WORKING PAPER SERIES Judo Economics in Markets with Asymmetric Firms Daniel Cracau Working Paper No. 2/2013

Similar documents
How Judo Economics can help small firms to survive Bertrand competition: evidence from the lab

The Role of Price Floor in a Differentiated Product Retail Market 1

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

Industrial. Organization. Markets and Strategies. 2nd edition. Paul Belleflamme Universite Catholique de Louvain. Martin Peitz University of Mannheim

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Competitive Franchising

References. Deneckere, R. (1983), Duopoly Supergames with Product Differentiation, Economics Letters, 11, pp

Advance Selling, Competition, and Brand Substitutability

Strategic Substitutes and Complements. MGT 525 Competitive Strategy Kevin Williams

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

1.. There are two complementary goods that are consumed together (each individual good

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Horizontal Product Differentiation in Bertrand and Cournot Duopoly: the Bertrand Paradox Revisited and Comparative Competitiveness

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

Industrial Organization

Consumer Conformity and Vanity in Vertically Differentiated Markets

Durable Goods Monopoly with Endogenous Quality

Product bundling and tying in competition

Price discrimination and limits to arbitrage: An analysis of global LNG markets

Strategic Ignorance in the Second-Price Auction

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan. Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe:

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Economics of Strategy Fifth Edition. Besanko, Dranove, Shanley, and Schaefer. Chapter 11. Entry and Exit. Copyright 2010 John Wiley Sons, Inc.

Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation

Horizontal mergers and competitive intensity

Lecture 2: Market Structure I (Perfect Competition and Monopoly)

Competition Policy Monopoly Competition Other. Bundling. Patrick Legros

Substitutability and Competition in the Dixit-Stiglitz Model

Assortative Matching > 0. (2)

Entry Deterrence in Durable-Goods Monopoly

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Stackelberg or Cournot Equilibria", Games and Economic Behavior, 2, 29-46, 1990.

Use the following to answer question 4:

NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES SPATIAL PRICE DISCRIMINATION WITH HETEROGENEOUS FIRMS. Jonathan Vogel. Working Paper

Reverse Pricing and Revenue Sharing in a Vertical Market

Chapter 13. Game Theory. Gaming and Strategic Decisions. Noncooperative v. Cooperative Games

Markus Reisinger: The Effects of Product Bundling in Duopoly

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

The Retailers Choices of Profit Strategies in a Cournot Duopoly: Relative Profit and Pure Profit

! lecture 7:! competition and collusion!!

Networks, Network Externalities and Market Segmentation

Universidade de Aveiro Departamento de Economia, Gestão e Engenharia Industrial. Documentos de Trabalho em Economia Working Papers in Economics

IS PERFECT PRICE DISCRIMINATION REALLY EFFICIENT? AN ANALYSIS OF FREE ENTRY EQUILIBRIA

Strategic Corporate Social Responsibility

On mergers in a Stackelberg market with asymmetric convex costs

OPTIMAL R&D POLICY AND ENDOGENOUS QUALITY CHOICE

Mergers, Spin-offs, and Employee Incentives

The Construction of the Green Supply System based on Game Theory

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

Product flexibility and price competition in Hotelling s duopoly

Analyzing Modes of Foreign Entry: Greenfield Investment versus Acquisition

Contents in Brief. Preface

Signaling Quality Through Prices in an Oligopoly.

The Quality of Complex Systems and Industry Structure

Market Dominance and Behavior Based Pricing under Horizontal and Vertical Differentiation

Duopoly Bundling: Multi-product vs Single-product Firms

Market structure 1: Perfect Competition The perfectly competitive firm is a price taker: it cannot influence the price that is paid for its product.

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

International Journal of Industrial Organization

Solutions to Final Exam

Vertical Integration and Downstream Collusion

MGMT 784: Managerial Economics and Game Theory, Q1, 2017

Section 10. Akos Lada. Fall Externality and Coasian Bargaining. We will explore this topic through an easy example

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Efficiency and Robustness of Binary Online Feedback Mechanisms in Trading Environments with Moral Hazard

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Horizontal mergers in the circular city: a note. Abstract

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Compatibility decisions, endogenous installed home bases, and third-market competition

Product Development Capability and Marketing Strategy for New Durable Products

WORKING PAPER SERIES Strike, coordination, and dismissal in uniform wage settings Karina Gose/Abdolkarim Sadrieh Working Paper No.

Search markets: Introduction

Spillovers, Licensing and Welfare

Analysis of Pre-order Strategies with the Presence of Experienced Consumers

Do Firms Always Choose Excess Capacity? Abstract

Chapter 11 Entry and Exit

Media Competition Enhances New-Product Entry: On the Market for Fake Observations

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

On Collusion and Industry Size

Universal Service Obligations in the Postal Sector: Endogenous Quality and Coverage

Empirical research on discrete choice game theory models of entry: An illustration

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Lecture 7 Rivalry, Strategic Behavior and Game Theory

Education, Institutions, Migration, Trade, and The Development of Talent

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

TYING, UPGRADES, AND SWITCHING COSTS

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Transcription:

WORKING PAPER SERIES

Impressum ( 5 TMG) Herausgeber: Otto-von-Guericke-Universität Magdeburg Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Der Dekan Verantwortlich für diese Ausgabe: Otto-von-Guericke-Universität Magdeburg Fakultät für Wirtschaftswissenschaft Postfach 4120 39016 Magdeburg Germany http://www.fww.ovgu.de/femm Bezug über den Herausgeber ISSN 1615-4274

Judo Economics in Markets with Asymmetric Firms Daniel Cracau 1a a University of Magdeburg, Faculty of Economics and Management Abstract I study a game with one market incumbent and a small entrant in a duopoly with perfectly substitutable products. Firms face a sequential Bertrand competition. Limiting the initial capacity (Judo economics) is a plausible entry strategy for the small firm. If we, however, introduce asymmetry in production cost or product quality, capacity limitation can become obsolete. I derive thresholds as regards the cost and quality differences for the entrant s choice to voluntarily limit the production capacity in equilibrium. I study a market entry game with price competition and perfectly substitutable products. Limiting the initial capacity (Judo economics) is a plausible entry strategy. I show that under asymmetry in production cost or product quality, capacity limitation can become obsolete. Keywords: Sequential Bertrand Competition, Judo Economics, Asymmetric Firms, Cost, Quality JEL: D43, L11 1. Introduction Judo economics as an entry strategy was first introduced in Gelman and Salop (1983). They show that a market entrant can use a capacity limitation to successfully survive in a Bertrand competition with homogeneous goods. For the market incumbent, accommodating entry turns out to be the profit maximizing response towards a Judo entrant. Rather than cutting down prices for the whole market, the incumbent allows the new entrant to serve 1 Correspondence to: Daniel Cracau; mailing address: University of Magdeburg, Faculty of Economics and Management, Chair in E-Business, Universitätsplatz 2, 39106 Magdeburg, Germany; telephone: +49-391-67-11359, e-mail: Cracau@ovgu.de

a small niche but sustains the power to serve the residual market as a monopolist. Meanwhile, the idea of Judo economics has been further elaborated in the economic literature. Empirical work has reported that Judo entrants are more likely to survive competition and incumbents respond less aggressively towards Judo entrants (Thomas, 1999). Also experimental results have shown that Judo economics works in the original setting (Cracau and Sadrieh, 2013). Theoretical work has focused on Judo Economics in more or less symmetric settings (Sørgard, 1995; Allen et al., 2000; Díaz et al., 2009). If any, only a cost advantage for the incumbent is considered. However, it is arguable that in some industries, entrants emerge with a technological innovation that gives them a cost or a quality advantage. The purpose of this article is to apply the idea of Judo Economics to a wider range of settings. I will allow for asymmetries in the firms cost structure and the consumers willingness to pay. 2. Model preliminaries I initially study two firms i = 1, 2 in a sequential Bertrand competition with firm 1 being the first moving entrant and firm 2 being the second moving market incumbent. Assumption 1. Products are perfect substitutes with different quality levels. Consumers willingness to pay for firm i s product is w i. Assumption 2. Total market demand D is fixed. In the first stage of the game, the entrant decides on his price p 1 w 1 and a capacity limitation 0 < k D. Then, the incumbent decides on her price p 2 w 2, adjusting output accordingly. 2 We, thus, assume that the incumbent has no capacity limitation. Assumption 3. Consumers preferences are lexicographic. Consumers buy from the firm which offers the highest consumer net benefit β i = w i p i. If firms offer the same net benefit, consumers buy from the incumbent. 2 W.l.o.g. I use male pronouns for the entrant and female pronouns for the incumbent. 2

Under Assumptions 1 to 3 and efficient rationing, firms sales s i depend on the firms decisions as well as on the market parameter. If the incumbent accommodates the entrant by setting a price p 2 > p 1 then s 1 = k and s 2 = D k. Otherwise, s 1 = 0 and s 2 = D. Finally, we assume that firms have linear production cost C i (s i ) = c i s i with 0 c i < w i. Firms maximize their total profit π i = p i s i C i = (p i c i ) s i. 3. Asymmetry in marginal cost When considering a cost differential, it is useful to define δ = c 2 c 1 as the cost differential between the two firms. A cost differential δ < 0 then indicates a cost advantage for the incumbent whereas δ > 0 indicates a cost advantage for the entrant. We can now differentiate two cases. 3.1. No cost advantage for the entrant (δ 0) This case is similar to the original model of Gelman and Salop (1983). It covers the symmetric case as well as the case where the incumbent is at a cost advantage. Proposition 1. Under Assumptions 1 to 3, the equilibrium price and capacity choices in the symmetric game satisfy p JAsymC 1 = (w + c 1 )/2, k JAsymC = (w c 1 )D/(2(w c 2 ) and p JAsymC 2 = w. Proof. After observing the entrants s price p 1 and capacity k, the incumbent can give two price responses. She may either choose p 2 = p 1 and match the entrants s price. In this case, she serves the entire market as the sole firm and earns a profit π2 Match (p 2 ) = ( p 1 c 2 )D. Alternatively, she can chooses a price p 2 > p 1 and accommodate the entrant. In this case, the incumbent acts as a quasi-monopolist for the residual market and earns π2 Resid = (w c 2 ) ( D k ). 3 From that, it is clear that the entrant must choose a price-capacity pair (p 1, k) so that the condition π2 Match π2 Resid is fulfilled, i.e. the incumbent s profit from accommodation must not be smaller than her profit from deterring entry. Let us now denote λ(k) as the function which assigns the greatest possible price p 1 to each capacity k that fulfills the condition. The entrant 3 The incumbent will always choose a price p 2 = w if accommodating, because demand is fixed and thus π Resid 2 / p 2 > 0. 3

then maximizese π 1 (p 1, k) = (p 1 c 1 )k w.r.t. p 1 λ(k). For the equilibrium, Gelman and Salop (1983) derive that the constraint holds with equality. The condition for the optimal capacity k can then be derived as 0 = λ(k ) + k λ (k ) C 1(k ). From that, also equilibrium prices p 1 = λ(k ) and p 2 = argmax π2 Resid (k ) are determined. Equilibrium profits can be derived as π JAsymC 1 = (w c 1 ) 2 D/4(w c 2 ) and π JAsymC 2 = (w + c 1 2c 2 )D/2. Being the second mover comes along with a strategic advantage and results in higher profits. Moreover, a cost advantage strengthens the incumbent. 3.2. Cost advantage for the entrant (δ > 0) This case was excluded by Gelman and Salop (1983) because it can make the Judo limitation obsolete. Proposition 2. If δ > w c 2, the entrant will not limit his capacity. Proof. The entrant can limit his capacity and earn Judo profits π JAsymC 1. If he does not limit his capacity, the incumbent will always match p 1 as long as p 1 c 2. Setting a price p F 1 orcec = c 2 ɛ, the entrant can force the incumbent to stay out of the market. In this case, any capacity limitation becomes obsolete, i.e. the entrant sets k F orcec = D. Using this strategy, the entrant earns π1 F orcec = (c 2 ɛ c 1 )D. The forcing strategy is beneficial for the entrant if π1 F orcec π JAsymC 1. After some calculations, this condition yields lim ɛ 0 δ > w c 2. For parameter values such that this condition holds, capacity limitation is no longer the profit maximizing entry strategy. If the cost advantage of the entrant is sufficiently high, he can destroy the strategic advantage of the incumbent by pricing below her marginal cost. 4. Asymmetry in product quality We assume that product quality is perfectly represented by consumers WTP and therefore consider w i as the quality of firm i s product. For the further analysis, we denote η i = w i c i as the social benefit of firm i s product. We also define κ = η 2 η 1 as the difference in social benefit between firms products. If κ > 0, the incumbent s product provides a higher social benefit and vice versa. 4

4.1. No quality advantage for the entrant (κ > 0) Proposition 3. Under Assumptions 1 to 3, the equilibrium price and capacity choices in the asymmetric demand game satisfy p JAsymW 1 = (w 1 + c 1 ) /2, k JAsymW = η 1 D/2η 2 and p JAsymW 2 = w 2. Proof. The proof follows a similar reasoning as that of Proposition 1. Knowing the entrant s price p 1 and capacity k, the incumbent may either match the social benefit of the entrant s product (p 2 = w 2 w 1 + p 1 ) or accommodate (p 2 > w 2 w 1 + p 1 ). In the first case, the incumbent serves the entire market and earns a profit of π2 MatchW (p 2 ) = (w 2 w 1 + p 1 c 2 )D. In the second case, the incumbent serves only the residual demand and therefore maximizes her profit π2 ResidW = (w 2 c 2 ) ( D k ). Because the entrant has to ensure that entry is accommodated, he must choose a pair (p 1, k) that fulfills the condition that the incumbent s profit from accommodation is not smaller than her profit from entry deterrence, i.e. π2 MatchW π2 ResidW. Let θ(k) denote the function that maps the greatest p 1 that fulfills the condition for each k. Then, the entrant maximizes π 1 (p 1, k) = (p 1 c 1 )k w.r.t. p 1 θ(k). As Gelman and Salop (1983) derive that the constraint holds with equality in equilibrium, one can derive the condition for the optimal capacity k as 0 = θ(k ) + k θ (k ) C (k ). This determines equilibrium prices p 1 = θ(k ) and also p 2 = argmax π ResidW 2 (k ). For the assumptions made, equilibrium profits are π JAsymW 1 = η1d/4η 2 2 and π JAsymW 2 = (2η 2 η 1 ) D/2. We can see that each firm s profit increases in the social benefit of its own product whereas it decreases in the social benefit of the other firm s product. 4.2. Quality advantage for the entrant (κ < 0) Proposition 4. If η 1 > 2η 2, the entrant will not limit his capacity. Proof. The entrant can limit his capacity and earn Judo profits π JAsymW 1. If he does not limit his capacity, the incumbent will always set a price p 2 = w 2 w 1 + p 1 to match the net benefit that the entrant s product provides to the consumers. Of course, the incumbent cannot set a price p 2 < c 2. Setting a price p F 1 orcew = w 1 w 2 +c 2 ɛ, the entrant can force the incumbent to stay out of the market. In this case, any capacity limitation becomes obsolete, i.e. the entrant sets k F orcew = D. Using this strategy, the entrant earns π1 F orcew = (w 1 w 2 + c 2 ɛ c 1 )D. The forcing strategy is beneficial for the entrant if π1 F orcew π JAsymW 1. After some calculations, this condition 5

yields lim ɛ 0 η 1 > 2η 2. For parameter values such that this condition holds, capacity limitation is no longer the profit maximizing entry strategy. If the social benefit of the entrant s product is sufficiently high, he can destroy the strategic advantage of the incumbent by pricing her out of the market. 5. Concluding remarks The results of this study are derived under the main assumptions of perfect substitutability and fixed market demand. The first assumption is crucial for the existence of Judo-type market outcomes. With horizontal product differentiation, a first mover earns positive profits in a sequential price competition even without capacity limitation, see for example Furth and Kovenock (1993). In contrast, the assumption of fixed market demand is non-crucial. Equilibrium characteristics remain the same with linear demand, however, outcomes become analytically less tractable. 4 Finally, as Gelman and Salop (1983) show, the assumption of efficient rationing only alters the distribution of equilibrium profits, but not the structure of equilibrium market outcomes. The results for the asymmetric settings derived in this article provide a basis for future work. I derive that the social benefit of a firm s product has a strong impact on firms profits. Therefore, it would be interesting to study a situation comparable to that in Motta (1993), where product quality is not exogenously given but firms determine their product quality by costly investments. Aligned with that, one could model market demand in dependence of products quality. Boccard and Wauthy (2009), for example, show that quality reduction and capacity limitation can be strategic substitutes. They study a game where an entrant commits to a quality and a capacity before a simultaneous price competition with the dominant market incumbent. By assumption, the incumbent in their model always sets the maximum quality level. The entrant can only choose to reduce quality. Obviously, both capacity limitation and quality reduction relax price competition in this setting. They show that in equilibrium, it is more advantageous for the entrant to limit his capacity and imitate the quality of the incumbent than choosing 4 For settings with asymmetric cost and linear demand, for example, equilibrium prices, capacity and profits can only be derived numerically. 6

a large capacity but reducing quality. Because my model also considers entrants offering potentially higher quality than the incumbent, the equilibrium result with endogenous quality choice might differ from that of Boccard and Wauthy (2009). A further model extension might include fixed market entry cost. Entry cost can create incentives for the entrant to turn his first mover position into a strategic advantage by setting limit prices. Typically, limit prices are assumed to be an entry-deterrence option of the incumbent (Milgrom and Roberts, 1982) but in the setting with an advantaged entrant, this idea can be reversed. Acknowledgements I am very grateful to Abdolkarim Sadrieh for helpful comments and suggestions. References Allen, B., Deneckere, R., Faith, T., Kovenock, D., 2000. Capacity precommitment as a barrier to entry: a bertrand-edgeworth approach. Economic Theory 15, 501 530. Boccard, N., Wauthy, X., 2009. Entry accommodation under multiple commitment strategies : judo economics revisited. CORE Discussion Papers 2009050, Université catholique de Louvain, Center for Operations Research and Econometrics (CORE). Cracau, D., Sadrieh, A., 2013. Coexistence of small and dominant firms in bertrand competition: judo economics in the lab. FEMM Working Papers 13001, Otto-von-Guericke University Magdeburg, Faculty of Economics and Management. Díaz, A. G., González, R. H., Kujal, P., 2009. List pricing and discounting in a bertrand-edgeworth duopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization 27 (6), 719 727. Furth, D., Kovenock, D., 1993. Price leadership in a duopoly with capacity constraints and product differentiation. Journal of Economics 57 (1), 1 35. 7

Gelman, J. R., Salop, S. C., 1983. Judo economics: capacity limitation and coupon competition. Bell Journal of Economics 14 (2), 315 325. Milgrom, P., Roberts, J., 1982. Limit pricing and entry under incomplete information: an equilibrium analysis. Econometrica 50 (2), 443 459. Motta, M., 1993. Endogenous quality choice: price vs. quantity competition. Journal of Industrial Economics 41 (2), 113 131. Sørgard, L., 1995. Judo economics reconsidered: capacity limitation, entry and collusion. International Journal of Industrial Organization 15, 349 368. Thomas, L. A., 1999. Incumbent firms response to entry: price, advertising, and new product introduction. International Journal of Industrial Organization 17 (4), 527 555. 8

Otto von Guericke University Magdeburg Faculty of Economics and Management P.O. Box 4120 39016 Magdeburg Germany Tel.: +49 (0) 3 91 / 67-1 85 84 Fax: +49 (0) 3 91 / 67-1 21 20 www.ww.uni-magdeburg.de