UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

Similar documents
UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Game Theory (EMBA 296 & EWMBA 211) Summer Oligopoly, signaling, auctions, social learning and bargaining

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Game theory (PR 13) Module 5 Oct.

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch work in the margins or in the blank space at the bottom of the last page.

ECON 2100 (Summer 2014 Sections 08 & 09) Exam #3D

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

ECON 4550 (Fall 2011) Exam 1

University of Victoria Winter Econ 203 Problem Set 3

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Final Examination Suggested Solution ECON 201

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

14.54 International Trade Lecture 17: Increasing Returns to Scale

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

14.03 Exam 3 Fall 2000 DO NOT OPEN THIS EXAM UNTIL TIME IS ANNOUNCED!

q S pq S cq S. where q is the total amount produced/consumed. There are two representative firms that maximizes their profits, max pq 1 c 2 q2 1 q 1

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Exam #2 Time: 1h 15m Date: 10 July Instructor: Brian B. Young. Multiple Choice. 2 points each

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS (EC201)

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

DEFINITIONS A 42. Benjamin Disraeli. I hate definitions.

Introduction to Economic Institutions

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Lecture Private Information, Adverse Selection and Market Failure

ECONOMICS 1 - LECTURE 2 Suggested Answers to Problem Set #2

JANUARY EXAMINATIONS 2008

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

ECON 2100 (Summer 2013 Section 06) Exam #3 (Version A)

Producer Theory - Monopoly

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Principles of Economics Final Exam. Name: Student ID:

Industrial Organization

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

Chapter 25: Monopoly Behavior

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Symmetric Information Benchmark Begin by setting up a comparison situation, where there is no information asymmetry. Notation:

Final Examination Thursday, June 16, 2016, 3:30pm 4:45pm ECON 201

MICROECONOMICS SECTION I. Time - 70 minutes 60 Questions

ECON 2100 (Summer 2015 Sections 07 & 08) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2015 Sections 07 & 08) Exam #3A

Hidden Information and Self-Selection. Dr. Margaret Meyer Nuffield College

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Final Exam - Solutions

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

What Is Covered. Econ 2 Final Exam. The Big Concepts. An Outline of Topics Covered In Econ 2

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Market Concentration and Power

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

The homework is due on Wednesday, December 7 at 4pm. Each question is worth 0.8 points.

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017

Hours needed to produce one unit of manufactured goods agricultural goods Pottawattamie 6 3 Muscatine 3 2

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

2007 Thomson South-Western

Part II. Market power

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3

Economics of Industrial Organization. Lecture 12: Mergers

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 1

Sellers goods have unobservable quality to buyers. Borrowers ability to repay is unobservable to banks who lend

Imperfect Competition

Transcription:

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures 13-14 Oct. 1, 2011

Pricing While there is some involved analysis required, the important takeaways about optimal pricing are At the optimal quantity produced q, marginal revenue equals marginal cost MR(q )=MC(q ) Marginal revenue comes from the underlying demands curve. Demand curves themselves come from consumer preferences.

Simple (nondiscriminatory) pricing A firm engages in simple pricing for a particular product if that product is sold for the same price per unit no matter who the buyer is or how many units the buyer purchases. The profit-maximizing quantity for the firm to produce (if it should be in business at all) q satisfies: (i) MR(q )=MC(q ) (ii) MR(q) >MC(q) for all q<q (iii) MR(q) <MC(q) for all q>q

Note that marginal profit, MR(q) MC(q) is positive for all q < q, that is, every additional unit in this region contributes positively to total profit. On the other hand, marginal profit is negative for all q>q, that is, every additional unit in this region reduces total profit. = Increasing the total profit in the region q<q and descending the total profit in the region q>q.

Profit-maximizing price and quantity Price/unit (P) P(q*) MC(q) Demand P(q) MR(q) q* Quantity (q)

Total costs, profit, and consumer surplus Price/unit (P) Consumer Surplus P(q*) MC(q) Profit Total cost MR(q) Demand P(q) q* Quantity (q)

What simple pricing loses? Price/unit (P) P(q*) Deadweight loss MC(q) Demand P(q) MR(q) q* Quantity (q)

The Holy Grail of pricing If the firm can capture all the welfare generated from selling q units, then the firm will want to produce q >q such that P (q )=MC(q ). Because this outcome is so good, any form of pricing that achieves this Holy Grail is known as perfect price discrimination. For historic reasons, perfect price discrimination is also known as firstdegree price discrimination. = Can the firm ever obtain the Holy Grail? Generally, the answer is no!!!

Two-part tariffs A two-part tariff is pricing with an entry fee and per-unit charge. It can help get a firm closer to the Grail than can simple pricing. Formally, a two-part tariff consists of an entry fee F and a per-unit charge p. A consumer s expenditure if she buys q units is given by T (q) = ( 0 if q =0 F + pq if q>0

If there are N homogeneous (have identical demands) consumers, then under the profit-maximizing two-part tariff, the firm produces q units, where P (q )=MC(q ) sets the per-unit charge p to equal P (q ) sets the entry fee F to equal average consumer surplus CS/N. If consumers are heterogeneous, the firm can still profit from using a twopart tariff, but designing the optimal tariff is much more complicated...

Third- and second-degree price discrimination Third-degree price discrimination is charging different prices on the basis of observed group membership. Examples: Senior-citizen/child/student discounts, and geography-based third-degree price discrimination. Second-degree price discrimination is price discrimination via induced revelation of preferences. Examples: quantity discounts, quality distortions (an adverse selection problem!).

Bertrand s oligopoly model (1883) In Cournot s game, each firm chooses an output, and the price is determined by the market demand in relation to the total output produced. An alternative model, suggested by Bertrand, assumes that each firm chooses a price, and produces enough output to meet the demand it faces, given the prices chosen by all the firms. = As we shell see, some of the answers it gives are different from the answers of Cournot.

Suppose again that there are two firms (the industry is a duopoly ) and that the cost for firm =1 2 for producing units of the good is given by (equal constant unit cost ). Assume that the demand function (rather than the inverse demand function as we did for the Cournot s game) is ( ) = for and zero otherwise, and that (the demand function in PR 12.3 is different).

Because the cost of producing each until is the same, equal to, firm makes the profit of on every unit it sells. Thus its profit is = where is the other firm. ( )( ) if 1 2 ( )( ) if = 0 if In Bertrand s game we can easily argue as follows: ( 1 2 )=( ) is the unique Nash equilibrium.

Using intuition, If one firm charges the price, then the other firmcandonobetter than charge the price. If 1 and 2,theneachfirm can increase its profit by lowering its price slightly below. = In Cournot s game, the market price decreases toward as the number of firms increases, whereas in Bertrand s game it is (so profits are zero) even if there are only two firms (but the price remains when the number of firm increases).

Markets with asymmetric information The traditional theory of markets assumes that market participants have complete information about the underlying economic variables: Buyers and sellers are both perfectly informed about the quality of the goods being sold in the market. If it is not costly to verify quality, then the prices of the goods will simply adjust to reflect the quality difference. = This is clearly a drastic simplification!!!

There are certainly many markets in the real world in which it may be very costly (or even impossible) to gain accurate information: labor markets, financial markets, markets for consumer products, and more. If information about quality is costly to obtain, then it is no longer possible that buyers and sellers have the same information. The costs of information provide an important source of market friction and can lead to a market breakdown.

Nobel Prize 2001 for their analyses of markets with asymmetric information

The Market for Lemons Example I Consider a market with 100 people who want to sell their used car and 100 peoplewhowanttobuyausedcar. Everyone knows that 50 of the cars are plums and 50 are lemons. Suppose further that seller buyer lemon $1000 $1200 plum $2000 $2400

If it is easy to verify the quality of the cars there will be no problem in this market. Lemons will sell at some price $1000 1200 and plums will sell at $2000 2400. But happens to the market if buyers cannot observe the quality of the car?

If buyers are risk neutral, then a typical buyer will be willing to pay his expected value of the car 1 2 1200 + 1 2400 = $1800 2 But for this price only owners of lemons would offer their car for sale, and buyers would therefore (correctly) expect to get a lemon. Market failure no transactions will take place, although there are possible gains from trade!

Example II Suppose we can index the quality of a used car by some number, which is distributed uniformly over [0 1]. There is a large number of demanders for used cars who are willing to pay 3 2 foracarofquality. There is a large number of sellers who are willing to sell a car of quality forapriceof.

If quality is perfectly observable, each used car of quality would be soled for some price between and 3 2. What will be the equilibrium price(s) in this market when quality of any given car cannot be observed? The unique equilibrium price is zero, and at this price the demand is zero and supply is zero. = The asymmetry of information has destroyed the market for used cars. But the story does not end here!!!

Signaling In the used-car market, owners of the good used cars have an incentive to try to convey the fact that they have a good car to the potential purchasers. Put differently, they would like choose actions that signal that they are offering a plum rather than a lemon. In some case, the presence of a signal allows the market to function more effectively than it would otherwise.

Example educational signaling Suppose that a fraction 0 1 of workers are competent and a fraction 1 are incompetent. The competent workers have marginal product of 2 and the incompetent have marginal product of 1 2. For simplicity we assume a competitive labor market and a linear production function 1 1 + 2 2 where 1 and 2 is the number of incompetent and competent workers, respectively.

If worker quality is observable, then firm would just offer wages 1 = 1 and 2 = 2 to competent workers, respectively. That is, each worker will paid his marginal product and we would have an efficient equilibrium. But what if the firm cannot observe the marginal products so it cannot distinguish the two types of workers?

If worker quality is unobservable, then the best the firm can do is to offer the average wage =(1 ) 1 + 2 If both types of workers agree to work at this wage, then there is no problem with adverse selection (more below). The incompetent (resp. competent) workers are getting paid more (resp. less) than their marginal product.

The competent workers would like a way to signal that they are more productive than the others. Suppose now that there is some signal that the workers can acquire that will distinguish the two types One nice example is education it is cheaper for the competent workers to acquire education than the incompetent workers.

To be explicit, suppose that the cost (dollar costs, opportunity costs, costs of the effort, etc.) to acquiring years of education is 1 and 2 for incompetent and competent workers, respectively, where 1 2. Suppose that workers conjecture that firms will pay a wage ( ) where is some increasing function of. Although education has no effect on productivity (MBA?), firms may still find it profitabletobasewageoneducation attractahigherquality work force.

Market equilibrium In the educational signaling example, there appear to be several possibilities for equilibrium: [1] The (representative) firm offers a single contract that attracts both types of workers. [2] The (representative) firm offers a single contract that attracts only one type of workers. [3] The (representative) firm offers two contracts, one for each type of workers.

A separating equilibrium involves each type of worker making a choice that separate himself from the other type. In a pooling equilibrium, in contrast, each type of workers makes the same choice, and all getting paid the wage based on their average ability. Note that a separating equilibrium is wasteful in a social sense no social gains from education since it does not change productivity.

Example (cont.) Let 1 and 2 be the education level actually chosen by the workers. Then, a separating (signaling) equilibrium has to satisfy: [1] zero-profit conditions [2] self-selection conditions ( 1 ) = 1 ( 2 ) = 2 ( 1 ) 1 1 ( 2 ) 1 2 ( 2 ) 2 2 ( 1 ) 2 1

In general, there may by many functions ( ) that satisfy conditions [1] and [2]. One wage profile consistent with separating equilibrium is and ( ) = ( 2 if 1 if 2 1 2 2 1 1 = Signaling can make things better or worse each case has to examined on its own merits!

The Sheepskin (diploma) effect The increase in wages associated with obtaining a higher credential: Graduating high school increases earnings by 5 to 6 times as much as does completing a year in high school that does not result in graduation. The same discontinuous jump occurs for people who graduate from collage. High school graduates produce essentially the same amount of output as non-graduates.

Example quality choice Next we consider a variation of the lemons model where quality may be determined by the producers. Suppose that each consumer wants to buy a single unit and that there are two different qualities available: value cost high $1400 $1150 low $800 $1150 If the industry is perfectly competitive (zero profits), then what we would expect to be the equilibrium quality produced?

If the fraction of high-quality producers is, then a risk-neutral consumer would be willing to pay = 1400 + 800(1 ) For both qualities to be produced we must have 1150. Thelowest value of that satisfies this inequality is = 7 12. The equilibrium value of is between 12 7 and 1. But these equilibria are not equivalent from the social point of view.