Chapter 2. The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply. Overview

Similar documents
Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

Chapter 10: Monopoly

Homework 4 Economics

microeconomics II first module

IB Economics Competitive Markets: Demand and Supply 1.4: Price Signals and Market Efficiency

Chapter 9. The Instruments of Trade Policy

Chapter 2: The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply. Multiple Choice Questions

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

1. Welfare economics is the study of a. the well-being of less fortunate people. b. welfare programs in the United States.

S11Microeconomics, Exam 3 Answer Key. Instruction:

1. You are given the following joint PPF for 3 individuals: Sarah, John, and Michael.

EC2004: International Trade Revision Topics.

The Basics of Supply and Demand

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

The Basics of Supply and Demand

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Economics 102 Summer 2015 Answers to Homework #2 Due Tuesday, June 30, 2015

Price = The Interaction of Supply and Demand WEDNESDAY, FEBRUARY 17 THURSDAY, FEBRUARY 18

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

1) Your answer to this question is what form of the exam you had. The answer is A if you have form A. The answer is B if you have form B etc.

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

MONOPOLY SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS: Quick Quizzes

Name. I Short Answers (15 points).

International business chapter 5 AN OVERVIEW OF TRADE THEORY. The benefits of trade. The pattern of International Trade.

Market Equilibrium, the Price Mechanism and Market Efficiency. Chapter 3

Problem Set #2 - Answers. Due February 2, 2000

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

Part I: PPF, Opportunity Cost, Trading prices, Comparative and Absolute Advantage

1. Suppose that policymakers have been convinced that the market price of cheese is too low.

CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

Chapter Summary and Learning Objectives

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

Chapter 2 The Basics of Supply and Demand

Course notes for EE394V Restructured Electricity Markets: Market Power

Econ 200: Lecture 6 October 14, 2014

Chapter 28 The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

Solution. Solution. Consumer and Producer Surplus

Supply and Demand. Objective 8.04

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Chapter 13 Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Other examples of monopoly include Australia Post.

58.5% 17.3% 17.0% 7.1%

2. For a competitive market, which of the following statements is correct?

2010 Pearson Education Canada

Linear Cost, Revenue, Profit, Supply, and Demand

1. The Heckscher Olin model emphasizes as the source of comparative advantage.

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Answers to Homework #6 Due Tuesday, Dec 10, 2013

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

Fundamentals of Markets

A Planned Course Statement for. Economics, AP. Length of Period (mins.) 41 Total Clock Hours: 123. Periods per Cycle: 6 Length of Course (yrs.) 1.

Prepared by Iordanis Petsas To Accompany. by Paul R. Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld

Homework 2 Answer Key

After studying this chapter you will be able to

Name: Eddie Jackson. Course & Section: BU Mid-term

Review Questions. Unions and Collective Bargaining. Choose the letter that represents the BEST response.

Handout. Ekonomi Manajerial [EMKU4402] Drs. Wihandaru SP, M.Si. Fak. Ekonomi / Manajemen

Chapter 6: Combining Supply and Demand

ECON 1000 D. Come to the PASS workshop with your mock exam complete. During the workshop you can work with other students to review your work.

EC101 DD/EE Practice Final December 16/19, 2017 Version 09

Essential Graphs for Microeconomics

Perfectly Competitive Supply. Chapter 6. Learning Objectives

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Instructions: must Repeat this answer on lines 37, 38 and 39. Questions:

Economics : Principles of Microeconomics Spring 2014 Instructor: Robert Munk April 24, Final Exam

1. Demand: willingness to buy a good or service and the ability to pay for it; how much of an item an individual is willing to purchase at each price

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Cost ATC AVC MC Output 2

Economics 1012A Introduction to Macroeconomics Spring 2006 Dr. R. E. Mueller First Midterm Examination September 28, 2006

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

CHAPTER 2 FOUNDATIONS OF MODERN TRADE THEORY: COMPARATIVE ADVANTAGE

AS/ECON AF Answers to Assignment 1 October 2007

1. Fill in the missing blanks ( XXXXXXXXXXX means that there is nothing to fill in this spot):

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

CHAPTER 3 SUPPLY AND DEMAND: AN INITIAL LOOK

Study Questions. Lecture 4 Modern Theories and Additional Effects of Trade

Lecture 7 - Food Stamps: The Whitmore Study

Microeconomics. More Tutorial at

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 7, 2017 Version 01

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Demand, Supply, and Market Equilibrium

ECON 102 Kagundu Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Chapter 5: Supply Section 3

CHAPTER 2: DEMAND AND SUPPLY

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

Demand, Supply, and Equilibrium

Text transcription of Chapter 4 The Market Forces of Supply and Demand

An Evaluation of the Proposed Procurement Auction for the Purchase of Medicare Equipment: Experimental Tests of the Auction Architecture 1

Appendix A. The horizontal axis measures both GDP and Sales. The vertical axis measures the average price level.

Chapter 14 Perfectly competitive Market

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

Making choices in a world of scarcity means we must pass up some goods and services. Every decision we make is a trade-off:

Transcription:

Chapter 2 The Basic Theory Using Demand and Supply Overview This chapter indicates why we study theories of international trade and presents the basic theory using supply and demand curves. Trade is important to individual consumers, to workers and other factor owners, to firms, and therefore to the whole economy. The box Trade Is Important provides useful data about the types of products traded and the increasing role of trade in national economies. Trade is also contentious, with perpetual battles over government policies toward trade. To understand the controversy, we need to develop theories of why people trade as they do. It is useful to organize the analysis of international trade by contrasting a world of no trade with a world of free trade, leaving analysis of intermediate cases (e.g., non-prohibitive tariffs) for Chapter 8-14. The analysis seeks to answer four key questions about international trade: 1. Why do countries trade? What determines the pattern of trade? 2. How does trade affect production and consumption in each country? 3. What are the gains (or losses) for a country as a whole from trading? 4. What are the effects of trade on different groups in a country? Are there groups that gain and other groups that lose? Theories of international trade provide answers to these four questions. Basic demand and supply analysis can be used to provide early answers to these four questions, as well as to introduce concepts that can be used in more elaborate theories. Using motorbikes as an example, the chapter first reviews the basic analysis of both demand (the demand curve and the role of the product s price, other influences on quantity demanded, movements along the demand curve and shifts in the demand curve, and the price elasticity of demand as a measure of responsiveness) and supply (the supply curve, the role of marginal cost, other influences on quantity supplied, movements along the supply curve and shifts in the supply curve, and the price elasticity of supply). It pays special attention to the meaning and measurement of consumer surplus and producer surplus. This section, which focuses on review and development of basic tools, ends with the picture of market equilibrium in a national market with no trade as the intersection of the domestic demand curve and the domestic supply curve. The remainder of the chapter examines the use of supply and demand curves to analyze international trade. If there are two national markets for a product and no trade between them, it is likely that the product s price will differ between the two markets. Someone should notice the difference and try to profit by arbitrage between the two markets. If governments permit free trade, then the export supply from the initially low-priced market (the rest of the world in the textbook example) can satisfy the import demand in the initially high-priced market (the United States in the textbook example), and the world shifts to a free-trade equilibrium. We can show this free trade equilibrium by deriving the supply-of-exports curve for the rest of the world and 9

the demand-for-imports curve for the United States. The international market for the product clears at the intersection of the export-supply and import-demand curves, indicating the equilibrium international or world price and the quantity traded. This equilibrium world price also becomes the domestic price in each country with free trade. The same set of three graphs (the two national markets and the international-trade market) is used to show the effects of the shift from no-trade to free-trade on different groups in each country and to show the net gains from trade for each nation. In the importing country consumers of the product gain consumer surplus and producers of the product lose producer surplus. Using the one-dollar, one-vote metric, the country as a whole gains, because the gain in consumer surplus is larger than the loss of producer surplus. In the exporting country producers of the product gain producer surplus and consumers of the product lose consumer surplus. The analysis shows that the country as a whole gains because the gain in producer surplus is larger than the loss of consumer surplus. Furthermore, the country that gains more from the shift to free trade is the country whose price changes more the country with the less elastic trade curve (import demand or export supply). Tips We believe that this chapter is an excellent way to introduce the analysis of trade. The four questions about trade focus student attention on key issues that are interesting to most of them. Students then get a quick payoff through the use of the familiar supply-demand framework. By the end of this short chapter we have preliminary answers to all four trade questions. We have also laid a solid foundation for the analysis of trade using supply and demand curves, the approach that will receive the most attention in Chapter 8-14 on trade policies. In class presentations it may be useful to show the graphs in a sequence, perhaps using a series of slides. After presenting the review of demand and supply and the national market equilibrium with no trade, the following sequence works well. 1. Two national market graphs with no trade, one with a high no-trade price (the United States), and one with a low no-trade price (the rest of the world, or ROW). Question to the class: If you were the first person to notice this situation, could you make a profit? This is a good way to motivate international trade driven by arbitrage. 2. The U.S. national market graph and the international market graph. Question to the class: Let s say that the United States is willing to open up to free trade and integrate into the world market. If it does this, the world price will also be the price within the United States. How much will the United States want to import? It depends on what the world price is. The instructor can pick one or two hypothetical world price(s) (below the no-trade U.S. price), and measure the gap between domestic quantity demanded and domestic quantity supplied. This is the U.S. demand for imports, and these import quantity-price combinations can be used to plot the U.S. demand-for-imports curve in the international market. 3. A graph of the international market and the ROW national market. A comparable discussion to item 2 above, to derive the supply-of-exports curve. 4. Superimpose the graphs from item 2 on the graphs from item 3. Question to the class: What will happen with free trade? When there is ongoing free trade, what is the equilibrium world 10

price? This set of three graphs can be used to show the free-trade equilibrium: world price, quantity traded, and quantities produced and consumed in each country. 5. A single graph showing the U.S. national market, to contrast no trade with free trade. Questions to the class: What group is made happier by the shift from no trade to free trade? What group is a loser? Can we somehow say that the country gains from free trade? 6. A single graph showing the ROW national market, with the same questions in item 5. The next Chapters 3-7 present additional theories of trade. The figure shown on the accompanying page provides a summary of the key features of these theories. It may be useful to copy and distribute this figure to your students. If it is distributed when the class begins to study the material, it can serve as a roadmap. If it is distributed when the class finishes the lectures on the material, it can serve as a summary and review. For instructors who want to begin with the discussion of absolute and comparative advantage rather than with the supply-and-demand framework that focuses on a single product, this should be possible. After covering the introductory material (the first two pages of Chapter 2, and, possibly, the two boxes in the chapter), the course would skip to Chapter 3. The remaining material from Chapter 2 on the supply and demand analysis can be inserted right after Chapter 4 s section referring to analysis using supply and demand curves, or this material can be presented as a separate topic elsewhere in the course. Chapter 2 has the first of five boxes about the global financial and economic crisis that began in 2007 and became dramatically worse in 2008. The box The Trade Mini-Collapse of 2009 documents and discusses the sharp decline in global trade that began in late 2008 (and the bounce back that occurred in 2010). With the series of boxes and the discussion of the global crisis in the final section of Chapter 21, an instructor can weave discussions of the global crisis and its aftermath throughout a course. Suggested answer to case study discussion question Trade Is Important: For most countries during the past several decades, trade has become more important in the economy. A country s total international trade (exports and imports) has risen as a percentage of national GDP for most countries. Whatever the effects of international trade, they have probably become larger or more pronounced. As discussed in this chapter (and subsequent chapters), some people in the country benefit from international trade, while other people in the country tend to be harmed by international trade. If trade often creates winners and losers, then trade has probably become more controversial as it has become more important in the economy. Suggested answers to end of chapter questions and problems 1. Consumer surplus is the net gain to consumers from being able to buy a product through a market. It is the difference between the highest price someone is willing to pay for each unit of the product and the actual market price that is paid, summed over all units that are demanded and consumed. The highest price that someone is willing to pay for the unit indicates the value that the buyer attaches to that unit. To measure consumer surplus for a product using real-world data, three major pieces of information are needed: (1) the 11

market price, (2) the quantity demanded, and (3) the slope (or shape) of the demand curve in terms of how quantity demanded would change if the market price increased. Consumer surplus could then be measured as the area below the demand curve and above the market-price line. 2. Producer surplus is the net gain to producers from being able to sell a product through a market. It is the difference between the lowest price at which some producer is willing to supply each unit of the product and the actual market price that is paid, summed over all units that are produced and sold. The lowest price at which someone is willing to supply the unit just covers the extra (marginal) cost of producing that unit. To measure producer surplus for a product using real world data, three major pieces of information are needed. First, the market price. Second, the quantity supplied. Third, some information about the slope (or shape) of the supply curve. How would quantity supplied change if the market price decreased? Or, what are the extra costs of producing each unit up to the actual quantity supplied? Producer surplus could then be measured as the area below the market price line and above the supply curve. 3. The country s supply of exports is the amount by which the country s domestic quantity supplied exceeds the country s domestic quantity demanded. The supply-of-exports curve is derived by finding the difference between domestic quantity supplied and domestic quantity demanded for each possible market price for which quantity supplied exceeds quantity demanded. The supply-of-exports curve shows the quantity that the country would want to export for each possible international market price. 4. The country's demand for imports is the amount by which the country's domestic quantity demanded exceeds the country's domestic quantity supplied. The demand-for-imports curve is derived by finding the difference between domestic quantity demanded and domestic quantity supplied, for each possible market price for which quantity demanded exceeds quantity supplied. The demand-for-imports curve shows the quantity that the country would want to import for each possible international market price. 5. There is no domestic market for winter coats in this tropical country, but there is a domestic supply curve. If the world price for coats is above the minimum price at which the country would supply any coats (the price at which the supply curve hits the price axis), then in free trade the country would produce and export coats. The country gains from trade because it creates producer surplus the area above the supply curve and below the international price line, up to the intersection (which indicates the quantity that the country will produce and export). 6. If there were no exports of scrap iron and steel, the domestic market would clear at the price at which domestic quantity demanded equals domestic quantity supplied. But the United States does export scrap iron and steel. The extra demand from foreign buyers increases the market price of scrap iron and steel. Domestic users of scrap iron and steel pay a higher price than they would if there were no exports. Thus, some support a prohibition on these exports, in order to lower the market price of the scrap that they buy. 12

7. It is true that opening trade bids prices into equality between countries. With a competitive market this also means that marginal costs are equal between countries. But ongoing trade is necessary to maintain this equilibrium. If trade were to stop, the world would return to the no-trade equilibrium. Then prices would differ, and there would be an incentive for arbitrage. The ongoing trade in the free-trade equilibrium is why prices are equalized trade is not self-eliminating. 8. a. With free trade at $100 per barrel: Domestic production QS: 100 = 4 + 40QS, or Qs = 2.4 billion barrels. Domestic consumption QD: 100 = 364 48QD, or QD = 5.5 billion barrels. Price ($/barrel) S US 100 D US 2.4 5.5 Quantity (billions of barrels) b. With no imports, domestic quantity supplied must equal domestic quantity demanded (both equal to QN) at the domestic equilibrium price PN: 364-48QN = 4 + 40QN, or QN = 4.09 billion barrels produced and consumed. Using one of the equations, we can calculate that the domestic price would be almost $168 per barrel. Price ($/barrel) S US 168 100 o i l D US 2.4 4.09 5.5 Quantity (billions of barrels) c. Domestic producers of oil would gain, receiving an increase of producer surplus shown as area o in the graph. Domestic consumers of oil would lose, experiencing a loss of consumer surplus shown as area o + i + l in the graph. 13

9. The demand curve DUS shifts to the right. The U.S. demand-for-imports curve Dm shifts to the right. The equilibrium international price rises above 1,000. It is shown by the intersection of the new U.S. Dm curve and the original Sx curve. 10. The supply curve SUS shifts down (or to the right). The U.S. demand-for-imports curve Dm shifts to the left (or down). The equilibrium international price decreases below 1,000 it is shown by the intersection of the new U.S. Dm curve and the original Sx curve. 11. For the first country, for any world free-trade equilibrium price above $2.00 per kilogram, the country will want to export raisins. For the other country, for any world free-trade equilibrium price above $3.20 per kilogram, this other country will also want to export raisins. With only sellers (exporters) internationally and no buyers (importers) internationally, the international market cannot be in equilibrium. Instead, at this high price, there is an excess supply of raisins. As the graphs below show, at the price of $3.50 per kilogram, both countries want to export at that price, domestic quantity supplied exceeds domestic quantity demanded for each country. 12. We can still use the basic analysis from this chapter, but changes in consumer surplus count for more than changes in producer surplus. We can examine this case as a deviation from the one-dollar, one-vote metric. Does the importing country still gain from trade? For the one-dollar, one-vote metric, the importing country gains from trade because the increase in consumer surplus is larger than the loss in producer surplus. If we give more weight to the change in consumer surplus, then, yes, the importing country still gains from trade. Giving more weight to consumer well-being reinforces the net gain from trade. Does the exporting country still gain from trade? For the one-dollar, one-vote metric, the exporting country gains from trade because the increase in producer surplus is larger than the loss in consumer surplus. If we give more weight to the change in consumer surplus, then we are no longer sure that the exporting country gains from trade. Giving more weight to consumer well-being increases the perceived size of the consumer surplus loss, 14

relative to the size of the producer surplus gain. If consumer well-being is sufficiently more important, then we would conclude the exporting country has a net loss from trade. 13. a. With no international trade, equilibrium requires that domestic quantity demanded (QD) equals domestic quantity supplied (QS). Setting the two equations equal to each other, we can find the equilibrium price with no trade: 350 (P/2) = -200 + 5P The equilibrium no-trade price is P = 100. Using one of the equations, we find that the notrade quantity is 300. b. At a price of 120, Belgium s quantity demanded is 290 and its quantity supplied is 400. With free trade Belgium exports 110 units. c. Belgian consumer surplus declines. With no trade it is a larger triangle below the demand curve and above the 100 price line. With free trade it is a smaller triangle below the demand curve and above the 120 price line. Belgian producer surplus increases. With no trade it is a smaller triangle above the supply curve and below the 100 price line. With free trade it is a larger triangle above the supply curve and below the 120 price line. The net national gain from trade is the difference between the gain of producer surplus and the loss of consumer surplus. This net national gain is a triangle whose base is the quantity traded (110) and whose height is the change in price (120 100 = 20), so the total gain is 1,100. 14. a. In the graphs below, the free trade equilibrium price is PF, the price at which the quantity of exports supplied by Country I equals the quantity of imports demanded by Country II. (The quantity-of-imports demanded curve for country II is the same as the country's regular demand curve.) This world price is above the no-trade price in country I. The quantity traded with free trade is QT. P P S P XI S I e PF P P F P a b c c F NI e Q T D D D I MII II Q Q Q Q Q T T b. In Country I producer surplus increases by area a + b + c, and consumer surplus falls by area a + b. The net national gain from free trade is area c. In country II consumer surplus increases by area e and this is also the net national gain from trade. Because there is no domestic production in Country II with or without trade, there is no change in producer surplus. 15

A guide to the trade theories of Chapter 2-7 What Forces Determine Name of Theory Trade Flows? Some Key Assumptions A. The basic theory Productivities Competition in all markets (Chapters 2-5) Factor Supplies Constant or increasing costs Product demands Any number of production factors (types of labor, land, etc.) B. Supply-oriented theories of trade (special cases of the basic theory, with the demand side neutral): 1. Absolute Absolute Competition in all markets advantage productivities Constant marginal costs (in Chapter 3) Only one factor (labor) 2. Comparative Relative Competition in all markets advantage productivities Constant marginal costs (in Chapter 3) Only one factor (labor) 3. Factor proportions Relative factor Competition in all markets (Heckscher- endowments Increasing marginal costs Ohlin theory, Small number of factors in Chapters 4-5) Technology neutral C. Additional theories of trade: 1. Monopolistic Product differentiation Imperfect competition competition Moderate scale De-emphasize factor (Krugman and economies supplies others, in Chapter 6) 2. Global oligopoly Substantial internal Imperfect competition (in Chapter 6) scale economies De-emphasize factor History, luck, or supplies government policy 3. External economies Substantial external Competition (in Chapter 6) scale economies De-emphasize factor Large home market, supplies history, luck, or government policy 4. Technology differences, Technological innovation Competition including product Technological "age" of Importance of cycle (Vernon and the industry research and others, in Chapter 7) development 16