International Comparison of Labor Productivity Distribution for Manufacturing and Non-Manufacturing Firms

Similar documents
1 Business outlook and demand forecast

Section 3 Rising productivity and the role of human capital and organization

An Empirical Analysis of the Effect of Corporate Group Structure on Profitability

Productivity in Japan, the US, and the Major EU Economies: Is Japan Falling Behind?

Kazuyuki Motohashi RIETI and University of Tokyo

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis September 9, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

2011 Input-Output Tables for Japan

Tankan Summary (December 2018) 179th Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan

Tankan Summary (June 2018) 177th Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan

Tankan Summary (September 2018) 178th Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan

Not to be released before 8:50 a.m. on Monday, April 2, 2018

Economics 314 Spring 2006 Final Exam May 10, 2006

Tankan Summary (December 2017) 175th Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan

Appendix A NAICS Codes and Titles

Tankan Summary (September 2017) 174th Short-Term Economic Survey of Enterprises in Japan

College: Department: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID:

Verification of Effectiveness of Employment Information on Productivity Performance in Japanese Companies

Stat ist ics at METI

Economics. In an economy, the production units are called (a) Firm (b) Household (c) Government (d) External Sector

2. Three Key Aggregate Markets

Final Exam - Solutions

AMERICAN AGRICULTURE has become one of

Aggregate Demand & Aggregate Supply

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomics University of California - Davis December 7, 2010 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

in Korean Industries ( ): Estimates from KIP Database

METHODS EXAMINATION - MAY MACROECONOMICS Meyer (chair), Conlin, Doblas Madrid, Wilson, Wooldridge

Midterm 2 - Solutions

The Role of Education for the Economic Growth of Bulgaria

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Markup Pricing and Monetary Policy: A Reexamination of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy under Imperfect Competition

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

NEW TECHNOLOGIES AND LONG-RUN GROWTH. Senior Honors Thesis. Tara Dwivedi. Thesis Advisor: Dr. Stanley Zin

Using this information, we then write the output of a firm as

Paper 11 Urban Economics

Intermediate Macroeconomics

Principles of BABY THOMAS 2016

Notes on Profit Maximization

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

Question 4: How do you find cost and revenue functions?

A Comparison of Contributions to the Canadian Economy of Key Bulk Commodity Shippers and Rail Freight Carriers

Do energy-intensive industries pass through the opportunity cost of CO2 allowances?

Macroeconomics II Unemployment

Automation and the Future of Work. Pascual Restrepo Based on joint work with Daron Acemoglu.

Microeconomics. Microeconomics. Lectures Jan 05&09; 2017

Costs classification,

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

Econ Intermediate Microeconomic Theory College of William and Mary December 12, 2012 John Parman. Final Exam

Economic Growth and Information Technology in the U.S. and Japan

Statistical experience in compiling the input-output tables (IOT) based on the Chilean National Accounts 2008 Benchmark Compilation 1

Japanese Large Corporations Use of Forest Certification in Social Responsibility Reporting

Final Exam - Solutions

Journal of Physics: Conference Series. Related content. Recent citations PAPER OPEN ACCESS

MBA Core Curriculum Course Descriptions

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function and Political Economy

PUBLIC GOODS PROVISION IN RURAL AREA: CASE FROM ZHEJIANGPROVINCE OF CHINA. Pan Weiguang 1 1. INTRODUCTION

WORLD KLEMS AND ASIA KLEMS

Productivity, Output, and Employment. Chapter 3. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Measuring the returns to innovation (1) Prof. Bronwyn H. Hall Globelics Academy May 31/June

ENDOGENOUS REGIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN ROMANIA. A KNOWLEDGE PRODUCTION FUNCTION MODEL

THE 2008 ROUND OF REVISIONS OF THE NON-MANUFACTURING REGULATION (NMR) AND REGULATORY IMPACT (RI) INDICATORS

Economic outcomes of the Kyoto Protocol for New Zealand

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis March 19, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

ECON 450 Development Economics

Lets review Yesterdays Activity.

Chapter 28: Monopoly and Monopsony

Hak K. Pyo (Seoul National University) Hyunbae Chun (Sogang University) Keun Hee Rhee (Korea Productivity Center)

MARNA KEARNEY Energy Research Centre University of cape Town

The goods market. Screen 1

Chapter 1- Introduction

Keywords: macroeconomics, economic growth, human capital, economic policy

Analysis of Inflation/Deflation: Clusters of micro prices matter!

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Some thoughts on productivity and Greece

MEASURING KNOWLEDGE- BASED CAPITAL

Archimedean Upper Conservatory Economics, October 2016

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

DIVERGENCE OF PER CAPITA REAL GROSSSTATEPRODUCTBYSECTOR 1963 to 1986

April An Analysis of Newfoundland and Labrador s Productivity, : Mining, and Oil and Gas Extraction Drives Strong Productivity Growth

UNIT 1 CONCEPT AND SCOPE OF ECONOMICS. J. Alberto Molina J. I. Giménez Nadal

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Macroeconomic Equilibrium: Aggregate Demand and Supply. Economics, 7th Edition Boyes/Melvin

Tetsuya Nakajima. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University. Hideki Nakamura. Faculty of Economics, Osaka City University

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture

ECON 1602 (B 09A): BASIC ECONOMIC CONCEPTS: MICROECONOMICS

Cost Behavior: Analysis and Use

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Final Exam December 8, 2006

Introduction to Labour Economics. Professor H.J. Schuetze Economics 370. What is Labour Economics?

Agricultural Productivity in China: Parametric Distance Function

MARK SCHEME for the October/November 2010 question paper for the guidance of teachers 9708 ECONOMICS

4.2 A Model of Production. 4.1 Introduction. A Model of Production. Setting Up the Model. Chapter 4

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROGRAMME SPECIFIC OUTCOME

THE PRODUCTION FUNCTION

Toru Kikuchi Kobe University. Abstract

The Real Economy. Chapter-2

Practice Exam Questions for Exam 2

ECONOMICS - scarcity and choices

Your Name: UM uniquename. Ford School of Public Policy 555: Microeconomics A Fall 2011 Placement Exam Professor Kevin Stange

Concentrating on the Fall of the Labor Share

Transcription:

Progress of Theoretical Physics Supplement No. 179, 2009 93 International Comparison of Labor Productivity Distribution for Manufacturing and Non-Manufacturing Firms Yuichi Ikeda 1 and Wataru Souma 2 1 Hitachi Research Institute, Tokyo 101-8010, Japan 2 NiCT/ATR CIS, Applied Network Science Lab., Kyoto 619-0288, Japan Labor productivity was studied at the microscopic level in terms of distributions based on individual firm financial data from Japan and the US. A power-law distribution in terms of firms and sector productivity was found in both countries data. The labor productivities were not equal for nation and sectors, in contrast to the prevailing view in the field of economics. It was found that the low productivity of the Japanese non-manufacturing sector reported in macro-economic studies was due to the low productivity of small firms. 1. Introduction The Japanese non-manufacturing sector, which is the service sector in the extended sense of the meaning, was reported to have low productivity in economic studies. 1), 2) Many researchers have cited low productivity as a serious problem of the Japanese economy. For this reason, policy makers, business administrators, and physicists have taken considerable interest in the reasons behind these figures. A recent macro-economic study 3) ranked the labor productivity of all industries in FY2005 (Table I). Japan (JP) ranked 20th, or about 71% that of the United States (US). Moreover, Japanese manufacturers productivity ranked 6th, or about 89% of the US (Table II). The labor productivity of Japanese non-manufacturers is estimated to be about 61% of the US, from the fact that 64% of Japanese GDP is created by non-manufacturers (see Tables I and II (0.36 89% + 0.64x = 71% leads to x = 61%)). In light of this background, we decided to study the labor productivity distribution at the microscopic level in terms of distributions based on individual firm financial data for Japan and the US. Japan s labor productivity and US labor productivity were compared for the manufacturing and non-manufacturing sectors. In the following, first, the economic theory of productivity is briefly described. Then, results of data analyses of the labor productivity distribution are presented. Finally, the discrepancy between the results of the data analysis and economic theory is discussed. 2. Economic theory of productivity The theory of productivity is briefly described to clarify what is expected for the labor productivity in the field of economics. 4), 5) We consider a firm s labor productivity to explain the theory. The following explanation is also valid for the industrial sector. Operating profit Π is defined by

94 Y. Ikeda and W. Souma Table I. Labor Productivity of All Industries in FY2005. Ranking Country Productivity ($/Worker) 1st Luxembourg 104, 610 2nd Norway 97, 275 3rd US 86, 714......... 20th Japan 61, 862 (71% of US) Table II. Labor Productivity of Manufacturers in FY2005. Ranking Country Productivity ($/Worker) 1st Ireland 170, 872 2nd Norway 97, 733 3rd US 96, 962......... 6th Japan 86, 608 (89% of US) Π = py rk wl. (2.1) Here, p, Y, r, K, w, andl are price, value added, interest rate, capital, wage rate, and labor, respectively. Each firm maximizes its profit Π by adjusting L: Π L = p Y L w =0. (2.2) Thus, marginal labor productivity Y/ L satisfies the relation: Y L = w p. (2.3) In equilibrium, the actual wage rate w/p is equal for each firm, which means that there is no arbitrage opportunity for wage rates. Labor moves from firms offering low wages to firms offering high wages by an amount ΔL, as shown in Fig. 1, where the origin of labor of the i th (j th )firmo i (O j ) is the left (right) axis. As a result, the following relation is obtained for firm i and firm j: ( ) ( ) Y Y =. (2.4) L i L j If added value Y is described using the Cobb-Douglass production function, 6) Y = AK α L β, (2.5) where A, α and β are fitting parameters, the marginal labor productivity Y/ L can be rewritten using labor productivity Y/L: Y L = β Y L. (2.6)

International Comparisons of Labor Productivity Distribution 95 Fig. 1. In equilibrium (the right panel), the actual wage rate w/p is equal for each firm, which means that there is no arbitrage opportunity for wage rates. Labor moves from firms offering low wages to firms offering high wages by an amount ΔL. Thus, labor productivity satisfies the following relation for firms i and j: ( ) ( ) Y Y β i = β j. (2.7) L i L j There is a drawback to the use of a simple production function (2.5). If constant returns to scale α + β = 1 is assumed, the following relation between productivity Y/L and capital equipment ratio K/L is obtained: ( ) Y K α L = A. (2.8) L This means that a simple production function provides no information on the size dependence of the productivity. 3. Data analysis of productivity distribution Labor productivity distributions and Pareto indexes were analyzed for JP and US listed firms. Productivities of manufacturing and non-manufacturing firms were compared. Analyzed financial data were Bloomberg data from 1990 to 2003. The analysis used two different definitions of labor productivity: Labor Productivity = Gross Margin, (3.1) Worker Value Added Labor Productivity =. (3.2) Worker Here, gross margin and value added are defined by Gross Margin = Revenue Cost of Goods Sold, (3.3)

96 Y. Ikeda and W. Souma Fig. 2. Scatter plots of gross margin Y, capital K, andlaborl show linear correlations for log transformed variables of gross margin Y, capital K, andlaborl. Value Added = Gross Margin + Total Labor Cost = Gross Margin 1 Labor Share, (3.4) respectively. Note that labor share is a macro-economic quantity. Workers do not include part-time and contract workers. The parameters of the microscopic production function were estimated for JP and US listed firms using the Cobb-Douglass production function (2.5). By taking log transformation of variables in Eq. (2.5), we obtain the relation, log 10 Y t =log 10 A + α log 10 K t + β log 10 L t. (3.5) Scatter plots of gross margin Y, capital K, and labor L are shown in Fig. 2. Linear correlations are observed for log transformed variables of gross margin Y, capital K, and labor L. This means that the Cobb-Douglass production function is an appropriate functional form. Parameters A, α, andβ were estimated using multiregression analysis. Figure 3 shows the parameters obtained for the production function. Manufacturers (both JP and the US) have constant returns to scale (α + β = 1). On the other hand, non-manufacturers (both JP and the US) have decreasing returns to scale (α + β<1). Note that β =0.6 for all cases. Thus, from Eq. (2.7), we can say that labor productivities Y/L for firm i and firm j are equal if an equilibrium state is achieved. Next, the labor productivity of firms was analyzed. Figure 4 plots the aggregated added value created by the listed firms. The vertical axis is aggregated added value divided by gross domestic product (GDP). About half of the GDP is created by listed firms in JP and the US. This means that a large fraction of economy of each nation is covered by the analysis of the listed firms. Figure 5 represents the rank-size plot of labor productivity for firms. Because the horizontal and vertical axes are log scales, the straight section indicates a power-law

International Comparisons of Labor Productivity Distribution 97 Fig. 3. Parameters A, α, and β were estimated using multi-regression analysis with the Cobb- Douglass production function. The obtained parameters of the production function are shown. JP and US manufacturers have constant returns to scale (α + β = 1). On the other hand, JP and US non-manufacturers have decreasing returns to scale (α + β < 1). Fig. 4. Aggregated added value created by listed firms in JP and the US. The vertical axis is aggregated added value divided by gross domestic product (GDP). About half of the GDP is created by listed firms in JP and the US.

98 Y. Ikeda and W. Souma Fig. 5. Rank-size plot of labor productivity for firms. Because the horizontal and vertical axes are log scales, the straight section indicates a power-law distribution. distribution. The tail of the labor productivity distribution for firms is the power-law distribution, P > (x) x μ, (3.6) where μ is called the Pareto index. The Pareto index μ was estimated using a least squares fitting to the tail of the productivity distribution. The labor productivity of the industrial sector was analyzed. Manufacturers included food, textile, pulp and paper, chemical, pharmaceutical, petroleum, steel, nonferrous metals, machinery, electrical machinery, automobile, shipbuilding, transportation equipment, precision apparatus, rubber, and ceramics. Non-manufacturers included fisheries, mining, construction, telecommunications, road transportation, railroads, marine transportation, air transportation, warehousing, wholesale, retail, service, electric power, gas, and real estate. The rank-size plots of labor productivity for industrial sectors are shown in Fig. 6. Each circle indicates an individual sector. Labor productivity for industrial sectors follows a power-law distribution. The Pareto index was estimated using the least squares method on the whole distribution. The observed power-law distribution for firms and sectors means that an equilibrium state is not achieved, in contrast to what is expected in economics, because the power-law distribution is, in general, obtained for the critical state, not for the equilibrium state. This discrepancy should be recognized as a serious fault of neoclassical economics. Figure 7 shows the time variation of the estimated Pareto indices for firms and sectors from 1990 to 2003. Pareto indices for firms are always larger than the indices for industry sectors. Pareto indices for the US is smaller than those for JP. In particular, the index is for US firms is small after 1994, which is the year the World Trade Organization was established and globalization of the economy began. This suggests that the economic disparity in the US grew as a result of globalization. Figure 8 shows the time variation of labor productivity of manufacturers and non-manufacturers from 1990 to 2003. It is expected from Eq. (2.7) with β =0.6 that labor productivities Y/L should be equal for firms and sectors. However, the

International Comparisons of Labor Productivity Distribution 99 Fig. 6. Rank-size plot of labor productivity for industrial sectors. Each circle indicates an individual sector. Labor productivity for industrial sectors follows a power-law distribution. Fig. 7. Time variation of the estimated Pareto indices for firms and sectors from 1990 to 2003. Pareto indices for firms are always larger than the indices for the industrial sector. obtained results show differences between nation and sectors. Specifically, the labor productivity of JP non-manufacturers is higher than that of US non-manufacturers in the range of listed firms. This result seems to contradict the results of the macroeconomic studies mentioned in 1. By assuming that both our result and the macro-economic studies are correct, we can hypothesize from the study of listed firms that the low productivity of JP non-manufacturers reported in the macro-economic studies has its root in the low productivity of unlisted small firms. To test this hypothesis, we analyzed financial data consisting of listed and unlisted JP firms. Analyzed data were combined data of Nikkei NEEDS and credit risk database (CRD). 7) Nikkei NEEDS includes only listed firms, and CRD includes only unlisted small firms. The combined data includes 4 10 5 firms approximately. Although this analysis used a different definition of added value:

100 Y. Ikeda and W. Souma Fig. 8. Time variation of labor productivity of manufacturers and non-manufacturers from 1990 to 2003. It is expected from Eq. (2.7) with β =0.6 that labor productivities Y/L are equal for firms and sectors. The labor productivity of JP non-manufacturers is higher than that of US non-manufacturers in the range of listed firms. Fig. 9. Productivities vs number of workers in 2005 for manufacturers and non-manufacturers. The productivity of large non-manufacturers is at the same level as that of large manufacturers. But the productivity of small non-manufacturers is more widely distributed than that of small manufacturers. Value Added = Ordinary Income + Total Labor Cost+ Financial Expense + Tax and Public Charge + Depreciation Cost, (3.7) it gives the same result as the the previous definition gives. Figure 9 plots productivity vs number of workers in 2005. The productivity of large non-manufacturers is at the same level as that of large manufacturers. But the productivity of small non-manufacturers is more widely distributed than that of small manufacturers. These figures indicate that there is a size dependence to productivity, which is not accounted for in Eq. (2.8). Figure 10 shows the size dependence of productivity in a different way. The

International Comparisons of Labor Productivity Distribution 101 Fig. 10. Size dependence of productivity. Lower productivity for smaller firms is apparent. The low productivity of the Japanese non-manufacturing sector is due to the low productivity of small firms. vertical axis is productivity obtained for firms with work forces larger than a threshold. Lower productivity for smaller firms is apparent. The low productivity of the Japanese non-manufacturing sector is thus due to the low productivity of small firms. This is the origin of the contradiction pointed out above. The above results reveal the need for an elaborate modeling method, rather than a simple production function, to analyze the size dependence of productivity. The copula method 8) is suitable to model the whole distribution of (Y, K, L) bytaking into account nonlinear correlations. 4. Conclusion Labor productivity was studied at the microscopic level in terms of distributions based on individual firm financial data for Japan and the US. A power-law distribution for firms and sector productivity was observed in both countries data. The power-law distribution for firms and sectors means that an equilibrium state is not achieved. The labor productivities were not equal for nation and sectors, in contrast to what can be expected from Eq. (2.7) with β = 0.6. It should be noted that the observed non-equlibrium state is evidence against the prevailing view in economics. The data analysis shows that the labor productivity of JP non-manufacturers is higher than that of US non-manufacturers in the range of listed firms. It was clarified that the low productivity of the Japanese non-manufacturing sector reported in macro-economic studies was caused by the low productivity of small firms. Acknowledgements The authors would like to thank Prof. H. Aoyama (Kyoto University), Prof. H. Iyetomi (Niigata University) and Dr. Y. Fujiwara (NiCT/ATR) for their

102 Y. Ikeda and W. Souma enlightening discussions. The authors also thank the Yukawa Institute for Theoretical Physics at Kyoto University. Discussions held during the YITP workshop YITP-W-07-16 on Econophysics III Physical Approach to Social and Economic Phenomena were invaluable to completing this work. References 1) K. Fukao and Y. Marukami, RIETI D.P., 04-E-014 (2004). 2) K. Motohashi, Journal of the Japanese and International Economics 21 (2007), 121. 3) Japan Productivity Center For Socio-Economic Development, Dec. 2007. 4) J. E. Stiglitz and C. E. Walsh, Principles of Macroeconomics (W.W.Norton&Co.Inc. 2002). 5) J. E. Stiglitz and C. E. Walsh, Principles of Microeconomics (W. W. Norton & Co. Inc. 2005). 6) C. W. Cobb and P. H. Douglas, American Economic Review 18 (1928), 139. 7) http://www.crd-office.net/crd/english/index.htm. 8) R. B. Nelsen, An Introduction to Copulas (Springer, 2006).