THE KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY AT THE TURN OF THE TWENTIETH CENTURY: THE EMERGENCE OF HIERARCHIES

Similar documents
Oshoring in a Knowledge Economy

Organizing Offshoring: Middle Managers and Communication Costs

31E00700 Labor Economics: Lecture 7

Talent and Information in the Production of Management: A Note.

The Labor Market Effects of an Educational Expansion. The case of Brazil from 1995 to 2014

Internet Appendix to Technological Change, Job Tasks, and CEO Pay

Performance, Career Dynamics, and Span of Control

PERFORMANCE, CAREER DYNAMICS, AND SPAN OF CONTROL

PERFORMANCE, CAREER DYNAMICS, AND SPAN OF CONTROL

Modeling Automation. February 4, Abstract

(Indirect) Input Linkages

Unequal Effects of Trade on Workers with Different Abilities

PERFORMANCE, CAREER DYNAMICS, AND SPAN OF CONTROL

CEO pay and appointments: A market-based explanation for recent trends *

Understanding the Supply and Demand Forces behind the Fall and Rise in the U.S. Skill Premium

Chapter 11 Markets for Factors of Production

Business Cycle Facts

Appendix to Skill-Biased Technical Change, Educational Choice, and Labor Market Polarization: The U.S. versus Europe

SOCIAL STRATIFICATION, CAPITAL SKILL COMPLEMENTARITY, AND THE NONMONOTONIC EVOLUTION OF THE EDUCATION PREMIUM

Skills, Tasks and Technologies

Online Appendix Stuck in the Adoption Funnel: The Effect of Interruptions in the Adoption Process on Usage

Productivity, Output, and Employment. Chapter 3. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

1 Preliminaries. 1.1 What is Macroeconomics?

Employer Size Effects for Workers vs. Supervisors: Evidence from British Survey Data

2. Why is a firm in a purely competitive labor market a wage taker? What would happen if it decided to pay less than the going market wage rate?

1 INTRODUCTION AND PRELIMINARIES

Journal of Business & Economics Research Volume 2, Number 11

Business Cycle Facts

Part 2. Urban efficiency wages

Hierarchies, Specialization, and the Utilization of Knowledge: Theory and Evidence from the Legal Services Industry

Articial Intelligence, Worker-Replacing Technological Progress and Income Distribution

MANAGERIAL MODELS OF THE FIRM

Department of Economics Working Paper

COMM 210 Midterm Study Guide

Chapter 5 Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

Chapter 9 employed human capital theory to explore the demand for education

Production and Cost. This Is What You Need to Know. Explain the difference between accounting and economic costs and how they affect the determination

Lecture 9. Income disparity among countries Endogenous growth: a model of human capital accumulation

Assortative Matching > 0. (2)

Liang Wang University of Hawaii Manoa. Randall Wright University of Wisconsin Madison Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis

GENDER EQUITY INSIGHTS 2018 INSIDE AUSTRALIA S GENDER PAY GAP

Economic Development and the Organization of Production

Economic Growth and Sector Dynamics *

Does Technology Create Jobs?

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

Chapter 8: Exchange. 8.1: Introduction. 8.2: Exchange. 8.3: Individual A s Preferences and Endowments

CHAPTER 2 THE EVOLUTION OF MANAGEMENT THOUGHT LEARNING OBJECTIVES. To describe the evolution of management theory.

Speed and Quality of Collective Decision Making: Incentives for Information Provision

The Returns to Knowledge Hierarchies

Women s labor force participation Income and substitution elasticities, and some critical remarks

Technology-Skill Complementarity

Econ 792. Labor Economics. Lecture 6

Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation

Reading Essentials and Study Guide

Why Haven t Global Markets Reduced Inequality in Emerging Economies?

Chapter 9: Labor Section 1

THE TIMING OF EDUCATION

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 5. Resources and Trade: The Heckscher-Ohlin Model

INFORMATION SYSTEMS, ORGANIZATIONS, MANAGEMENT, AND STRATEGY

ALFRED P. MASSACHUSETTS SLOAN SCHOOL OF MANAGEMENT CAMBRIDGE, MASSACHUSETTS INSTITUTE OF TECHNOLOGY PLANNED CHANGE IN ORGANIZATIONAL SYSTEMS

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Fair Labor Standards Act Part 541 Overtime Final Rule

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

The NEW White Collar Exemption Rule: How to Prepare

UNEMPLOYMENT AND ITS NATURAL RATE

Chapter 9: Labor Section 3

Worker Turnover, Industry Localization, and Producer Size. Christopher H. Wheeler

PAPER No. : 02 MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS MODULE No. : 03 PRINCIPLES: INDIVIDUAL AND MARKET

Exporters, Engineers, and Blue-Collar Workers

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

6. In the early part of 1998, crude oil prices fell to a nine-year low at $13.28 a barrel.

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Productivity or Signaling?

The nature of offshoring of business services and its labour market consequences. Karolina Ekholm Stockholm University

DIVERSE ORGANIZATIONS

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Chapter 8 The Labor Market: Employment, Unemployment, and Wages

Chapter 16 Motivation

How to Determine the X in RPI - X Regulation: A User's Guide

Medical Practice Billing Analysis

Chapter 5: Supply Section 1

The value which motivated him was giving experience to all the employees for different job positions but the value which lack here are the following.

Sample Organizational Chart

The Productivity of Unskilled Labor in Multinational Subsidiaries from Di erent Sources

ECON 450 Development Economics

Wage and Productivity Dispersion in U.S. Manufacturing: The Role of Computer Investment

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent

6. The law of diminishing marginal returns begins to take effect at labor input level: a. 0 b. X c. Y d. Z

Thursday, October 13: Short and Long Run Equilibria

1/16/2009. Chapter Two

Chapter 3. Labour Demand. Introduction. purchase a variety of goods and services.

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

I. Create an episode map on westward expansion

Implicit Contracts, Unemployment, and Labor Market Segmentation

Heterogeneous Workers and International Trade

5.2 Demand and Supply in the Labour Market

Pyramids. Marianne Bertrand (University of Chicago, CEPR and NBER) Sendhil Mullainathan (MIT and NBER) September 25,2002

Operations and Supply Chain Management Prof. G. Srinivasan Department of Management Studies Indian Institute of Technology, Madras

UNIT 8 COST CONCEPTS AND ANALYSIS I

Transcription:

THE KNOWLEDGE ECONOMY AT THE TURN OF THE TWENTIETH CENTURY: THE EMERGENCE OF HIERARCHIES Luis Garicano University of Chicago Esteban Rossi-Hansberg Princeton University Abstract We use a simplified version of Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2005) to understand the impact of improvements in communications technology at the turn of the twentieth century on wages and organization. Improvements in communication technology allow individuals of different skills to abandon self-employment and form teams with each other. In particular, they allow high-skill agents to leverage their knowledge by specializing in the hardest tasks and hiring lowskill agents to do the routine tasks. Organization then exploits the complementarities between individual skills, which in turn affects the distribution of earnings. (JEL: D2, J3, L2, N3) 1. Introduction The knowledge economy is nothing new. As Chandler s (1977) classic study documents, improvements in communication technology (e.g., mail via railways, the telegraph, and later the telephone) played a key role in the emergence of the modern American corporation in the late 19th century and the start of the 20th century. These technological changes revolutionized the organization of production, thereby changing the demand for skilled and unskilled agents by creating a new class of professional salaried managers and a class of blue-collar workers under their supervision. In this paper we present a simple equilibrium theory based on Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2006) in which organization is endogenous and depends crucially on the state of communication technology. With this theory we are able to study the emergence of hierarchies and the implications for the demand for workers of different skills and, therefore, wages. We present a very simplified version of the theory in Garicano and Rossi- Hansberg (2006) where improvements in communication technology allow individuals of different skills to abandon self-employment and form teams with each other. The idea is that low communication costs allow high-skill agents to leverage their knowledge by specializing in the hardest tasks and hiring low-skill E-mail addresses: Garicano: luis.garicano@chicagogsb.edu; Rossi-Hansberg: erossi@princeton.edu Journal of the European Economic Association April-May 2006 4(2 3):396 403 2006 by the European Economic Association zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 396 #1

Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg The Emergence of Hierarchies 397 agents to do the routine tasks. Organization then exploits the complementarities between individual skills which in turn affects the distribution of earnings. Organization allows high-skill agents to better leverage their knowledge, and thus it initially increases the returns to skill. However, this increase in the ability of managers to leverage their talent eventually turns against them. As communication technology improves further and the size of production teams that can be managed by a single manager increases, the demand for production workers, and therefore their wages, increase; in contrast, those able to perform managerial jobs become, by the same process that made them more productive, less necessary. Thus our analysis implies a constant increase in the wages of low-skill/production workers as communication costs decrease, and an inverted U-shaped change in the wage of high-skill workers and managers, who first see gains due to their ability to leverage their knowledge and then experience a drop in the demand for their services. 1 We present the model in the Section 2 and show that our theory provides a link between communication technology, the emergence of organization, the relative demand for skills, and wages. We then argue in Section 3 that this is consistent with the evidence for the turn of the 20th century in the US. 2. The Model 2.1. Production, Communication, and Organization The model is a simplified version of Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2006). In particular, here teams have only two layers rather than many, agents have only two skill levels rather than a continuum, and the supply of skills is exogenous. The economy is formed by two types of agents of different skills who can choose their occupation and join a team or work on their own. The occupations that are available are problem-solving and production. All agents supply one unit of time, which can be used in production or communicating with others. The equilibrium in the economy determines the occupations of individuals (workers, managers, and self-employed) and their wages. Production requires labor and knowledge. There is a measure 1 of problems. Agents with skill q [0, 1] can solve all problems between 0 and q, soan agent with q >qcan solve all problems that q can solve plus some extra ones. That is, knowledge is cumulative. Agents who specialize in production draw one problem per unit of time. There are two types of agents: low-skill agents with skill q l and high-skill agents with skill q h. The economy-wide ratio of low- to high-skill agents is exogenously given by ρ. We normalize output of a team when 1. Supply reactions are, of course, also very important and missing in our analysis. See Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2005) for a general theory with a continuum of abilities, multiple layers, and endogenous skill acquisition. zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 397 #2

398 Journal of the European Economic Association production takes place to 1, and thus expected output of an agent with skill q i working alone is y = q i. Agents can also communicate their knowledge to others, and thus help them solve problems. This possibility allows them to form organizations in which several individuals combine their time and knowledge to produce together. Such organizations are composed by production workers, who draw problems, and problem-solvers, who can answer questions and thus help workers solve the problems they cannot solve. Workers draw a problem, and try to solve it; if they can, they produce; if they cannot they ask for help to the managers, in which case these managers incur a communication cost h. If the manager knows the solution the team produces one unit of output. Thus the organization of production is in knowledge-based hierarchies, with some agents specialized in production and some in management; and management by exception, whereby production workers deal with the most common problems and problem solvers with the exceptions. These characteristics are optimal under the assumption that agents do not know who may know the solution to problems they cannot solve, as Garicano (2000) shows. The purpose of the hierarchy is to protect the knowledge of those who are more knowledgeable from easy questions others can solve. A manager with knowledge q 1 can help a team of n 0 production workers. These workers draw one problem each, and solve a fraction q 0 of them. Hence they pass on a fraction (1 q 0 ) of all problems. Managers are thus asked to solve n 0 (1 q 0 ) problems, which they can address in n 0 (1 q 0 )h units of time. Optimally, managers join teams with precisely the right number of production workers so that they use all their time. Because all agents have one unit of time available, the team size n 0 is implicitly given by n 0 h(1 q 0 ) = 1. The time constraint implies that the span of the manager is limited by the knowledge of their subordinates. Output is produced whenever either workers or manager know the solution to the problems, so y = q 1 n 0. (1) Note the source of complementarity between skills in our model: An able top manager increases the productivity of all workers in the team. The more knowledgeable are subordinates, the larger the team and the more managers can leverage their knowledge. Given zero profits, we can denote the earnings of low-skill agents by w p and let those of high-skill agents be given by w h = n(q m w p ) = q m w p h(1 q p ). zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 398 #3

Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg The Emergence of Hierarchies 399 2.2. Team Size and Occupational Choice Agents are income maximizers. They organize in teams if they earn more in a team than as self-employed. First, note that this can never be the case with teams of identical workers, because a worker cannot add value to someone of his same skill. Formally, a team of n production workers with skill q l and a manager of skill q l produces nq l, which is lower than than the autarchy output (n + 1)q l. Similarly, a team will never optimally have a manager who is less skilled than the subordinates. Then, a team of n(h, q) 1/(h(1 q)) low-skill workers and a high-skill manager will be formed if n(h, q l )q h > n(h, q l )q l + q h, that is if h<h(q h,q l ) q h q l < 1. (2) q h (1 q l ) So for h<h(q h,q l ) some teams are formed and if h>h(q h,q l ) everyone is self-employed. Intuitively, for teams to form communication technology must be good enough to justify removing one person from production and allowing them to specialize in solving problems for others. Skills and technology jointly determine the demand for skills. As h goes down, more workers and fewer managers are needed to form teams; as q l goes up, more low-skill workers are demanded per high-skill worker. The supply of skills is exogenously given by the relative quantity of low- to high-skill workers ρ. In equilibrium, if the relative demand for low-skill agents (n) is higher than the relative supply (ρ), some high-skill agents do not form teams and remain selfemployed; alternatively, if the demand for low-skill agents per high-skill agent (n) is low relative to ρ, then some low-skill agents are production workers in teams and some remain self-employed. Let s i be the share of agents of a given type who work in organizations for i ={l,h}. Thus, 1 s i is the share who are self-employed. Then the unique equilibrium is of one of three types: s l = 0,s h = 0, if h>h(q h,q l ) 0 <s l 1,s h = 1, if h<h(q h,q l ) and ρ n(h, q l ) s l = 1, 0 <s h < 1, if h<h(q h,q l ) and ρ < n(h, q l ). This characterization implies directly the following result which is illustrated in Figure 1. Result 1. As the communication costs h decrease: (i) the proportion of low-skill agents working in organizations, s l, weakly increases; (ii) the proportion of high-skill agent working in organizations, s h, weakly increases if h>1/(ρ(1 q l )) and decreases otherwise. zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 399 #4

400 Journal of the European Economic Association Figure 1. Self-employment and team production (q h = 0.7,q i = 0.3,ρ = 4). In sum, as communication costs fall, we move from an equilibrium in which everyone is self-employed to one in which there is organization. In this second stage all high-skill agents work in teams and some low-skill agents remain self-employed because teams are small and require many managers per worker. As communication costs fall further managers lead larger teams and so the demand for low-skill workers increases and incentivates some low-skill agents to leave self-employment and join organizations. Eventually all low-skill agents work in teams and further decreases in communication costs imply that some high-skill agents cannot find workers to form teams and so they go back to self-employment. Figure 1 presents an example where these three stages are evident. 2.3. Wages and Inequality We now turn to equilibrium wages. The type of agents in excess supply have their wages pinned down at their self-employment levels, and the other agents earn the rents associated with producing in teams relative to producing alone. In particular, if some high-skill agents are self-employed, then the low-skill wage, w l, is obtained from w h = q h = (q h w l )/(h(1 q l )); whereas if some lowskill agents are self-employed then w l = q l and therefore w h = (q h q l )/ (h(1 q l )). zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 400 #5

Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg The Emergence of Hierarchies 401 Figure 2. Wages (q h = 0.7,q i = 0.3,ρ = 4). This allows us to characterize equilibrium earnings as follows: w h = q h,w l = q l, if h>h(q h,q l ) w h = q h q l h(1 q l ),w l = q l, if h<h(q h,q l ) and ρ n(h, q l ) w h = q h,w l = q h (1 h(1 q l )), if h<h(q h,q l ) and ρ < n(h, q l ) It is then immediate to obtain the following result, which is illustrated in Figure 2. Result 2. As the communication cost h decrease: (i) the wages of low-skill agents weakly increase; (ii) the wages of high-skill agents increase weakly if h>1/(ρ(1 q l )) and decreases otherwise. The effect of h on the wages of low-skill agents is clear. Low-skill agents are increasingly needed to take production jobs in teams with high-skill agents as high-skill agents form larger teams. This can also be seen in Figure 1 as h goes down, the proportion of low-skill agents in self-employment always declines. The effect on the earnings of high-skill agents is more subtle. First, as communication costs decrease, the productivity of teams goes up, and eventually high-skill agents start forming teams with low-skill agents. If low-skill agents zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 401 #6

402 Journal of the European Economic Association are relatively plentiful, then high-skill agents capture gains from forming these teams. They benefit from the leverage effect, which allows them to spread their knowledge over an entire team. However, the leverage effect eventually turns against them. As managers become more and more productive at solving problems, fewer problem-solvers are needed, and some high-skill agents have to turn to self-employment. As a result, the wage of high-skill agents is determined by their self-employment earnings, and the low-skill agents capture the benefits from organization. As a result, the ratio of low- to high-skill wages exhibits a U-shaped pattern as a function of h, as illustrated in Figure 2. 3. The Turn of the Century This simple supply and demand model allows us to study the emergence of the modern corporation at the turn of the century, and provides some additional empirical implications on wages. As communication costs decrease, with the emergence of the telegraph and the improvement of railway and other land and water-based communication, managers can leverage their talent by having large teams. 2 To illustrate this, consider, for example, the account of Chandler (1977) on the first development of hierarchies, which took place in the 1840s in the railroad sector. In the Erie railroad information flowed through the hierarchy as follows: Hourly reports, primarily operational and sent by telegraph, gave the location of trains... Just as importantly, the information generated on these tabular forms was filed away to provide an excellent source of operational information which, among other things, was useful in determining and eliminating causes of delay. Similarly, daily reports were required from conductors, agents and engineers (p. 103). The success of such a system relied on the emergence of agents with special skills and training: the salaried manager. By 1850 Chandler (1977, p. 87) documents that large roads were already employing from 40 to 60 full-time salaried managers, and some more by the 1870s. The creation of these hierarchies resulted in an increase in the demand for both managers and production workers, who left previous self-employed positions and joined larger teams. However, our theory suggests that the initial stages of the process favor high-skill agents, who can leverage their talent through large teams, thereby increasing the skill premium. Eventually, however, communication should become so cheap, and teams so large, that the scarcity should shift from high-skill to low-skill workers. This in turn would reduce wages of highskill agents and therefore inequality. Hence, according to our theory continuous 2. The first telegraph line was officially opened by Samuel Morse on May 24, 1844. Simultanously, improving transportation allowed for the sharpest reductions in mail rates in history between 1851 and 1855 first-class mail rates of 5 cents per ounce up to 300 miles carried, and 10 cents beyond, were reduced to 3 cents an ounce up to 3,000 miles (Chandler 1977, p. 195). zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 402 #7

Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg The Emergence of Hierarchies 403 declines in communication technology first increase and then decrease inequality across salaried managers and production workers. The existing evidence on the evolution of wages at the end of the 19th century and the start of the 20th century suggests that some of these effects may be present in the data. Goldin (2001) argues that large increases in the demand for skill at the turn of the century resulted in large increases in the skill premium. After that, several studies have documented a substantial and continuous decline in skill premia, whether measured by the white-collar/blue collar differential or the premium to education (see Douglas 1930; Goldin and Katz 1999; and Goldin 2001). As Goldin and Katz (1999, 2003) have pointed out, the drop in the relative wages of white-collar workers is in part a response to the large increase in the supply of skills during the start of the century. Our model suggests another mechanism that may have contributed as well: Increasing relative demand for production labor relative to highly skilled labor, due to larger spans of control as a result of better communication technology. Of course, in interpreting such long-run data our model has an important limitation: The fact that it fixes the supply of skill. Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2006) generalizes the model to allow individuals to invest in knowledge at a cost, and the underlying heterogeneity is heterogeneity in cognitive ability or cost of acquiring knowledge. This modification implies that decreases in communication costs lead to less inequality among agents in production and lower layers of management, because they acquire less knowledge, but more inequality between them and top managers. Hence, although the role of communication costs h on flattening the lower part of the wage structure must always be part of the analysis, the simple model in this paper eliminates a second effect in the opposite direction: Decreases in communication cost can favor some super-star managers that lead very large teams, After all, this is the era of Sloan, Morgan, and Ford. However, the evidence refers not to these top managers but to a large white-collar managerial class. References Chandler, Alfred D. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Belknap Press. Douglas, Paul (1930). Real Wages in the U.S.: 1890 1926. Houghton Mifflin Company. Garicano, Luis (2000). Hierarchies and the Organization of Knowledge in Production. Journal of Political Economy, 108, 874 904. Garicano, Luis, and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg (2006). Organization and Inequality in a Knowledge Economy. Quarterly Journal of Economics (forthcoming). Goldin, Claudia (2001). The Human Capital Century and American Leadership: Virtues of the Past. Journal of Economic History, 61, 263 291. Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz (1999). The Returns to Skill across the Twentieth Century United States. NBER Working Paper 7126. Goldin, Claudia, and Lawrence F. Katz (2003). The Virtues of the Past: Education in the First Hundred Years of the New Republic. NBER Working Paper 9958. zwu002060325 2006/6/27 page 403 #8