricultural and Food Policies: Implications on Poverty and Income Distribution

Understanding Aggregate Supply

Differences Between High-, Medium-, and Low-Profit Cow-Calf Producers: An Analysis of Kansas Farm Management Association Cow-Calf Enterprise

A Thesis Submitted to the College of Graduate Studies and Research In Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements For the Degree of Masters of Science

Iowa Farm Outlook. December 2015 Ames, Iowa Econ. Info Replacement Quality Heifer Prices Supported by Latest Data

Mona Loa Malaysian Manufacturing cost per bag... $6.00 $5.00 Add markup at 30% Selling price per bag... $7.80 $6.50

Agriculture in China - Successes, Challenges, and Prospects. Prof. Zhihao Zheng College of Economics & Management China Agricultural University

Global Growth in Pork Production

UNION COUNTY AGRICULTURAL DEVELOPMENT COUNCIL COMPREHENSIVE PLAN. Union County is in the northwestern part of Kentucky. Union County is bounded on the

Agri-Service Industry Report

THE FARM BILL AND THE WESTERN HAY INDUSTRY. Daniel A. Sumner and William Matthews 1

Commodity Program Reform and the Structure of U.S. Agriculture

UPDATE ON THE ECONOMIC IMPACTS OF THE CANADIAN DAIRY INDUSTRY IN 2015

The Local Impacts of Agricultural Subsidies: Evidence from the Canadian Prairies

Agricultural Outlook Forum 2002 Presented: Friday, February 22, 2002 CHINA S ACCESSION TO WTO: IMPLICATIONS FOR US AGRICULTURAL EXPORTS

PRODUCTION AND TRADE POLICIES AFFECTING THE COTTON INDUSTRY

An essay about the privatization in UK

I enjoy teaching this class. Good luck and have a nice Holiday!!

Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

EFFECTS OF UNILATERAL TRADE LIBERALIZATION IN SOUTH ASIAN COUNTRIES: Applications of CGE Models of Bangladesh, India, Nepal, Pakistan and Sri Lanka

Status and trends in milk production world wide

RESOLUTIONS to the CANADIAN FEDERATION OF AGRICULTURE STANDING POLICY. As Approved at the 2018 ANNUAL MEETING OTTAWA, ONTARIO

Agricultural subsidy policies and its development in PR China

Canpotex Exporting Potash to International Markets. Feb 2007

Michael E. Salassi and Michael A. Deliberto 1

Transcription:

MSABR 02-02 Morrison School of Agribusiness and Resource Management Faculty Working Paper Series Factor Market Distortions: Input Subsidies and Compensation Troy G. Schmitz, Tim Highmoor, Andrew Schmitz January 16, 2002 This report is also available online at http://agb.east.asu.edu/workingpapers/0202.pdf

Factor Market Distortions: Input Subsidies and Compensation Troy Schmitz (University of Arizona) Tim Highmoor (University of Saskatchewan) and Andrew Schmitz (University of Florida) January 16, 2002; 10am Draft : Not for Quotation

Factor Market Distortions: Input Subsidies and Compensation Troy Schmitz, Tim Highmoor, and Andrew Schmitz Introduction The theory of factor market distortions deals largely with taxing inputs (Just, Hueth, and Schmitz, 1982; Markusen et al., 1995). However, input subsidies are not only common in manufacturing. For example, U.S. agriculture is heavily dependent on input subsidies. If water subsidies in the production of California cotton were removed, along with commodity payments, production of cotton in California would likely cease (Schmitz, Schmitz, and Dumas, 1997). Likewise, transportation subsidies were common in both the U.S. and Canada, and still prevail in the U.S. Transportation subsidies played a key role in the development of North American agriculture (Fowke, 1957; Schmitz, Furtan, and Baylis, 2002). In Canada s early development years, rail transportation rates were agreed to under the Crowsnest Pass agreement. In 1897 the Canadian Pacific Railway Company entered into a subsidy and rate-control agreement with the Dominion of Canada government for the construction of the Crow s Nest Pass Railway (Fowke, p.54). Much later, the Canadian National Railway and the Canadian Pacific Railway argued that rail rates had to be adjusted because the railroads were incurring large losses from hauling grain from the prairies to ocean ports. The federal government agreed to pay the Crow shortfall to the railways. This shortfall approached $800 million in the 1991/92 crop year. Though many groups favoured continuing the pay-the-railroads approach, others put forth recommendations to pay the Crow gap to producers through a one-time payment. The livestock industry in particular supported this proposal as they argued that the added costs of shipping grain 2

out of the prairies, if the Crow subsidy was changed in this manner, would lower the cost of beef production on the prairies and create much needed value added activities. The federal government in 1996 eliminated the Crow completely by paying producers what many argue was only a portion of the Crow gap. Full compensation was not paid. For example, Rosaassen and Schmitz (1985) contend that at most only 30 percent of the full compensation amount was paid. The elimination of the Crow resulted in significant increases in rail rates. Rail rates increased by a factor of roughly four (Figure 1). Despite the importance consequences of removing the Crow, little formal analysis was ever done on what the impact would be. Would the agricultural sector gain significantly by paying the producers the Crow gap? What sectors would gain and what sectors would lose? Or would they all gain? How much of the Crow gap would be paid as compensation to farmers for giving up the Crow subsidy? Full compensation, or partial compensation? Would the payment of compensation make any difference on resource allocation? This paper discusses input subsidies in general within the context of neo-classical welfare economics. This theory is then used to discuss farmer compensation and impacts from under the removal of the Crow transportation subsidy. Even in the absence of compensation, some sectors were made better off with the removal of the Crow subsidy. The compensation needed to satisfy either the Pareto or compensation principles depends on whether or not the payment for the removal of the Crow subsidy is decoupled from producers production decisions. 3

Crow Subsidy Removal Historically, the Canadian federal government has been involved with both the subsidization of grain moved by rail to an export position, as well as the monitoring of freight rates charged by railways for shipping grain. The Crow freight rate subsidy had been a part of farming in Western Canada since 1897 (Canadian Transportation Act, 1996). In that year, Canadian Pacific received a $3.4 million subsidy from the federal government and in exchange the railway-company agreed to set a maximum freight rate for shipping grain off the prairies in perpetuity. These freight rates were extended to all railways and all western grain movement by law in 1925. This statutory requirement forced the railways to move grain for a set rate indefinitely (Khakbazan and Gray, 1997). Overtime the costs associated with the transportation of grain rose with inflation and the two dominant railway companies that existed in Western Canada began to incur losses. By the 1970 s the rate railways were forced to charge for moving grain was far below its costs of doing so. In 1977 only 32% of variable costs were covered by users, 18% by federal branch line subsidies and the remaining 50% was left to the railroad as loss. As a result, the railway companies had an incentive to slow down maintenance on Prairie branch lines. A lack of equipment capacity to move grain to port became severe during the 1970 s and led to major delays and a lack of capacity in the grain handling system. Demand for wheat exceeded the grain transportation capacity and grain sales were lost. As a result of the crisis, the Government of Canada along with Provinces of Saskatchewan and Alberta became involved in the grain transportation industry by providing new hopper-bottomed cars to the railways, in order to improve their grain handling capacity (Khakbazan and Gray, 1997). 4

In 1983, the Western Grain Transportation Act was introduced in an attempt to increase capacity in the grain transportation sector as well as to prevent the railways from exercising monopoly power over farmers shipping grain by rail. Under the WGTA, the Canadian government paid railways the difference between the railways costs of moving grain and the freight rates paid by farmers moving grain from interior points to Vancouver for export purposes and to Thunder Bay for export and domestic purposes. Subsidy levels were adjusted annually, and a volume cap applied to total subsidy outlays (Khakbazan and Gray, 1997). Overtime the WGTA was intended to transfer the responsibility of the costs of transportation from the government to the grain producers. However, lower than anticipated inflation since 1983 resulted in the government still being responsible for a significant subsidy to the railways well into the 1990 s (Khakbazan and Gray, 1997). On February 27, 1995, the Federal Government announced the demise of the WGTA. The proposed reform would no longer provide the WGTA to the railroads and a one time capital payment of 1.6 billion dollars was made to landowners as compensation for the loss of the WGTA. These producers were then deemed responsible for paying the full costs of shipping their grain by rail. A maximum freight rate was established and left in place until August 1, 2001, which limited the amount railways could charge for the movement of a tonne of grain. Transportation costs for grain farmers on the prairies increased substantially in the 1995/96 crop year due to the elimination of the WGTA (Coghill, 1998). For example, the freight cost for moving barley out of Saskatchewan more than triples after the Crow subsidy was removed (Figure 1). The result for grain farmers was that the net price received for their grains was lower than it would have been if the WGTA were still in 5

place. This change in the net price of grains shipped by rail, also altered the price ratio that previously existed between cattle and grain (Coghill, 1998). A vital question for prairie economy farmers was how the removal of the WGTA (which was a capital input subsidy for grain production) would affect future production decisions, given that farmers would now be facing a different set of prices for the goods they had been producing. Inputs Taxes and Subsidies In Figure 2(a) we depict the standard Edgeworth box. The agricultural sector is endowed with L 0 of labour and K 0 of capital. The grains sector (G) is assumed to be capital intensive, while the beef sector (R) is assumed to be labour intensive. Under constant returns-of-scale technology, the corresponding production frontier is given in Figure 2(b) as (P 0 P 0 ). Given relative prices P R /P G, grain output is G' while beef production is R'. A tax on inputs shifts the production possibility curve inward to PP. In Figure 2(a), x represents a point on the production surface in the absence of taxes, where y represents a point when factor market distortions are introduced through taxes. A tax on inputs creates a distortion referred to in the literature as a type II distortion. Now the introduction of an input subsidy, rather than a tax, essentially expands the Edgeworth box outwards. If the subsidy is on capital, as was the case with the Crow subsidy, then the Edgeworth box expands outward from the addition of capital denoted as K' in Figure 2(a). The agricultural production frontier shifts outward to P'P'. As a result of the input subsidy, if the relative price P R /P G (now represented by P R /P G ') remains unchanged, the output of the labour intensive industry (B) decreases absolutely (from B' to B 0 ), following the Rybczynski theorem, while the output of the capital intensive sector (G) increases absolutely (from G' to G 0 ). 6

Eliminating Input Subsidies Complete Subsidy Removal and Partial Adjustments Consider the case in Figure 3 where the Crow subsidy is completely eliminated, and producers are not compensated. That is, under pay-the-producer approach, the payout from the federal government is zero. Initially, production of grain is G, and beef production is R. (The corresponding price line is P R /P G and the Scitovsky indifference curve is C 1.) When the Crow input subsidy is removed, the production possibility curve shifts from P P to P'P'. Assume for the moment that relative product prices do not change as a result of removing the Crow subsidy. Thus, the price line P R /P G is parallel to P R '/P G. Applying the Rybczynski theorem, the new equilibrium would be where production of grain is G', and the production of red meats is R'. (There is an absolute reduction in the quantity produced of the capital intensive good, and an absolute increase in the quantity produced of the labour intensive good.) If this were the new equilibrium point, then the aggregate welfare of both grain and cattle producers would be reduced. One of the arguments for removing the Crow subsidy was that by paying it to the railroads, relative product prices were distorted in favour of the grain sector (Coghill, 1997). This was because since full transportation costs were not paid by producers, major importers such as China paid lower prices for imports than would otherwise be the case. Therefore, to model the removal of the Crow, one has to take into account that the removal of the Crow resulted in a significant change in the relative prices of grains and the red meat sector, as grain producers have to pay the full transportation costs (Rosaasen and Schmitz 1985). 7

The new relative price line from the removal of the Crow, as shown in Figure 3, is P 0 R /P G. The corresponding production amounts are G 0 and R 0. Interestingly, at x, welfare of livestock producers is increased, but the welfare of grain producers is decreased. This is a strong conclusion, because to this point we have assumed zero compensation to producers under pay-the-producer approach. How realistic is the above partial adjustment solution from an empirical perspective? The data suggests that there has been very little adjustment out of grains into the livestock sector as a result of the Crow change. In fact, between 1995 and 2000, the number of beef cattle produced on the prairies declined (Figure 4), even though cattle prices increased relative to wheat prices (Table 1). Full adjustment takes time, as adjustments are not costless. Starting at the partial adjustment solution, point t in Figure 3, one could visualize the production process as eventually moving from t to x. This move would result in an absolute welfare improvement to the agricultural sector, given that a distortion exists at t, given the full adjustment price line of P 0 R /P G. From a theoretical perspective, it is possible that without compensation relative prices could move in favour of the grain sector. This is because of the nature of the production possibility curve shift, given that the grain sector is capital intensive. The absolute reduction in grain production with the Crow removal is greater than the absolute reduction in beef production. In this case, grain production is G * and cattle production is R *. Note that now both sectors become absolutely worse off due to the removal of the Crow. (However, the empirical evidence suggests that cattle prices increased relative to grain prices, as seen in Table 1 above. Cattle prices doubled between 1996 and 2001, while grain prices fell by over 30 percent.) 8

Compensation Under Coupled Programs Consider now the case where producers were compensated by the amount of the Crow gap, under the pay-the-producer approach where the amount of the subsidy was equal to that paid by the government to the railways. In this particular case, capital is added back into the Edgeworth box, such that the production possibility curve under pay-theproducer approach becomes PP (Figure 5). This would be the case when subsidy payments and producer decisions are coupled. Note that in Figure 5, in the absence of compensation and/or total decoupling, output is G' and R'. Under compensation, the new equilibrium is at G 0, R 0 (using the Rybczynski theorem). (The equilibrium quantities would likely be to the left of e but to the right of e'.) At the equilibrium point, e, grain producers are worse off and livestock producers are made better off under a pay-theproducer approach, even though the amount of capital in the industry remains unchanged under a pay-the-producer approach. Why this result? Grain producers are made worse off because of the change in relative prices, which no longer favour grain producers (relative price shifts from P R /P G to P R '/P G ). Pay-the-producer yields product prices which are neutral, whereas under pay-the-railroads, prices favour grain producers, because the subsidy is applied to transportation (Cogill 1997). If relative product prices did not change, adherence to the Pareto principle is not possible unless producers are compensated by more than the amount that the railroads received under a pay-the-railroad approach. Added Compensation and Pareto Improvements Figure 6 demonstrates that for everyone to be better off from the pay-the-producer approach, the federal government would have to pay an amount greater than the subsidy 9

that was paid under the pay-the-railroad approach. The original production possibility frontier, when the subsidy payments are equal, is given by PP. Additional capital, through subsidization, expands the production frontier P 0 P 0 ; however, whether this represents a Pareto improvement depends on the relative product prices. To make both sectors better off, or at least one sector better off and the other no worse off, the production frontier has to expand to the northeast of point a. If the Crow change gave rise to P R */ PG, then both sectors would be better off. If, however, the relative price after the Crow change is P 0 R / PG, then the compensation is still inadequate to make both sectors better off. Clearly, the magnitude of the compensation needed, for there to be a Pareto improvement, depends on the size of the product price distortion introduced by providing a transportation subsidy through a pay-the-railroad approach. But the amount of compensation needed, if the Pareto principle were used as the basis for policy change, would have to be greater in dollar amounts than that given to the railroads when the Crow gap was paid to them. Subsidy Payments with Decoupling Up to now we have assumed that either producers received no compensation when the Crow was removed or that producers were compensated but these payments were not decoupled from production. What if payments under the pay-the-producer approach were totally decoupled? The producer payments required to satisfy the Pareto principle, when input subsidies are removed, would be generally less if such payments were decoupled from production decisions. This is especially true if the situation where payments were not decoupled resulted in inefficient resource use. In Figure 6, for example, the welfare level C could be achieved with less compensation if in fact this compensation were not 10

decoupled from the production surface. In this case, the production surface would be the shrunken production surface P'P' in Figure 5. Empirical Assessment The following focuses on the degree to which farmers were compensated under the paythe-producer approach. The so called Crow payout of roughly $1.6 billion in 1996 was not nearly enough to satisfy the Pareto principle if it were used as a criterion for policymaking, nor was the payment sufficient to meet the compensation principle. Political and economic arguments are given as to why the federal government was able to remove the Crow subsidy with relatively little compensation to producers. Compensation and the Pareto Principle The Crow payment made in 1996 totaled roughly $1.6 billion. Prior to 1966, the yearly government payments to the railways averaged $704.9 from 1985 to 1995 (Table 2). Table 3 gives the present value of future payments under pay-the-railway approach, and compares this to the roughly $1.6 billion payout under pay-the-producer approach. Under the latter system, the numbers are quite staggering (assuming that producers would have received full compensation). At a discount rate of 5 percent, producers would have received $24.5 billion instead of the roughly $1.6 billion they actually received. Under a discount rate of 10 percent, the payment would have been $44.4 billion. Clearly, the removal of the Crow subsidy, regardless of whether or not the program was decoupled, resulted in some farmers being made worse off. In view of the theoretical discussion, removing the Crow subsidy greatly shrunk the size of the Edgeworth box because of the withdrawal of capital from the agricultural sector. 11

Politics and Economics There were at least five major factors as to why producers did not receive anywhere near full compensation for the removal of the Crow subsidy. First, net farm income reached a near-record high in 1996. Second, lobbying groups did not have a united front in supporting one or the other policy choice. Third, the federal deficit was large and growing. Fourth, the West generally does not support the federal Liberal government. And fifth, there was increasing pressure from the WTO to have the Crow subsidy removed. Net farm income in Saskatchewan reached close to a record level in 1996 (Table 4). The 1995-1996 average income was sufficiently high such that producers paid little attention to what impact the Crow removal would have. Removing the Crow at this time would have little negative political fallout. In fact, the political climate was such that given the large federal deficit, any move to reduce it would be received favourably. Also, removing the Crow subsidy was looked at favourably by the WTO. From a political economy perspective, it is little wonder that producers received little compensation, given the disagreements among special interests over the Crow payments. Table 4 lists some of the lobbying groups that favoured the pay-the-railway approach. These included the Saskatchewan Wheat Pool, the National Farmers Union, and the Saskatchewan Government. Those who favoured paying the producers included the United Grain Growers, the Alberta Cattle Commission, and the Alberta Barley Growers Association. Given these different, opposing positions, it was easy for the Federal Government to choose the pay-the-producer approach but with limited compensation. It was not until the late 1990s that producers began to realize, in the 12

presence of falling and low farm incomes, that they had been had. (Based on the theoretical discussion, one can question why a united front was not presented by the various interest groups; the magnitude of compensation could have been the key ingredient enabling these groups to form a united coalition. Producer groups essentially stated their positions without knowing what the actual compensation would be.) Based on public choice economics, there is another important component to the policy decision regarding how to pay the Crow subsidy. Since the West generally does not support the federal Liberal government, which was in power when the Crow decision was made, why would the federal government dole out more money if they could not garner any votes by doing so? Schmitz, Furtan, and Baylis (2002), using public choice theory and rent-seeking behaviour models, find that the Crow decision was predictable. Conclusions This paper has focused on the impact of input subsides on resource allocation and the impact when such subsidies are removed. Often, compensation comes into play once input subsidies are removed, since some sectors of the economy are made worse off. In our empirical assessment of the landmark Crow transportation subsidy case, producers were not sufficiently compensated under the pay-the-producer approach if one were to use the Pareto principle as the basis for policy decisions. We present economic and political arguments as to why this was the case. Even so, some sectors gained while others lost as a result of the Crow removal. Full compensation to make no one worse off and at least one person better off (the Pareto criterion) would have required federal payments several times larger than what farmers actually received. If producer compensation is not decoupled from production, then the compensation under a pay-the- 13

producer approach required more money than under a pay-the-railroad approach. Factor market distortions introduced by the Crow caused relative product prices to change in favour of the livestock sector once the Crow was removed. This had to be accounted for when assessing the impact of removing the Crow. Under the pay-the-railway approach, producers had to grow grain before they could receive the transportation subsidy. Under pay-the-producer, the limited payments made were not tied to production. Further work is needed to determine if indeed such payments are decoupled. Under the WTO, policies fitting the green box are alleged to be decoupled. The Crow payment to producers fits the green box category according to the WTO. However, from a dynamic perspective, it is not easy to determine empirically whether certain programs are green or not. Given the high farm incomes in 1995 and 1996, likely a considerable amount of the Crow payout was not used at that time by producers for production purposes, but as time went on and farm incomes fell, this so called Crow cash likely was used to meet debt payments and the like (Shalit and Schmitz 1982). It is our hypothesis that totally decoupling farm payments from production is highly unlikely, regardless of the nature of the farm program. 14

References Coghill, Gary, J. 1997. The Economic Production Potential of the Cow-Calf Herd in Saskatchewan. M. Sc. Thesis. University of Saskatchewan, Saskatoon, Saskatchewan. Fowke, V.C. The National Policy and the Wheat Economy. Toronto: University of Toronto Press, 1957. Just, R., D. Hueth, and A. Schmitz. Applied Welfare Economics and Public Policy. New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1982. Khakbazan, M. and Gray, R. 1997. A case study of Branch Line Abandonment in West Central Saskatchewan. Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Saskatchewan. Saskatoon, SK. Markusen, J.R., J.R. Melvin, W.H. Kaempler, and K. E. Maskus. 1995. International Trade: Theory and Evidence. New York: McGraw Hill. Rosaasen, K. and A. Schmitz. 1985. Influence of Feed Grain Freight Rates on the Red Meats Industry in the Prairie Provinces. A study prepared for the Hall Committee of Inquiry on Method of Payment, Government of Canada. (February) Rybczynski, T.M. 1968. Factor Endowment and Relative Commodity Prices. Readings in International Economics. American Economic Association. Homewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc. 72-77. Schmitz, A., H. Furtan, and K. Baylis. 2002. Agricultural Policy, Agribusiness, and Rent-Seeking Behaviour. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. 15

Schmitz, A., T. Schmitz, and C. Dumas. Gains from Trade, Inefficiency of Government Programs, and the Net Economic Effects of Trading. Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 105, No. 3 (1997): 637-647. Shalit, H. and A. Schmitz. 1982. Farmland Accumulation and Prices. American Journal of Agricultural Economics. Vol. 64, No. 4 (November): 710-719. 16

Table 1. Feeder Calf Prices and Grain Prices Received by Saskatchewan Farmers (1990-2001) Year 1 Feeder Price 2 Wheat Price Year Feeder Price Wheat Price $/lb. $/tonne $/lb. $/tonne 1990 110 152 1996 81 214 1991 115 115 1997 111 159 1992 109 113 1998 119 149 1993 128 119 1999 131 150 1994 129 119 2000 153 126 1995 108 167 2001 160 136 1 For wheat, 1990 represents the crop-year 1989-90 (etc.). 2 Price quoted for 500-600lb. animals. Source: Statistics Canada and Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food. Table 2: WGTA Payments and Grain Tonnages by Crop Year (1985/86-1994/95) Crop Year Nominal Payments * Real CPI Real Payments Grain Shipments ('000,000) ('000,000) (Tonnes) 1985/86 625.90 1.33 834.90 27,610,000.000 1986/87 906.10 1.28 1160.18 35,323,513.977 1987/88 825.90 1.23 1013.48 35,043,416.437 1988/89 555.80 1.18 655.49 23,265,253.575 1989/90 702.00 1.12 788.47 30,222,132.913 1990/91 728.90 1.07 781.52 34,551,823.330 1991/92 796.10 1.02 808.15 36,426,523.410 1992/93 687.00 1.00 687.17 31,444,710.148 1993/94 634.90 0.98 623.47 32,645,846.913 1994/95 586.00 0.98 574.51 36,489,762.097 Indexed into 1992 dollars. * The freight rate increase became effective on August 1, 1995. Nominal Payments Obtained from CTA (2001). 17

Table 3: Compensation Payments from Crow Removal (Various Discount Rates) Discount Rate (percent) Crow Payment (billion $) 2.5 18.46 5.0 24.47 10.0 44.41 Based on average payments received by the railroads between 1985 and 1994 of $704.86 million. Table 4: Total Net Income of Saskatchewan Farm Operations (1971-2000) Year Total Net Income Year Total Net Income ('000) ('000) 1971 438,148 1986 1,184,998 1972 366,645 1987 601,238 1973 869,754 1988-21,576 1974 1,116,758 1989 1,126,165 1975 1,450,345 1990 1,076,952 1976 1,189,697 1991 477,051 1977 749,186 1992 419,412 1978 816,993 1993 961,094 1979 733,210 1994 799,091 1980 572,940 1995 958,571 1981 1,479,376 1996 1,358,614 1982 981,137 1997 187,770 1983 428,239 1998 488,469 1984 136,024 1999 604,687 1985 680,949 2000 422,200 Source: Statistics Canada and Saskatchewan Agriculture and Food. 18

Table 5: Policy Position on the Crow Change Pay the Producer Approach Pay the Railways Approach Alberta Cattle Commission Canadian National Alberta Grain Commission Canadian Pacific Railway Western Wheat Growers Saskatchewan Wheat Pool Alberta Barley Growers Alberta Wheat Pool Canadian Canola Growers Assoc. Manitoba Wheat Pool Canadian Flax Growers Assoc. Saskatchewan Government Saskatchewan Stock Growers Assoc. National Farmers Union Saskatchewan Cattle Feeders Assoc. United Grain Growers 19

50.00 40.00 30.00 20.00 10.00 0.00 72-73 74-75 76-77 78-79 80-81 82-83 84-85 86-87 88-89 90-91 92-93 $/tonne 94-95 96-97 98-99 00-01 Year freight rate for feed barley basis Norquay Figure 1 Real Freight Rate for Feed Barley, Basis Norquay, Saskatchewan, Canada Sources: Canadian Wheat Board Archives, (Various Years) 1 ; Rosaasen and Schmitz, (1985) 2 1 Nominal freight rates obtained for 1983-84 to 2000-01 were then indexed according to consumer price index published by the Statistic Canada Web Site (2001) 2 Nominal freight rates obtained for 1972-73 to 1982-83 which were then indexed according to consumer price index published by the Statistics Canada Web Site (2001) 20

R R'' Factor L L 0 y x K 0 K' G Product G P' G 0 Factor K Figure 2(a) P R /P G ' G' P R /P G Input subsidy (K' of capital) Factor market distortion (tax) (PP) No input tax or subsidy (P 0 P 0 ) R 0 R' P' Figure 2(b) Figure 2 Input Taxes and Subsidies Product R 21

( G ) P G G * G' P' P R '/P G C 2 t P R 0 /P G C 1 P R /P G C 2 ' C 3 G 0 x R * P ' P R R ' R 0 ( R ) Figure 3 Complete Subsidy Removal and Partial Adjustments 22

Number of Head ('000) 4500 4000 3500 3000 2500 2000 1500 1000 500 0 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 Year Alberta Saskatchewan Manitoba Source: Statistics Canada-Cal.no. 23-603-UPE Figure 4. Total Inventory on Cow-Calf Operations in Alberta, Saskatchewan and Manitoba on July 1: 1995 to 2000 23

G P P R /P G e' C 1 G 0 P' e C 2 P R ' /P G G 1 C 3 P R 0 /P G P' P R 0 R 1 R Figure 5 Compensation Under Coupled Programs 24

G P 0 P R * /P G P P R /P G C 1 G a C 3 C 2 P R 0 /P G P P 0 R R Figure 6 Added Compensation and Pareto Improvements 25