Groundwater Economics without Equations

Similar documents
Department of Natural Resources and Environmental Management University of Hawaii at Manoa

DISCOUNTING AND SUSTAINABILITY JOHN QUIGGIN DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS, RESEARCH SCHOOL OF SOCIAL SCIENCES AUSTRALIAN NATIONAL UNIVERSITY

UNESCO EOLSS. The various methods available for the treating and disposing of treated sewerage in natural receiving water bodies are outlined.

DISCUSSION PAPER INTEGRATED WATER RESOURCES MANAGEMENT IN ISRAEL

Issue paper: Aquifer Water Balance

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

WATER RESOURCES MANAGEMENT Vol. I - Economic Valuation of Water - Peter Philips Rogers, Ramesh Bhatia and Annette Huber

How Do Environmental and Natural Resource Economics Texts Deal With the Simple Model of the Intertemporal Allocation of a Nonrenewable Resource?

CHAPTER 2. Objectives of Groundwater Modelling

Palestinian Water Sector Capacity Building

Overview and highlights

Model objectives. Main features. Water Evaluation And Planning (WEAP)

National Water Demand Management Policy

CURRICULUM VITA James A. Roumasset Department of Economics University of Hawaii Honolulu, Hawaii

Lecture 1 Integrated water resources management and wetlands

WATER FROM THE CLOUDS

Transient and Succession-of-Steady-States Pipeline Flow Models

Chapter 6. Depletable Resource Allocation: The Role of Longer Time Horizons, Substitutes, and Extraction Cost

Sustainability Definitions 2013 ENVIRONIC FOUNDATION INTERNATIONAL

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

POTABLE WATER ELEMENT

Boom Before Bust? The Industrial Organization of Groundwater

Water Account, Mauritius 2013

Progress Report. August 2000 Report No Purpose. 1 Section 11.45(7)(f), F.S. 2 Review of the Reuse of Reclaimed Water, OPPAGA Report

Externalities, Common Property, and Public Goods. Main topics. What are Externalities? Intermediate Microeconomics. positive.

Review of Saudi Arabia Municipal Water Tariff

Middle East and North Africa

Counterfeiting as Private Money in Mechanism Design

Numerical Simulation of Variabledensity Groundwater Flow: Submarine Groundwater Discharge

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

Guidelines for Preparation of Reuse Feasibility Studies for Applicants Having Responsibility for Wastewater Management. Use it Again, Florida!

Groundwater and Water Resources Management: Knowledge Gap and Research Need

PIMA COUNTY COMPREHENSIVE PLAN CO PIMA COUNTY REGIONAL COMPREHENSIVE PLAN POLICY MAJOR PLAN AMENDMENT

Environmental and Natural Resource Economics: A Contemporary Approach by Jonathan Harris and Brian Roach

Climate Change and the Eastern Mediterranean Precipitation Regime

BAEN 673 / February 18, 2016 Hydrologic Processes

Local, State and Federal Funding Opportunities

Calculating Mitigation

M. Tech Irrigation & Drainage Engineering

Chapter 1. Introduction

Property Rights and Collective Action for Pro-Poor Watershed Management

Water Resources on PEI: an overview and brief discussion of challenges

CONTENTS TABLE OF PART A GLOBAL ENERGY TRENDS PART B SPECIAL FOCUS ON RENEWABLE ENERGY OECD/IEA, 2016 ANNEXES

Date: Tuesday February 25 th, Name: Student #: Multiple Choice (8) Please circle the correct answer. Each question is worth one mark.

Hydrology and Water Management. Dr. Mujahid Khan, UET Peshawar

Hydrological Aspects of Drought

PREPARE60 OVERVIEW 1

Financing Landscape Programs Integrating Different Financing Sources

Wage Floors and Unemployment: A Two-Sector Analysis

ENVIRONMENTAL AND NATURAL RESOURCE ECONOMICS: A CONTEMPORARY APPROACH, 4 th Edition

U.S. Water Budget. Figure Source:Data from The Nation s Water Resources , Vol. 1, U.S. Water Resources Council.

Central Florida has historically utilized

The State of the Colorado River

Stormwater Attenuation Systems Sustainable Drainage Solutions for Domestic & Commercial Applications

The effect of Hilti / Salahi Recharge Dam in Batineh Area, Sultanate of Oman on the Quality of Groundwater Using GIS

Analyzing Accumulated Change Integrals in Action. Improper Integral

Reuse of Reclaimed Water and Florida s Consumptive Use Permit Program The Legal Aspects

The Quest for Long-Term Water Resource Planning

The social and economic aspects of groundwater. indicator. 3.1 SOCIAL AND ECONOMIC RELEVANCE OF GROUNDWATER INDICATORS

The Hydrological Cycle. Hydrological Cycle. Definition of Terms. Soils and Water, Spring Lecture 7, The Hydrological Cycle 1

Developing Metrics & Indicators for the California Water Plan. CA Sustainability Indictors Symposium February 23, 2011

Monopolistic competition, endogenous markups, and growth

CONCLUSIONS OF THE PRESIDENCY OF THE INTERNATIONAL SUMMIT OF ROME ON WATER AND CLIMATE

Liberalization, Investment, and Regulation: The Key Factors for the Development of the Electronic Communications Market

Cumulative Risks of Shale Gas Development

b. Why are measured long-run elasticities larger than measured short-run elasticities?

The surface water hydrology of the site has been logically divided into six phases of monitoring, analyses, and investigation as outlined below:

2017 American Water Works Association

Water Supply Water Quality Water Reuse and Conservation Watershed Management Interagency Coordination

Steady Flow in Confined Aquifer

Desalination Plans to Solve Water Scarcity

Why Desalination? Q A Q A

FEMA s Mitigation Support for Resiliency: Innovative Drought and Flood Mitigation Projects

A Strategic Research and Innovation Agenda for the Water in the EU

Impact of Compaction State and Initial Moisture on Infiltration Characteristic of Soil

NATURAL FEATURES, LAND SUITABILITY FOR DEVELOPMENT AND DEVELOPMENT CONCERNS

A participatory approach for implementing IWRM in Al-Batinah (Oman) Ayisha Mohammed Al Khatri

Watershed: an area or ridge of land that separates waters flowing to different rivers, basins, or seas. It is the interdependent web of living

WHY INVEST IN WATER?

AGEC 604 Natural Resource Economics

15. Soil Salinity SUMMARY THE ISSUE

DRAINAGE FOR AGRICULTURE

Optimizing B2B Pricing One of the Greatest Levers on Profitability

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern:

- A person who directs resources to achieve a stated goal. - The science of making decisions in the presence of scarce resources.

Inefficiencies in Zonal Market Coupling due to Uncertainties in Generation Shift Keys

Water Security for Sustainable Development: The challenge of Scarcity in the Middle East & North Africa

The following words and terms shall have the following meanings unless the context indicates otherwise:

IB Economics Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply 1.4: Price Signals and Market Efficiency

Indicator 6.4.2: Level of water stress: freshwater withdrawal as a proportion of available freshwater resources

Cooperating Graduate Faculty Department of Economics, Department of Natural Resources and Environmental Management University of Hawaii at Manoa

water resources action project, inc.

COMMON PROPERTY RESOURCES AND PUBLIC GOODS Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

What s Your Drought Vulnerability? (Surviving the Drought of )

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Climate change science, knowledge and impacts on water resources in South Asia

PASO ROBLES GROUNDWATER BASIN: WATER SUPPLY FRAMEWORK, HISTORY, AND CURRENT CONDITIONS. CCVT Sustainable Ag Expo.

Rainwater Harvesting and Groundwater Conservation: When Endogenous Heterogeneity Matters

UNIT I ENVIRONMENT, ECOSYSTEMS AND BIODIVERSITY

2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3ez2Y3e

Transcription:

Groundwater Economics without Equations by James A. Roumasset and Christopher A. Wada Working Paper No. 2014-8 June 2014 UNIVERSITY OF HAWAI I AT MANOA 2424 MAILE WAY, ROOM 540 HONOLULU, HAWAI I 96822 WWW.UHERO.HAWAII.EDU WORKING PAPERS ARE PRELIMINARY MATERIALS CIRCULATED TO STIMULATE DISCUSSION AND CRITICAL COMMENT. THE VIEWS EXPRESSED ARE THOSE OF THE INDIVIDUAL AUTHORS.

Groundwater Economics without Equations James Roumasset Department of Economics, University of Hawai i at Mānoa 2424 Maile Way, Saunders 542, Honolulu, HI 96822 jimr@hawaii.edu Christopher A. Wada University of Hawai i Economic Research Organization 2424 Maile Way, Saunders 540, Honolulu, HI 96822 cawada@hawaii.edu Abstract In many parts of the world, irrigation and groundwater consumption are largely dependent on groundwater. Minimizing the adverse effects of water scarcity requires optimal as well as sustainable groundwater management. A common recommendation is to limit groundwater extraction to maximum sustainable yield (MSY). Although the optimal welfare-maximizing path of groundwater extraction converges to MSY in some cases, MSY generates waste in the short and medium term due to ambiguity regarding the transition to the desired long-run stock level and failure to account for the full costs of the resource. However, the price that incentivizes optimal consumption often exceeds the physical costs of extracting and distributing groundwater, which poses a problem for public utilities facing zero excess-revenue constraints. We discuss how the optimal price can be implemented in a revenue-neutral fashion using an increasing block pricing structure. The exposition is non-technical. More advanced references on groundwater resource management are also provided. Keywords: groundwater, sustainability, dynamic optimization, maximum sustainable yield

Groundwater Economics without Equations In many parts of the world, irrigation and groundwater consumption are largely dependent on groundwater. Over time, a typical aquifer, or subsurface layer of water-bearing, porous materials, is recharged naturally from precipitation that infiltrates below ground. It can also be recharged via irrigation return flow, due either to canal leakage or excess applied water not consumed by crops. The cost of withdrawing water is a direct function of lift, which is the distance between the water table and the surface. In some cases, water can also naturally discharge from the aquifer to adjacent water bodies, or in the case of a costal aquifer, into the ocean. The management problem is to determine how much groundwater to withdraw over time. Long before the World Commission on Environment and Development (1987) launched the modern quest for sustainable development, sustainability was a concern to resource managers. A common recommendation was to limit extraction of a renewable resource (e.g., groundwater) to maximum sustainable yield (MSY) the amount of resource regeneration that would occur at the stock level that maximizes resource growth. Harvesting MSY in perpetuity indeed ensures the convergence of the resource stock to the level that maximizes growth, provided that the initial stock is sufficiently high. However, while the MSY management strategy is straightforward, it generates two sources of waste: ambiguity regarding the transition to the desired stock level and failure to account for the full costs of resource use. These shortcomings led to a search for a sequence of groundwater withdrawals over time that maximizes the present value (PV) of a single groundwater aquifer, or system of aquifers. Dynamically efficient or optimal resource management entails selecting the sequence of withdrawals that generates the largest PV of social welfare. The solution describes the optimal

resource stock in the long-run (the steady state) which may or may not coincide with the MSY stock as well as the optimal transition path to get there. MSY may turn out to be eventually optimal in the long-run. Managing a resource is a dynamic problem because the stock changes over time in response to natural growth/decay, as well as anthropogenic extraction/replenishment. In the context of groundwater, the volume of stored water in an aquifer is measured by the head level, or the distance from some reference point to the top of the water table. The head level depends on the amount of recharge to the aquifer; the amount of water extracted for consumption; and the amount of groundwater that discharges from the aquifer naturally, e.g. to the sea. Each component may vary over time, but the resource stock becomes constant in the steady state, wherein extraction is limited to the recharge net of discharge. The optimal steady state head level will depend on a variety of factors, including the aquifer s physical characteristics and the demand for water. When water demand is rising, it may be optimal to gradually draw down the groundwater stock to the MSY level, and thereafter supplement with an alternative water source, such as desalinated brackish water. Since discharge is increasing with the head level (a larger volume of stored water means more pressure and a larger surface area through which groundwater can leak), per-period yield is maximized at the head constraint. Calculating the optimal steady state head level is generally straightforward, but that level will rarely coincide with the initial state of the system. Optimal extraction in each period is determined by pumping until the marginal benefits of water (MB) fall to equal the full marginal cost (FMC) of withdrawal. The history of extraction determines, in turn, the path of the head level as it transitions from its initial state to the optimal long-run target. Since the FMC is determined only after the solution to the dynamic optimization problem is known, one cannot

characterize the extraction and stock paths ex ante. A few general results have been established, however, with respect to time-dependence. For a single resource, if the demand and cost functions are stationary over time, the paths of extraction and head will be monotonic. That is, if the initial head level is above (below) the optimal steady state level, it will fall (rise) smoothly over time until it reaches the target level. If, however, demand is growing over time, a single aquifer should be accumulated initially, then drawn down, and finally stabilized at the optimal steady state level. Social welfare ideally includes not only the consumption benefits and physical extraction costs of the resource, but also non-use benefits and environmental damage costs. Thus, the FMC of resource consumption should include any externality cost (e.g., irrigation-induced salinization of underlying aquifers) and user cost, which is defined as the cost of using the resource today in terms of forgone future benefits. In the case of groundwater, extracting a unit of water today lowers the water table thus increasing stock-dependent extraction costs in all future periods and forgoes capital gains that could be obtained by leaving the resource in situ to be harvested at a later date. The efficiency condition for resource extraction can be obtained by setting the price (P) equal to the FMC, where FMC includes marginal extraction cost, marginal user cost, and marginal externality cost in PV terms. By consuming along their demand curves, resource users will consume until MB is equal to price. The chance that this welfare-maximizing consumption path coincides with MSY is very slim. Inasmuch as the FMC exceeds the physical costs of extraction and distribution, a public utility may not be legally allowed to charge the optimal price. Another complication arises from the fact that a price increase across the board may decrease welfare disproportionately for lower income users. One potential solution that addresses both efficiency and equity is an increasing

block pricing structure (IBP). If consumers respond to prices at the margin, the only requirement for efficiency is that the price for the last unit of water is equal to FMC in every period, i.e. the price can be lower for inframarginal units of water. In the simple case of two price blocks, the first-block price can even be set to zero to ensure that all users can afford water for basic living needs. Any units of water beyond the first block would be priced at FMC. If designed properly, the IBP would induce efficient consumption, while returning would-be surplus revenue to consumers via the free block. In many parts of the world, groundwater is characterized as a common-pool resource. In the limit, it is individually rational for competitive users to deplete the groundwater until MB equals unit extraction cost. In this open-access equilibrium, each user ignores the effect of individual extraction on future value. The surprising result that the potential welfare gain from groundwater management is negligible has come to be known as the Gisser-Sanchez effect. Under certain circumstances, the PV generated by the competitive market solution is almost identical to that generated by the optimal solution. Welfare gains may be larger, however, when one or more of the original model s simplifying assumptions are relaxed, e.g. when extraction costs are non-linear, demand is non-stationary, the discount rate is low, and the aquifer is severely depleted at the outset. Because common pool resources may face overuse by multiple consumers with unrestricted extraction rights, additional governance may be warranted if the gains from governance exceed the costs. The optimal solution may be unattainable when enforcement and information costs are considered. Which of several institutions (e.g. privatization, centralized ownership, and user associations) maximizes the net PV of the groundwater resource depends on the relative benefits generated from each option, net of the governance costs involved in

establishing the candidate institution. For example, if the initial demand for water is small and the aquifer is large, the gains from management are likely to be small, and open access might be preferred. As demand grows over time and water becomes scarcer, however, a user association, government regulations, or a water market may become efficient. References Gisser, M., and D.A. Sanchez. 1980. Competition Versus Optimal Control in Groundwater Pumping. Water Resources Research, 31:638 42. Kamien, M.I., and N.L. Schwartz. 1991. Dynamic optimization: the calculus of variations and optimal control in economics and management. New York: North-Holland. Krulce, D.L., J.A. Roumasset, and T. Wilson. 1997. Optimal Management of a Renewable and Replaceable Resource: The Case of Coastal Groundwater. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79:1218 28. Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: the evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. World Commission on Environment and Development (WCED). 1987. Our Common Future (The Brundtland Report). Oxford: Oxford University Press. Further reading (with equations) 1. Optimal extraction over space and time: Pitafi, B.A., and J.A. Roumasset. 2009. Pareto- Improving Water Mangement over Space and Time: The Honolulu Case. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 91:138-153.

2. Conjunctive use a) Roumasset, J., and R. Smith. 2011. Inter-District Water Allocation with Conjunctive Use. Journal of Contemporary Water Research and Education, 118:68-73. b) Pongkijvorasin, S., and J. Roumasset. 2007. Optimal Conjunctive Use of Surface and Groundwater with Recharge and Return Flows: Dynamic and Spatial Patterns. Review of Agricultural Economics, 29:531-539. c) Jandoc, K., R. Howitt, J. Roumasset, C. Wada. 2014. Institutions for Managing Ground and Surface Water and the Theory of the Second-Best. In: K. Burnett, R. Howitt, J. Roumasset, and C.A. Wada (Eds.), Routledge Handbook of Water Economics and Institutions. Routledge (forthcoming). 3. Multiple aquifer management: Roumasset, J.A., and C.A. Wada. 2012. Ordering the extraction of renewable resources: The case of multiple aquifers. Resource and Energy Economics, 34:112-128. 4. Optimal timing of wastewater recycling: Roumasset, J., and C.A. Wada. 2011. Ordering Renewable Resources: Groundwater, Recycling, and Desalination. The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy, 11: Article 28. 5. Integrated watershed management a) Roumasset, J., and C.A. Wada. 2013. A dynamic approach to PES pricing and finance for interlinked ecosystem services: Watershed conservation and groundwater management. Ecological Economics 87:24-33. b) Pongkijvorasin, S., and J. Roumasset. 2010. Integrated Watershed Management: The Role of Optimization in Sustainability Science. In: J. Roumasset, K. Burnett, and A. Balisacan (Eds.),

Sustainability Science for Watershed Landscapes. Singapore: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies; Los Banos, Philippines: Southeast Asian Regional Center for Graduate Study and Research in Agriculture. c) Roumasset, J., and C. Wada. Integrated Groundwater Resource Management. In: A. Balisacan, U. Chakravorty, and M. Ravago (Eds.), Economics of Sustainable Development: Risk, Resources and Governance. Elsevier (forthcoming). d) Roumasset, J.A., and C.A. Wada. 2013. Economics of Groundwater. In: J.F. Shogren (Ed.), Encyclopedia of Energy, Natural Resource, and Environmental Economics. Amsterdam: Elsevier. 6. Energy and climate change a) Roumasset, J., and C.A. Wada. 2014. Energy, backstop endogeneity, and the optimal use of groundwater. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, doi: 10.1093/ajae/aau025. b) Roumasset, J., and C.A. Wada. Payments for watershed services as adaptation to climate change: upstream conservation and downstream aquifer management. University of Hawaii Department of Economics, Working Paper Series #14-17.