Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry

Similar documents
WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

BLP applications: Nevo (2001) and Petrin(2002)

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Oligopoly Pricing. EC 202 Lecture IV. Francesco Nava. January London School of Economics. Nava (LSE) EC 202 Lecture IV Jan / 13

Lecture 11 Applications of BLP. Bronwyn H. Hall Economics 220C, UC Berkeley Spring 2005

Mergers with differentiated products: the case of the ready-to-eat cereal industry

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

ECONOMIC RESEARCH CENTER DISCUSSION PAPER

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Identification and Estimation of Cost Functions Using Observed Bid Data: An Application to Electricity Markets *

Aviv Nevo, Deputy Assistant Attorney General for Economic Analysis: Interpreting Data Under the Guidance of Economic Theory

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Identification in differentiated product markets

Cartelization of Cross-Holdings

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Principles of Microeconomics Assignment 8 (Chapter 10) Answer Sheet. Class Day/Time

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Imperfect Competition

Some relationships between evolutionary stability criteria in games

How Competitive is the World Wheat Market?

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

SEISMIC CRACKING AND STRENGTHENING OF CONCRETE GRAVITY DAMS

Two-Part Tariffs versus Linear Pricing Between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Tests on Differentiated Products Markets

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Counterintuitive Signs in Reduced Form Price Regressions

A Mixed-type Distribution for. Inventory Management

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

STATISTICAL TECHNIQUES. Data Analysis and Modelling

International Journal of Industrial Organization

Department of Agricultural & Resource Economics, UCB

Tilburg University. Published in: Marketing Letters. Publication date: Link to publication

Restrictions in labor supply estimation: Is the MaCurdy critique correct?

A Note on Revenue Sharing in Sports Leagues

Lectures on International Trade and Investment: Multinational Firms, Offshoring, Outsourcing, and Environment

Identification and Estimation of Intra-Firm and Industry Competition via Ownership Change

Applications and Choice of IVs

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim

. This function gives the supplier s behavior with respect to price and quantity.

Industrial Organization

Market Delineation and Product Differentiation

Empirical Models of Auctions

Vertical relationships between Manufacturers and Retailers: Inference with Limited Data

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES. No MARKET DEFINITION WITH DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS LESSONS FROM THE CAR MARKET. Randy Brenkers and Frank Verboven

Food Marketing Policy Center

IS PERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION REALLY EFFICIENT? AN ANALYSIS OF FREE ENTRY EQUILIBRIA

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS. Jonathan Vogel. Working Paper

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

Evaluating the Competitive Yardstick Effect of Cooperatives on Imperfect Markets: A Simulation Analysis

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

Solutions to Final Exam

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

Making Optimal Decisions of Assembly Products in Supply Chain

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Advanced Microeconomics Theory. Chapter 8: Game Theory and Imperfect Competition

may be regarded as the aggregate investment and consumption functions arising from a decentralized homogeneous consumer economy.

Empirical research on discrete choice game theory models of entry: An illustration

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

COST, REVENUE, AND STRATEGIC INTERACTION

arxiv: v1 [q-fin.gn] 20 Sep 2009

Rent-setting in multiple winner rent-seeking contests

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

Economics 101A (Lecture 19) Stefano DellaVigna

References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage"

Market Power in Direct Marketing of Fresh Produce: Community Supported Agriculture Farms

Models of Creative Destruction (Quality Ladders)

ADVANCED PLACEMENT MICROECONOMICS Maple Grove Senior High School Jeff Rush Social Studies Department

Department of Agricultural, Environmental, and Development Economics The Ohio State University Working Paper: AEDE-WP

Voluntary Export Restraints on Automobiles: Evaluating a Trade Policy

ECO 162: MICROECONOMICS INTRODUCTION TO ECONOMICS Quiz 1. ECO 162: MICROECONOMICS DEMAND Quiz 2

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness

Graduate Industrial Organization

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Microfoundations and General Equilibrium. Before beginning our study of specific macroeconomic questions, we review some micro

ETSG 2015 PARIS 17th Annual Conference, September 2015 Université Paris 1 Panthéon Sorbonne

The social norm of leaving the toilet seat down: A game theoretic analysis

Agricultural Supplier s Online Sale Mode Choice Under Dual-channel. Supply Chain. Bei Xia

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Pass-Through Rates and the Price Effects of Mergers

Supermarkets Price Competition in Dallas Fort Worth Fluid Milk Market. Benaissa Chidmi

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS WILEY A JOHN WILEY & SONS, INC., PUBLICATION. A Mathematical Approach

Optimizing demand-side bids in day-ahead electricity markets

Cardiff Economics Working Papers

Transcription:

Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry Aviv Nevo* 549 Evans Hall [3880, Department of Economics, UC Berkeley, Berkeley, CA 94720-3880, USA Received 16 December 1997; accepted 19 February 1998 Abstract A central part of the new empirical industrial organization has been the study of market power in homogenous-product industries. This paper discusses extension of these methods to differentiated-products industries. The requirements for identification of conectural variation parameters are shown to be hard to satisfy in practice. An alternative menu-approach is discussed. 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. Keywords: Conectural variation parameters; Differentiated-products; Market power JEL classification: L13 1. Introduction Much of the work in study of concentrated homogenous-product industries has attempted to identify the degree of market power (see Bresnahan, 1989). A central part of these studies is the 1 estimation of conectural variation (CV) parameters. The main limitation of extending these studies to differentiated-products industries has been the difficulty of estimating demand in such cases (for a discussion of the problems in estimation and solutions see Nevo, 1997). However, with recent improvement in the methods of estimating demand for a large number of closely related products the time has come to ask if CV parameters can be identified in these industries? And if using CV parameters is the best way to test different solution concepts? This note discusses both these questions. I show that, in principal, CV parameters are identified (ust like they are in the homogenous-product case). However, in practice the exclusion restrictions required for identification will be hard to satisfy. Furthermore, an alternative menu approach is discussed and shown to be easier to identify. *Tel.: 11 510 642 4752; fax: 11 510 642 6615; e-mail: nevo@econ.berkeley.edu 1 By a conectural variation parameter I mean a continuous parameter that measures the degree of market power in an industry. This parameter can be interpreted as measuring, in some quantitative sense, how close the equilibrium outcome is to theoretical predictions, or as measuring the conectures firms have regarding the competition. See Bresnahan (1989) for a discussion of the various alternatives. Here I abstract from interpretation and focus on identification issues. 0165-1765/ 98/ $19.00 1998 Elsevier Science S.A. All rights reserved. PII: S0165-1765(98)00061-5

392 A. Nevo / Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 2. The model Assume we observe J differentiated products, with aggregate demand for each product given by Q 5 D( p,...,p, Y, a), 5 1,...,J, (1) 1 J where Q is quantity demanded of variety, p,...,p are the prices of all products, Y is a vector of 1 J exogenous variables, and a is a vector of parameters to be estimated. Suppose there are F firms, each of which produces some subset, ^, of the J different brands. The profits of firm f are f P 5O ( p 2 mc (W, b ))Q 2 C, (2) f f [^ f where mc(?) denotes the marginal cost, which is a function of exogenous variables, W, and parameters to be estimated, b. Fixed costs are denoted by C f. This specification assumes that marginal costs are constant. In a general setup the marginal costs are allowed to be a function of the quantities produced. The implications of this more general setup are discussed below. Assuming (1) the existence of a pure-strategy Bertrand Nash equilibrium in prices; and (2) that the prices that support it are strictly positive; the price p of any product produced by firm f must satisfy the first order condition Q r( p) Q ( p) 1O ( p 2 mc )]]] 5 0. (3) r r r[^ f p These set of J equations imply price costs margins for each good. The markups can be solved for explicitly by defining S 52 Q / p, r 5 1,...,J, H r r 1, if ' f : hr,, ^ f ; Q r 5 0, otherwise and Vr 5 Q r * S r. In vector notation the first order conditions become Q( p) 2 V( p 2 mc) 5 0. (5) This implies a pricing equation 21 p 5 mc 1 V Q( p). (6) Different models of competition can be nested within this framework by setting various elements of the matrix Q to one. For example, a single-product Nash Bertrand model corresponds to an Q equal to the identify matrix, a multiproduct Nash Bertrand model corresponds to blocks of ones in Q, and a fully collusive model corresponds to a matrix of ones. The econometric specification is completed by adding to both the demand and pricing equations econometric error terms, denoted e and h, respectively. The parameters of the model, a and b, are identified because both demand, specified in equation (1), and the supply relation, specified in equation (6), have excluded exogenous variables. The parameters can be estimated using simulations equations methods for different models of conduct, which correspond to different Q matrices. (4)

A. Nevo / Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 393 Furthermore, one can test between different models of conduct by comparing the fit of the various models. Formally, the test is performed by constructing tests of nonnested models as in Bresnahan (1987) or Gasami et al. (1992). In this approach the choice of the conduct model is from a finite set that is defined by the researcher according to her understanding and intuition. I refer to this approach as the menu approach. 3. Identification of CV parameters An alternative, to the method described in the previous section, is to replace the matrix Q defined by equation (4), which is derived directly from different economic models, with a matrix of parameters. These parameters are equivalent to the conectural variations (CV) parameters used in much of the literature that measures market power in homogenous goods industries. The reader is referred to Bresnahan (1989) for a discussion of the interpretation of these parameters. Here I ask under what conditions are these parameters identified ointly with the cost and demand parameters? 3.1. A simple example In order to examine the question I study the simplest model possible. Assume there are only two single product firms, and that both demand and marginal cost are given by linear functions. The demand function for brand is Q 5 a 1 a p 1 a p 1 Y9a 1 e, 5 1, 2, (7) 0 1 1 2 2 3 and the marginal cost function is mc 5 b 1 W9b, 5 1, 2. (8) 0 1 Note that Y and W may include more than a single variable and these variables are assumed to be different between cost and demand equations. I assume that the dimension of W is such that the 2 parameters of the demand function are identified. Substituting the linear demand and cost specifications into equation (6), and allowing for CV parameters rather than the structure of equation (4), the supply relation becomes where S D Q Q i p5 b0 1 W 9 b1 2 A uii]] Q 2ui]] Qi 1h pi pi 5 b 1 W 9b 2 A(u aq 2u aq ) 1h, 5 1, 2, i 5 3 2 5 2, 1, (9) S 0 1 ii ii i i i Q Q Q Q A 5 u u 2u u 5 (u u a a 2u u a a ). D 21 2 1 2 1 21 11 22]]]] 12 21]]]] p p p P 11 22 22 11 12 21 21 12 2 1 1 2 2 In practice identifying parameters of the demand for differentiated products is a difficult problem, potentially harder than the one discussed here. For a discussion of the problem and possible solutions see Nevo (1997) and references therein.

394 A. Nevo / Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 Given the assumptions made the demand parameters are identified. Therefore, a necessary condition for the parameters (u 11, u 12, u 21, u 22) to be identified is that the dimension of the exogenous variables in the demand equation, Y, is at least two. In the case where we have J products, the dimension of Y has to be at least J. Thus, in principal the CV parameters are identified. In practice, however, it is hard, if not impossible, to find such a large number of exogenous variables that influence demand but are uncorrelated with the shock in the pricing equation. Various marketing variables might be included in the demand equation; however, it is unlikely that these are uncorrelated with the pricing decision. Seasonal parameters that influence demand are good candidates; however, they are unlikely to be of large enough dimension. In summary, even for this relatively simple example there is little hope of identifying all the CV parameters in practice. 3.2. The general case The problems presented in the previous section continue to hold if we examine a more general demand function. Furthermore, if marginal costs are not constant and vary with quantity, then additional terms enter the pricing equation. This augments the problem. Now, we not only require 3 more instrumental variables, but also for each quantity variable that enters demand we require an instrumental variable that rotates, not ust shifts, the demand curve. The argument is essentially the same as that given in Bresnahan (1982) and Lau (1982). 4. Discussion Adding CV parameters to the model has some appeal because it allows the researcher to obtain a quantitative estimate of how close the observed data is to some theoretical model of conduct. However, the above discussion shows that in practice the exclusion restrictions required for identification will be hard to meet, even if only several CV parameters are estimated. Beyond suggesting a research strategy, this result suggests that the identifying assumptions made by those studies that claim to identify CV parameters in differentiated-products industries should be carefully examined. The alternative menu approach, presented in Section 2, does not require additional instrumental variables, beyond those required to estimate the demand and supply parameters, yet at the same time allows to test between different models of conduct. This approach has the additional advantage of directly linking estimation and theory. Acknowledgements Financial support from a University of California at Berkeley Committee on Research Junior Faculty Grant is gratefully acknowledged. 3 One could make the argument that all quantities produced by a multiproduct firm, as well as quantities produced by other firms, influence marginal cost.

A. Nevo / Economics Letters 59 (1998) 391 395 395 References Bresnahan, T., 1982. The oligopoly solution concept is identified. Economics Letters 10, 87 92. Bresnahan, T., 1987. Competition and collusion in the American automobile oligopoly: The 1955 price war. Journal of Industrial Economics 35, 457 482. Bresnahan, T., 1989. Empirical methods for industries with market power. In: Schmalensee, R., Willig, R. (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, vol. II. North-Holland, Amsterdam. Gasami, F., Laffont, J.J., Vuong, Q., 1992. Econometric analysis of collusive behavior in a soft-drink market. Journal of Economics and Management Strategy 1, 277 311. Lau, L., 1982. On identifying the degree of competitiveness from industry price and output data. Economics Letters 10, 93 99. Nevo, A., 1997. A research assistant s guide to random coefficients discrete choice models of demand. National Bureau of Economic Research Technical Working Paper No. 221.