Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money

Similar documents
After studying this chapter you will be able to

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Money and internal specialization

Imperfect Competition

Problem Set #2 - Answers. Due February 2, 2000

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract

Chapter 1 Introduction to Pricing Techniques

The Model of Perfect Competition

2.1 Economic Questions

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

This is a refereed journal and all articles are professionally screened and reviewed

Things people like and desire.

2010 Pearson Education Canada

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

Monetary Policy and Distribution

Welfare Economics. Philip A. Viton. May 17, Philip A. Viton CRP 781 () Welfare May 17, / 1

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

Models of Creative Destruction (Quality Ladders)

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

Economics 101. Chris Gan July Economics 101 1

MICRO-ECONOMIC THEORY I STUDY NOTES CHAPTER ONE

Industrial Organization

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

WEEK 4: Economics: Foundations and Models

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

Journal of Industrial Organization Education. Third-Degree Price Discrimination

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

ECON 500 Microeconomic Theory MARKET FAILURES. Asymmetric Information Externalities Public Goods

Chapter 11. Decision Making and Relevant Information Linear Programming as a Decision Facilitating Tool

Thursday, October 13: Short and Long Run Equilibria

Psychology and Economics Field Exam August 2015

. This function gives the supplier s behavior with respect to price and quantity.

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

HIERARCHICAL decision making problems arise naturally

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

IB Economics Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply 1.4: Price Signals and Market Efficiency

2007 Thomson South-Western

Supply and Demand: CHAPTER Theory

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

1.1 Efficiency in economics What is efficiency in economics?

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. FIGURE 1-2

CHAPTER 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

The Efficient Allocation of Individuals to Positions

PCP (2017): Environmental Economic Theory, No. 1 Benefits and Costs, Supply and Demand

Attribute Theory of Consumer Behavior

7-1: PERFECT COMPETITION NOTES

Chapter 2 Market forces: Demand and Supply Demand

Working Paper No Can By-product Lobbying Firms Compete? Paul Pecorino

CHAPTER 5 SOCIAL WELFARE MAXIMIZATION FOR HYBRID MARKET

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Consumers, Producers, and the Efficiency of Markets. Premium PowerPoint Slides by Vance Ginn & Ron Cronovich

Perfectly competitive markets: Efficiency and distribution

Section 1: Neoclassical welfare economics

The Management of Marketing Profit: An Investment Perspective

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

- Scarcity leads to tradeoffs - Normative statements=opinion - Positive statement=fact with evidence - An economic model is tested by comparing its

Externalities and the Environment

Competitive Markets. Jeffrey Ely. January 13, This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial-ShareAlike 3.0 License.

Calculating consumer s surplus and the change in consumer s surplus Calculating compensating and equivalent variations

Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Bilateral and Multilateral Exchanges for Peer-Assisted Content Distribution

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

1. T F The resources that are available to meet society s needs are scarce.

microeconomics II first module

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

Chapter 5: A Closed-Economy One-Period Macroeconomic Model

Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets

Linear Programming. 1 Goals and Agenda. Management 560: Management Science. Tuesday, March 17, 2009

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

AP Microeconomics Chapter 4 Outline

Principles of Macroeconomics, 11e - TB1 (Case/Fair/Oster) Chapter 2 The Economic Problem: Scarcity and Choice

David Besanko and Ronald Braeutigam. Prepared by Katharine Rockett Dieter Balkenborg. Microeconomics, 2 nd Edition

Price Discrimination: Exercises Part 2

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

2. Which of the following is a distinguishing feature of a market system? A. public ownership of all capital.

Oshoring in a Knowledge Economy

SCHOOL OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE THE UNIVERSITY OF HONG KONG ECON6021 MICROECONOMICS PROBLEM SET NO.3 COMPETITIVE MARKETS AND MONOPOLY

1. Welfare economics is the study of a. the well-being of less fortunate people. b. welfare programs in the United States.

Econ 2113 Test #2 Dr. Rupp Fall 2008

ECONOMICS 103. Dr. Emma Hutchinson, Fall 2017

Ch. 7 outline. 5 principles that underlie consumer behavior

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment

Solutions to Final Exam

Linear Programming. BUS 735: Business Decision Making and Research. Wednesday, November 8, Lecture / Discussion. Worksheet problem.

Transcription:

Chapters 1 and 2 Trade Without Money and A Model of Money Main Aims: 1. Answer following two questions: Why money is used as a medium of exchange? How and why money improves allocations in an economy and social welfare? 2. Develop a simple overlapping generation model (OLG) of money.

Money as a Medium of Exchange Paper or fiat money is intrinsically useless in the sense that they do not directly yield utility and/or cannot be used as input in production. They do however lead to higher consumption/production by facilitating trading in real world. Now the question is what feature of real world leads to use of money as a facilitator of trading processes: Problem of the Double Coincidence of Wants: In the absence of money it is difficult to acquire desired consumption good or input for production or sell goods.

Money as a Medium of Exchange However, mere presence of the problem of double coincidence of wants is not enough. People should be willing to hold money as an asset (store of value). When a buyer buys good from a seller using money, then the seller is left with money which he/she cannot directly consume. The seller can potentially use the money to buy goods in future. Thus, if a seller is wiling to sell his/her good for money, he/she must believe that others will also accept money in exchange for goods in future. A necessary condition for that is that there is always someone who will live in the next period.

Money as a Medium of Exchange Any model of money (in which money emerges as a medium of exchange) incorporates these two necessary conditions: 1. Frictions (difficulty) in trading 2. Infinitely-lived economy 3. Imperfect credit market

Overlapping Generations Model as a Model of Money 1. Highly tractable and can be used to address many monetary and non-monetary issues 2. Provides a natural physical environment in which trading without money is difficult 3. Dynamic models. Anticipated future events affect current decisions

Environment Infinitely-lived economy Economy is populated by people who live for two periods. People in the first period of their life are called young and in the second period of their life old. In each period t 1, N t individuals are born. The economy starts in period 1. The generations born in periods t 1 are called future generations. In addition, in period 1 there are N 0 people born in time 0 called the initial old. In any period (t 1), two generations live- N t young and N t 1 old. Total population at time t is N t + N t 1.

Environment There is only one perishable or non-storable good. Each individual when young receive an endowment of the consumption good equal to y. Old receive nothing. Thus the total availability or supply of good at time t is yn t. Preferences: Each individual would like to consume in both periods of their life. Let c 1,t and and c 2,t+1 denote the consumption of an individual born in time t as a young and as a old respectively. The utility function is given by U(c 1,t, c 2,t+1 ), U 1 &U 2 > 0, U 11 &U 22 < 0 where U 1 and U 2 are partial derivatives of the utility function with respect to c 1,t and c 2,t+1 respectively.

Economic Questions 1. Given the environment (endowments, preferences, population structure), what will be the allocation of good among different generations with or without money? 2. Does the allocation in an economy with money is better than the allocation without money (barter economy)? 3. Does the existence of money leads to the best outcome possible in the given environment?

Economic Questions We will answer the above three questions as follows: 1. First, find out the best outcome possible (Golden Rule Allocation/ Allocation by the central planner). 2. Second, derive the allocation in a barter economy and compare with the golden rule allocation. 3. Third, derive the allocation in an economy with money and compare with the golden rule allocation as well as the allocation in a barter economy.

Golden Rule or Central Planner Allocation Imagine that there exists a central (or social) planner with total knowledge and complete control over economy. Question is what allocation of consumption he/she would choose. In order to answer the above question, we need to know the feasible set of allocations and the objective function or the preference of the planner. We will begin with the feasible set of allocations. The feasible set of allocations consists of all the allocations of consumption goods which are equal to or lower than the total availability of goods.

Feasible Allocations To know feasible allocations, we need to know the total availability/supply of goods and total demand in any period. The total supply in period t is N t y. (1.1) The demand for goods come from young and old individuals at time t. Suppose that each young consume c 1,t amount of good and each old consume c 2,t (symmetric allocation). Then total demand at time t is N t c 1,t + N t 1 c 2,t. (1.2)

Feasible Allocations The set of feasible allocations are given by all the combinations of c 1,t and c 2,t such that N t c 1,t + N t 1 c 2,t N t y. (1.3) (1.3) is also known as the feasibility constraint. If we assume that population is constant, N t = N, t, then (1.3) can be written as c 1,t + c 2,t y. (1.4) If we further assume that consumption is stationary i.e., each generation has same consumption pattern, c 1,t = c 1, and c 2,t = c 2 t, then the set of feasible allocations is given by c 1, c 2 such that c 1 + c 2 y. (1.5)

Objective Function of the Planner Assume that the central/social planner wants to maximize the utility of future generations (not of initial old). Given feasible allocations and the objective function, now we can derive the optimal allocations chosen by the planner. Such an allocation is known as the Golden Rule Allocation. Focussing on symmetric and stationary allocations, the planner problem reduces to subject to the feasibility constraint (1.5). max c1,c 2 U(c 1, c 2 ) (1.6)

Golden Rule Allocation The golden rule allocation can be derived as follows. Since the utility is strictly increasing in consumption, (1.5) will be binding. c 1 + c 2 = y. (1.7) Putting (1.7) in the objective function (1.6), the optimization problem reduces to The first order condition is max c 1 U(c 1, y c 1 ). (1.8) U 1 = U 2 (1.9) which implies that allocation will be such as to equate the marginal utility of consumption across two periods. (1.7) and (1.9) together give the golden rule allocation {c 1, c 2 }.

Market/Decentralized Allocations Now we consider allocations achieved when individual agents interact with each other and take their own decisions. First, we consider allocations in the barter economy and then in an economy with money. Before we do so, we need to make some assumptions regarding the behavior of individuals and the market structure and define the notion of equilibrium. These are given below:

Competitive Equilibrium A competitive equilibrium has following properties: 1. Individuals maximize their utilities subject to their budget constraints. 2. They take prices as given. 3. Supply equals demand in each market i.e., markets clear. We are going to find allocations which satisfy the above three conditions. Allocations and prices which satisfy these conditions constitute the competitive equilibrium.

Equilibrium in a Barter Economy In the economy, individual agents decide how much to consume when they are young and how much when they are old. Notice that old do not have any endowment. Also no young individual can save in order to finance his/her consumption for old age, as goods are perishable. Thus old can consume if they can trade with the young. But will any young would trade with old? Answer is NO! An old has no endowment and thus cannot give a young anything in exchange. A young will also not sell good to an old on credit, because the old will not be alive next period to repay. There will be no trade among young because they are all identical. Thus in a barter economy there will be no trade (autarky). Young will consume their endowment, and old will consume nothing i.e., c 1 = y, c 2 = 0. Since, individuals would like to consume in both parts of their lives, they are worse-off compared to the golden rule allocation.

Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy Now we consider equilibrium in a monetary economy. Suppose that the government/central bank introduces M units of fiat money in the economy. Fiat money has following characteristics: 1. They are intrinsically useless. In other words, they do not directly serve as an object of consumption or input for production. 2. They are (nearly) costless to produce. 3. They cannot be counterfeited.

Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy A monetary equilibrium is a competitive equilibrium in which (fiat) money is valued or have purchasing power. Given the characteristics of fiat money, it will be valued only if it enables individuals to trade for something they want to consume. As discussed earlier, there can potentially be trade between the young and the old. But given the age structure of the population such trades do not take place in the barter economy. The question of whether money will be valued reduces to whether it can facilitate trade between the young and the old. In other words, will a young in the current period give up part of his/her endowment in exchange for money?

Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy To answer the above question, assume that at time 1, the government/central banker distributes M units of fiat money equally among the initial old. Thus, each initial old has M N units of money. In this economy, young individuals can sell part of their endowment to old individuals for money in the current period and then buy consumptions goods next period using money. If such exchanges are possible, then each generation can consume in both parts of their lives - young and old and attain higher utility.

Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy For such exchanges to be possible two conditions are necessary: 1. Supply of fiat money should be limited. 2. Young in each period must believe that next period money will be valuable. If in any period T, young believe that money will be not valuable next period, it will be worthless not only in time T but all the previous periods.

Equilibrium in a Monetary Economy With the above comments in the background, we are in a position to derive allocations and prices in the monetary economy. First, we will derive optimal choices made by individuals. Then, we will derive prices implied by the interactions among different individuals. Let p t be the price of the consumption good. The purchasing power of one unit of money, v t, is defined as v t = 1 p t. (1.10)

Optimal Choices We will analyze optimal choices of individuals under the assumption that money is valued. Then, we will show that it is indeed the case in equilibrium. Any individual makes three choices: c 1,t, c 2,t+1, m t, where m t is the amount of money acquired in period t. We assume that these choices are made to maximize the utility of the individual. max U(c 1,t, c 2,t+1 ). (1.11) c 1,t,c 2,t+1,m t

Optimal Choices These choices are made subject to the individual budget constraints. The budget constraint in period t is c 1,t + v t m t y (1.12) where v t m t is the units of endowment sold. The budget constraint in period t + 1 is c 2,t+1 v t+1 m t. (1.13) We can combine (1.12) and (1.13) and derive an individual s life-time budget constraint [ ] vt c 1,t + c 2,t+1 y. (1.14) v t+1

Optimal Choices An individual s problem is subject to max U(c 1,t, c 2,t+1 ). (1.15) c 1,t,c 2,t+1 [ ] vt c 1,t + c 2,t+1 y. (1.16) v t+1 While making optimal choices, the individual takes value of money (or prices) v t, v t+1 as given.

Optimal Choices Given the assumptions regarding the utility function, the budget constraints (1.12) and (1.13) will be binding. We can put the budget constraints in the objective function (1.15). The problem now becomes The first order condition is max m t U(y v t m t, v t+1 m t ). (1.17) U 1 (y v t m t, v t+1 m t ) U 2 (y v t m t, v t+1 m t ) = v t+1 v t. (1.18) (1.18) equates the marginal rate of substitution between the first and the second period consumption to the ratio of the value of money between the second and the first period.

Optimal Choices The ratio of the value of money between the second and the first period v t+1 v t can be interpreted as the real rate of return of money. By accepting one unit of money in period t, an individual forgoes the opportunity to consume v t units of good. But by using money, the individual acquires v t+1 units of consumption good next period. Thus the pay-off for holding money is v t+1 units of consumption good. In general, one can derive (gross) rate of return on any asset by using the following formula Rate of Return = Pay off Price of the Asset.

Optimal Choices Using (1.18) together with (1.12) and (1.13), we can derive the optimal choices of an individual, c 1,t, c 2,t+1, m t. However, they will be functions of the value of money v t, v t+1, which are yet unknown. In order to find v t, v t+1, we turn to market clearing condition. The market clearing condition for money is that the demand for money should equal its supply.

Rate of Return on Money The supply of money is equal to M t. What is the demand? The demand for money comes from young who would like to sell some of their endowments to the old. The demand is N t m t. Thus market clearing requires that M t = N t m t. (1.19) Using the budget constraint of the first period (1.12), we can derive the expression for v t as Similarly, v t = N t(y c 1,t ) M t. (1.20) v t+1 = N t+1(y c 1,t+1 ) M t+1. (1.21)

Rate of Return on Money Using (1.20) and (1.21), we can derive the (real) rate of return on money v t+1 v t = N t+1 (y c 1,t+1 ) M t+1 N t (y c 1,t ). (1.22) M t In the stationary environment where c 1,t = c 1 and c 2,t = c 2, the (real) rate of return on money is v t+1 v t = N t+1 M t+1 N t. (1.23) M t If we assume constant population N t = N t+1 = N and constant money supply M t = M t+1 = M, then the above expression simplifies to v t+1 v t = 1 (1.24) implying constant value of money.

Competitive Monetary Equilibrium Competitive Monetary Equilibrium consists of optimal choices c 1,t, c 2,t+1, m t characterized by (1.12), (1.13), and (1.18), the real rate of return ( v t+1 v t ) given by (1.22), and the goods market clearing condition c 1,t + c 2,t = y. The Quantity Theory of Money: (1.20) implies that in the stationary environment price level, p t is given by p t = 1 v t = M N(y c 1 ). (1.25) The above equation shows that price level is proportional to the money stock, which is known as the quantity theory of money. A once for all increase in the money stock (M), just affects the price and not the allocations. In such case, money is said to be neutral.

Monetary Equilibrium and the Golden Rule Allocation Recall that the golden rule allocation is given by (1.9) U 1 (c 1 ) U 2 (c 2 ) = 1 (1.26) and the resource constraints (1.7). With constant population and money supply, allocations in the monetary equilibrium are also characterized by same equations (just put 1.24 in 1.18 and use budget constraints). Thus the competitive monetary equilibrium achieves the golden rule allocation.

Introduction of Population Growth Suppose now that population is growing at the constant growth rate, n. Thus N t = nn t 1. (1.27) Rest of the environment remains the same. Now we want to find out the golden rule allocation and the monetary equilibrium. The set of feasible allocations is given by N t c 1 + N t 1 c 2 N t y (1.28) which simplifies to c 1 + [ ] 1 c 2 y. (1.29) n

The Golden Rule Allocation The golden rule allocation can be found by solving the following problem: subject to (1.29). The first order condition is max U(c 1, c 2 ) (1.30) c 1,c 2 U 1 (c 1 ) = n. (1.31) U 2 (c 2 ) The central/social planner equates the marginal rate of substitution between the current and the future consumption to the growth rate of population. (1.31) together with (1.29) give the golden rule allocation.

The Competitive Monetary Equilibrium An individual faces the same problem as he/she did in an economy without population growth. Thus the optimal choices continue to be characterized by (1.12), (1.13), and (1.18). Only thing changes is the real rate of return on money v t+1 v t. (1.23) implies that v t+1 v t = n. (1.32) (1.12), (1.13), (1.18), and (1.32) imply that allocations in the monetary equilibrium are identical to the golden rule allocation.