Vertical Mergers. The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit.

Similar documents
Unit 7. Firm behaviour and market structure: monopoly

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Chapter 14 Oligopoly and Monopoly

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

Lecture 12. Monopoly

2007 Thomson South-Western

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

Monopolistic Markets. Regulation

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2004

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Chapter 11. Monopoly. I think it s wrong that only one company makes the game Monopoly. Steven Wright

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH PERFECT COMPETITION.

11.1 Monopoly Profit Maximization

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Textbook Media Press. CH 12 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

Agenda. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 1. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 2. Marginal Revenue. 3. Profit Maximization Exercise

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Many sellers: There are many firms competing for the same group of customers.

Chapter 28 The Labor Market: Demand, Supply, and Outsourcing

Economics 500: Microeconomic Theory

Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises. Global Economy: Firms in the. Chapter 8

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

Economics of Industrial Organization. Problem Sets

Professor David Popp Solutions to Problem Set #6 Fall 2018

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

2. What is Taylor s marginal utility per dollar spent on the 2 nd race? a. 2 b. 3 c. 4 d. 5

Chapter 10: Answers to Problems

Unit 13 AP Economics - Practice

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

Economics 101 Spring 2014 International Trade. Problem Set 3. May 20, Horizontal Foreign Direct Investment

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

CHAPTER 8. Managing in Competitive, Monopolistic, and Monopolistically Competitive Markets

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

Monopoly Behavior or Price Discrimination Chapter 25

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics

Chapter 13 Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

1. For a monopolist, present the standard diagram showing the following:

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

When economies of scale exist, large firms may be more efficient than small firms, and the industry may consist of a monopoly or a few large firms.

Test 3 Econ 3144 Fall 2010 Dr. Rupp 31 Multiple Choice Questions Signature I have neither given nor received aid on this exam

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Quiz 10. For questions 1-9, consider firms using a technology with cost and marginal cost functions:

Economics. Monopolistic Perfect Competition. Monopolistic Competition. Monopolistic Competition 11/29/2013. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

ECON 2100 (Summer 2014 Sections 08 & 09) Exam #3D

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Final Exam December 8, 2006

Imperfect Competition (Monopoly) Chapters 15 Mankiw

Department of Economics, University of Oslo. ECON4820 Spring Last modified:

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

MARKETS. Part Review. Reading Between the Lines SONY CORP. HAS CUT THE U.S. PRICE OF ITS PLAYSTATION 2

EXAMINATION #4 VERSION C General Equilibrium and Market Power November 24, 2015

Thanksgiving Handout Economics 101 Fall 2000

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 6. I. Choose the correct answer (each question carries 1 mark)

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

Monopoly and How It Arises

ASSIGNMENT 3 ECON 101 FALL parts 3 marks each plus 1 for name= 100 points Due: Nov 30 in class

Problem Set 4 Eco 112, Fall 2011 Chapters covered: Ch. 8 and Ch. 9 (up to slide 15 Price Discrimination) Due date: October 20, 2011

Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy: Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises

iv. The monopolist will receive economic profits as long as price is greater than the average total cost

Preview. Introduction. Chapter 8. Firms in the Global Economy: Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises

Chapter 8 Firms in the Global Economy: Export Decisions, Outsourcing, and Multinational Enterprises

Monday, October 15: Monopoly and Marginal Revenue

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

Economics. Monopolistic Competition. Firms in Competitive Markets. Monopolistic Competition 11/22/2012. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Lesson 5: Market Structure (II) 5.1 The Monopoly

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Market structures Perfect competition

Monopoly. Firm s equilibrium. Muhammad Rafi Khan

TUTORIAL 10 Welfare. Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring Massimo Scotti

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

ECON 2100 (Summer 2015 Sections 07 & 08) Exam #3A

ECON 4550 (Fall 2011) Exam 1

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Refer to the information provided in Figure 12.1 below to answer the questions that follow. Figure 12.1

Lesson-33. Pricing Strategy

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

Final Exam - Solutions

Monopoly single producer strong barriers to entry price marker no close substitute discriminates the price

CHAPTER 5 FIRM PRODUCTION, COST, AND REVENUE

Perfectly Competitive Markets, Market Equilibrium, Welfare Economics, Efficiency, and Market Failure

Professor Christina Romer. LECTURE 9 MONOPOLY February 13, 2018

Transcription:

Vertical Mergers Suppose that Grapefruit Computers makes a unique product that is distributed exclusively by the retailer Better Buy. Both firms act as monopolists to maximize their profits. Consumers have a demand curve at retail given by P=1000-Q. Grapefruit has constant marginal costs of $100. Better Buy has marginal costs comprised of $1 00 related to its sales activity (e.g. labor costs) and it also incurs the cost of purchasing its computers from the manufacturer. a) In the first part of this question we will investigate the profit maximizing behavior of the 2 firms: i) If Grapefruit sets a producer price of PU for the retailer which the retailer takes as given, what is the retailer's marginal cost curve? The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit. ii) What is the profit maximizing quantity of sales for Better Buy, for any given price Pu? How can we interpret the equation you have derived? Start in the retail market and take the price PU as given. From the point of view of the retailer the quantity will be chosen according to MR=MC implying a markup of price over input costs. If demand is P=1000-Q then MR is P=1000-2Q Thus the profit maximization decision of the retailer is: But note that this curve only determines the quantity of sales in terms of the producer price PU. In other words this is precisely the DEMAND CURVE of the retailer from the point of view of the producer. iii) What is the marginal revenue curve for Grapefruit, and hence the profit maximizing quantity of output? PU = 900-2Q is the demand curve from above Since we also have monopoly power in this market the producer sets its price by considering its marginal revenue curve - this is the DOUBLE MARGINALIZATION

Solving Grapefruit's problem: iv) What are the producer and retail price of the computer, and hence the profits of each firm? For the producer price we go to the demand curve for the producers; So the producer marks up the price by $400 over costs. In the final goods market the retail price is: So the retailer introduces another markup of $200 over costs of $600. We can calculate the profit of the two firms: Grapefruit profit = 200*400=80000 Better Buy profit = 200*200=40000

b) Now we will proceed to examine whether this vertical structure is maximizing its profits. i) Suppose that Grapefruit could sell its computers directly to consumers, incurring the same retail costs as Better Buy in part a). What would be the profit maximizing price and quantity now? If the computers could be sold directly the full marginal cost would be $200. Grapefruit would act as a profit maximizing monopolist and set The price is given by the demand curve, so P=1000-400=600 ii) What are the profits of the firm? Profits are 400x(600-200)=160,000 iii) If Grapefruit cannot create its own retail network, but has to rely on that of Better Buy can it create value by buying out the retailer? The profits of the vertical structure are larger when there is only a single firm making the pricing decisions. In particular the total producer surplus created by the structure is 160,000 compared to 80,000+40,000=120,000 in the original scenario. A merger here would make sense. Since 40,000 value can be created, Grapefruit can offer Better Buy anything from 40,000 to 80,000 - any offer in this range is a Pareto improvement - both firms benefit. In fact either firm could buy the other: 1 Total Profit 1 Profit Grapefruit 1 Profit Better Buv I Separate 120,000 80,000 40,000 Grapefruit 160,000 160,000-P>80,000 P>40,000 Purchases for 40.000<P<80,000 1 Better Buy I Purchases for 160,000 P>80,000 I 160,000-P>40,000

It does not make any difference from an efficiency perspective which firm buys the other - the same value is created in each case. There is a range of selling prices that would leave both firms better off, reflecting precisely the fact that there is a gain from trade. Of course the actual selling price will determine how that gain from trade is divided between the two firms. We can think of this in terms of the Coase theorem that we discussed in the section on externalities - with a small number of agents and a situation with an externality, we would expect that negotiation between the parties would come up with a way of internalizing the externality. As is usual with the Coase theorem, there can be many solutions - they all reach the efficient outcome but can differ in terms of the distribution of surplus. iv) What is the economic rationale for the merger? Why is the vertical structure inefficient and how does the merger create value? The vertical structure is inefficient because of the DOUBLE MARGINALIZATION. There is an externality at work here. The retailer takes the producer price as given and maximizes its profits. As it is a monopolist it does so by restricting the quantity of sales. Although this is profit maximizing for Better Buy, it does not take into account that the restriction of sales reduces the profits of Grapefruit, since Grapefruit is also earning a margin on its sales. This negative externality is not taken into account in the pricing at retail level, and since negative externalities are done to excess there is too little output sold relative to the fully profit maximizing arrangement. The merger, by rationalizing the decision making, essentially removing the intermediate pricing step allows this externality to be fully internalized so the efficient outcome for the firms together can be reached. We can see that the inefficiency is related to the monopoly pricing by comparing the outcome if the retail sector were competitive. If retail is competitive then so the demand curve upstream is: And profit maximization implies that

900-2Q=100 so that Q=400 - the profit maximizing quantity for the structure as a whole. Equivalently, suppose the computer manufacturer market is competitive so that Grapefruit cannot charge a mark-up. The marginal costs of Better Buy are $200 and the MR curve from the market demand is P=1000-2Q. Profit Maximization again gives 1000-2Q=200 and Q=400 the efficient quantity of output. c) Thinking about welfare more generally, the merger allows the firms to exploit their monopoly power more effectively. Does this come at the cost of consumer surplus? Should the merger be permitted on the grounds of economic efficiency? What are the welfare implications of this merger? Compared to perfect competition, consumers always suffer when firms get to exploit their monopoly power. However in the case of double marginalization consumers also gain. The reason is that prices are higher and quantities lower in the non-integrated arrangement - the non-integrated firms restrict output beyond that which a single monopolist would choose - profits actually increase as the firms increase output closer towards the competitive level. This illustrates an important difference between horizontal and vertical mergers. Horizontal mergers will often reduce competition and have negative implications for consumers. Vertical mergers can rationalize the production structure to the benefit of both producers and consumers.