EconS Vertical Di erentiation

Similar documents
EconS Second-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

EconS Bundling and Tying

EconS Third-Degree Price Discrimination

EconS Bertrand Competition

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 1

EconS Asymmetric Information

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 2

EconS Theory of the Firm

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

EconS Long Term Contracts

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Sellers goods have unobservable quality to buyers. Borrowers ability to repay is unobservable to banks who lend

EconS Endogenous Market Size

Notes on Introduction to Contract Theory

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

P rofit t (1 + i) t. V alue = t=0

EconS Introduction / History of Industrial Organization

Price Discrimination: Part 1

This is the midterm 1 solution guide for Fall 2012 Form A. 1) The answer to this question is A, corresponding to Form A.

Industrial Economics. Price Discrimination. Andras Niedermayer

Economics 102 Summer 2015 Answers to Homework #2 Due Tuesday, June 30, 2015

CHAPTER 3 ELASTICITY AND SURPLUS. Monday, September 19, 11

Competitive Strategy: Week 4. Static Pricing

1) Your answer to this question is what form of the exam you had. The answer is A if you have form A. The answer is B if you have form B etc.

Q K L MPL APL FC VC TC AFC AVC ATC MC $ $ $40 $ $550 $10

Terry College of Business - ECON 4950

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

Advanced Microeconomic Theory. Chapter 7: Monopoly

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

knows?) What we do know is that S1, S2, S3, and S4 will produce because they are the only ones

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

Producer Theory - Monopoly

1. Suppose that policymakers have been convinced that the market price of cheese is too low.

6) Consumer surplus is the red area in the following graph. It is 0.5*5*5=12.5. The answer is C.

Principles of Microeconomics ECONOMICS 103. Topic 8: Imperfect Competition. Single price monopoly. Monopolistic competition.

TOPIC 4. ADVERSE SELECTION, SIGNALING, AND SCREENING

Two Lectures on Information Design

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Lecture 2: Basic Models of Trade

Information Design: Murat Sertel Lecture

Economics 101 Fall 2013 Answers to Homework #6 Due Tuesday, Dec 10, 2013

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 3: Supply, Demand & Equilibrium

This exam contains 11 pages (including this cover page) and 12 questions.

Practice Session 3 Price Discrimination

Lecture 10: Price discrimination Part II

Department of Economics Queen s University. ECON239: Development Economics Professor: Huw Lloyd-Ellis

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis December 10, 2008 Professor John Parman.

Lecture 13 - Price Discrimination

Final Exam: ECON-100A Intermediate Microeconomics Bob Baden Section I: Answer at least two questions (answer all parts of the questions you choose)

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Harvard University Department of Economics

1. You are given the following joint PPF for 3 individuals: Sarah, John, and Michael.

Part I. Multiple Choice Questions. Circle the best answers (14 marks).

ECON 102 Wooten Final Exam Practice Exam Solutions

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 5: Externalities. External costs and benefits

Final Exam - Solutions

Chapter 25: Monopoly Behavior

Thanksgiving Handout Economics 101 Fall 2000

Charpter 10 explores how firms can have more sophisticated behavior to extract surplus from consumers and maximize surplus.

The 'stickiness' of prices

Midterm 1 60 minutes Econ 1101: Principles of Microeconomics October 8, Exam Form A

ECON3021 Urban Economics. Lecture 1: Course Overview: What is a city? How do we model it? Lars Nesheim

a. Find MG&E s marginal revenue function. That is, write an equation for MG&E's MR function.

Chapter 15: Monopoly. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 1 / 83. Notes. Watanabe Econ Monopoly 2 / 83. Notes

EC Lecture 11&12. Vertical Restraints and Vertical Mergers

DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

Also, big thank you to fellow TA Enoch Hill for edits and some additions to the guide.

1. True or False. If the marginal product of labor is decreasing, then the average product of labor must also be decreasing. Explain.

EC 201 Lecture Notes 1 Page 1 of 1

PRICE DISCRIMINATION IN STACKELBERG COMPETITION

Final Exam - Solutions

Econ 200: Lecture 9 April 28, Learning Catalytics Session: Types of Goods 2. Exam Review

Examples: Kellogg s: breakfast cereals, Procter and Gamble: 12 different versions of Head &Shoulder Shampoo, Automobile producers Various types of

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 13 Sections 13.1, 13.2, 13.3 and 13.6 continued

Strategic Alliances, Joint Investments, and Market Structure

Chapter 10: Monopoly

Econ 1101 Summer 2013 Lecture 3. Section 005 6/19/2013

Introduction to Economics II: Producer Theory

GAME THEORY: Analysis of Strategic Thinking Exercises on Repeated and Bargaining Games

Adam Smith Theorem. Lecture 4(ii) Announcements. Lecture. 0. Link between efficiency and the market allocation.

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations

Introduction to Economic Institutions

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Topic 3. Demand and Supply

Loss Leading as an Exploitative Practice

# of Problems Written # of Homeworks Corrected Tom 2 26 Yoshi 3 27 Gary 6 15

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set # 3 May 31

To start we will look at the relationship between quantity demanded and price.

Commerce 295 Midterm Answers

Theory of Consumer Behavior First, we need to define the agents' goals and limitations (if any) in their ability to achieve those goals.

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Transcription:

EconS 425 - Vertical Di erentiation Eric Dunaway Washington State University eric.dunaway@wsu.edu Industrial Organization Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 1 / 41

Introduction For our next couple of lectures, we are going to see what happens when rms sell products that are not identical. These products can vary in quality, de ning characteristics, or something as simple as its color. Note: My o ce hour on Wednesdays is permanently being moved to 2:00 PM. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 2 / 41

Product Di erentiation Firms may want to o er di erent versions of the same product. By diversifying their product line, they can attract di erent consumers with varying tastes and (of course) extract more pro t from the market. At the same time, if there were multiple rms in a market, they may want to di erentiate their products to increase their market power. We ll talk about this at a later time (we ll need some game theory). Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 3 / 41

Product Di erentiation Product di erentiation can also be quite subtle. Is Cougar Gold sold in Pullman the same as Cougar Gold sold in Spokane? No. There are additional costs involved to ship Cougar Gold from one location to another. We can actually treat these two products (while identical in appearance) as separate. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 4 / 41

Product Di erentiation Product Di erentiation often leads to price discrimination. Be careful, however. We may see situations where di erent groups are charged di erent prices, yet there is not price discrimination going on. For example, suppose gas were being sold in Pullman for $3 a gallon, while it was being sold for $2 a gallon in Colfax (ignore taxes, etc.). Now suppose the marginal cost for gas was $2 in Pullman and $1 in Colfax. In this case, the prices merely take into consideration the di erence in marginal costs. To determine if price discrimination is happening, we want to see if the net prices (price less costs) di er across markets. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 5 / 41

Product Di erentiation Product di erentiation easily satis es our necessary conditions for price discrimination. By o ering di erent versions of a good, we can design it such that di erent consumers want to purchase di erent goods. This will cause consumers to sort themselves into their own groups, even if we can t observe their characteristics. Also, a group will want their product more than the other, reducing the chance of arbitrage. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 6 / 41

Product Di erentiation We classify product di erentiation into two broad categories, vertical and horizontal. We separate them based on how consumers view quality. With Vertical Di erentiation, consumers can all agree "what quality is," but they have di erent willingnesses to pay for quality. Examples: Lexus vs. Toyota, Banana Republic vs. GAP vs. Old Navy. With Horizontal Di erentiation, consumers can t agree on what quality is, and have di erent preferences for di erent characteristics. Example: Di erent kinds of Colgate toothpaste. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 7 / 41

Today, we ll focus on vertical di erentiation. If a rm can o er di erent versions of the same product that vary in their quality, how should they price them? We will use some technniques that we saw in second-degree price discrimination, namely the participation and incentive compatibility constraints. They re a bit easier in this context. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 8 / 41

Let s start with a simple model. A rm can produce two versions of a good, one of low quality and one of high quality. The marginal costs of producing these goods are c L and c H, respectively and c L < c H. The quality of the goods is predetermined (exogenous). We ll relax this later. There are N 1 consumers who value both versions of the good less (the low type), and N 2 consumers who value both versions of the good more (the high type). We are unable to observe any di erences between the consumers. Perhaps the high type has more income than the low, or the low type is just a cheapskate. Consumers have unit demand (They will only buy one unit, or none at all). Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 9 / 41

The low type consumer has a reservation price of V1 L for the low quality good, and V1 H for the high quality good. Likewise, the high type consumer has a reservation price of V2 L for the low quality good and V2 H for the high quality good. We can rank the valuations as following. V H 1 > V L 1 V H 2 > V L 2 V H 2 > V H 1 V L 2 > V L 1 thus we know that the high type values both versions of the good more than the low type, and both consumers value the high quality good more than the low quality good. We ll also assume that all reservation prices are above their respective costs, otherwise it would be ine cient for a consumer to buy the product. We ll also assume V H i V L i > c H c L for i = 1, 2 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 10 / 41

If the rm knows everything about the consumers except for which consumer is which, the rm has three viable options: O er only the high quality good, and sell it to both types of consumer. O er only the high quality good, and sell it to only the high type. O er both types of good, and target a di erent type of consumer with each. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 11 / 41

If the rm o ers only the high quality good, but wants to sell it to both types of consumers, the most they can charge is V H 1. Anything higher than that, and it would be better for the low type consumer to not buy the good. The rm s pro t level is π 1 = (N 1 + N 2 )(p H c H ) = (N 1 + N 2 )(V H 1 c H ) Consumer 1 receives no surplus, while consumer 2 receives a surplus of V H 2 V H 1. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 12 / 41

Next, the rm could o er only the high quality good, but sell it only to the high type consumer. In this case, it can charge a much higher price, V2 H, but it loses out on all of the low type consumers. The rm s pro t level is π 2 = N 2 (p H c H ) = N 2 (V H 2 c H ) Neither consumer receives any surplus in this case. High types pay their whole valuation, while the low types don t buy. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 13 / 41

Lastly, the rm could o er both types of good, and target the high quality to the high type and the low quality to the low type. We have to be aware, though, that one consumer may want to purchase the product not intended for them. This requires us to use participation and incentive compatibility constraints. As before, we ll have two participation constraints and two incentive compatibility constraints, one for each type of consumer. Again, only one participation constraint and one incentive compatibility constraint will bind in equilibrium. I ll spoil it and tell you that the participation constraint for the low type and the incentive compatibility constraint for the high type bind. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 14 / 41

Our constraints are V L 1 p L {z } Consumer 1 s surplus V H 2 p H {z } Consumer 2 s surplus if they buy high quality = 0 (PC 1 ) = V L 2 p L {z } Consumer 2 s surplus if they buy low quality (IC 2 ) We can rearrange these to solve for prices, p L = V L 1 p H = V2 H V2 L + V1 L {z} p L Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 15 / 41

p L = V L 1 p H = V H 2 V L 2 + V L 1 Now, we can calculate pro ts for the rm, π 3 = N 1 (p L c L ) + N 2 (p H c H ) = N 1 (V L 1 c L ) + N 2 (V H 2 V L 2 + V L 1 c H ) Once again, the low type consumer receives no surplus, but the high type receives a surplus of V L 2 V L 1 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 16 / 41

Which of the three cases should the rm choose? The one that gives the most pro ts, of course! We can compare the pro t levels across cases, and see which ones are the best, given what we know about our consumers. Starting with the rst two cases, the rm would rather only sell the high quality good to the high type consumer instead of selling to both consumers if π 2 > π 1 N 2 (V2 H c H ) > (N 1 + N 2 )(V1 H c H ) Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 17 / 41

N 2 (V2 H c H ) > (N 1 + N 2 )(V1 H c H ) We can rearrange this expression to obtain N 2 (V2 H V1 H ) > N 1 (V1 H c H ) This expression is actually quite intuitive. The left-hand side, N 2 (V2 H V1 H ), is the amount of extra pro t the rm can squeeze out of the high type if the rm sells only to them. The right-hand side, N 1 (V1 H c H ), is how much pro t the rm would get from the low type by including them in the market. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 18 / 41

N 2 (V H 2 V H 1 ) > N 1 (V H 1 c H ) This condition is not guaranteed to hold. If N 1 is much larger than N 2, i.e., there are a lot more low types than high types, the condition is unlikely to hold. If the high type has a much larget reservation price than the low type relative to the marginal cost, the condition is likely to hold. It is a case by case basis that you will have to analyze. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 19 / 41

What about the third case where the rm o ers both products? It would be better for the rm to do this (assuming π 2 > π 1 ) if π 3 > π 2 N 1 (V1 L c L ) + N 2 (V2 H V2 L + V1 L c H ) > N 2 (V2 H c H ) which rearranges to N 1 (V1 L c L ) > N 2 (V2 L V1 L ) Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 20 / 41

N 1 (V L 1 c L ) > N 2 (V L 2 V L 1 ) Again, this also has some great interpretation, The left-hand side, N 1 (V1 L c L ) is how much pro t the rm makes by letting the low type into the market and selling them the low quality good. The right-hand side, N 2 (V2 L c H ) is how much pro t the rm loses to consumer surplus to the high type, since it has to lower the price they charge due to incentive compatibility. Naturally, the rm chooses whichever method yields the highest pro ts (again, it depends on parameters). Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 21 / 41

Let s make the model a little harder. So far we ve let quality be determined outside of the model, but now were going to let the rm choose the quality they o er along with the price. We need add a few things to the model. The rm can choose the quality, s j of both of its j products. Quality is costly. To add quality to a product, the rm must pay some cost function c(s) which is increasing (always going up) and convex (getting steeper). Higher quality adds a lot of cost to the rm. The consumer valuation of the product is θ i s j, where θ i is consumer i s preference for quality. Let θ 2 > θ 1, so the high type values quality more than the low type. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 22 / 41

Going back to our three cases, if the rm sells a single quality of the good to all consumers, its pro t maximization problem is max p,s (N 1 + N 2 )(p c(s)) subject to two participation constraints θ 1 s p 0 (PC 1 ) θ 2 s p 0 (PC 2 ) of which only one will bind, PC 1. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 23 / 41

θ 1 s p = 0 (PC 1 ) From this participation constraint, we can solve for price as a function of quality, p = θ 1 s and substitute this back into our maximization problem max p,s max s (N 1 + N 2 )(p c(s)) (N 1 + N 2 )(θ 1 s c(s)) Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 24 / 41

max s (N 1 + N 2 )(θ 1 s c(s)) From here, we take a rst-order condition with respect to s to obtain, which reduces to (N 1 + N 2 )(θ 1 c 0 (s)) = 0 c 0 (s) = θ 1 Thus, when the rm sells one quality of good to the whole market, it sets that marginal cost of quality equal to the low type s preference for quality (Their marginal willingness to pay for quality). Again, the low type receives no surplus, while the high type receives a surplus of (θ 2 θ 1 )s. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 25 / 41

For the case where the rm sells a single quality of good, but only caters to the high type, its maximization problem is max p,s N 2 (p c(s)) subject to a single participation constraint, which will bind in equilibrium. θ 2 s p 0 (PC 2 ) Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 26 / 41

Our results are very similar to those in the rst case. We will nd that p = θ 2 s from our participation constraint, and in equilibrium, c 0 (s) = θ 2 the marginal cost of quality will now equal the high type s preference for quality (Their marginal willingness to pay). No consumer will have any surplus either (since the low type doesn t buy the product). Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 27 / 41

Lastly, we have our third case, where the rm o ers more than one quality of the good. To make this case a little bit easier, I m going to impose c(s) = 1 2 s2. The rm s pro t maximization problem is, max N 1 (p 1 c(s 1 )) + N 2 (p 2 c(s 2 )) p 1,p 2,s 1,s 2 1 1 max N 1 p 1 p 1,p 2,s 1,s 2 2 s2 1 + N 2 p 2 2 s2 2 with two participation and two incentive compatibility constraints. Again PC 1 and IC 2 bind. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 28 / 41

Our binding constraints are θ 1 s 1 p 1 = 0 (PC 1 ) θ 2 s 2 p 2 = θ 2 s 1 p 1 (IC 2 ) which we can solve for p 1 and p 2 to obtain p 1 = θ 1 s 1 p 2 = θ 2 s 2 (θ 2 θ 1 )s 1 Notice that the low type is charged their valuation, while the high type is charged less than their valuation. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 29 / 41

Substituting these values back into the pro t maximization problem, 1 1 max N 1 p 1 p 1,p 2,s 1,s 2 2 s2 1 + N 2 p 2 2 s2 2 1 1 max N 1 θ 1 s 1 s 1,s 2 2 s2 1 + N 2 θ 2 s 2 (θ 2 θ 1 )s 1 2 s2 2 and calculate rst-order conditions for s 1 and s 2 to obtain, N 1 (θ 1 s 1 ) N 2 (θ 2 θ 1 ) = 0 N 2 (θ 2 s 2 ) = 0 Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 30 / 41

N 1 (θ 1 s 1 ) N 2 (θ 2 θ 1 ) = 0 N 2 (θ 2 s 2 ) = 0 Solving for s 1 and s 2, we have s 1 = θ 1 N 2 N 1 (θ 2 θ 1 ) s 2 = θ 2 Again, notice that the low type receives a lower quality than the e cient level (c 0 (s) = s, and s i = θ i is the e cient level) while the high type receives the e cient level. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 31 / 41

The results of vertical di erentiation are very similar to those we saw with menu pricing. In menu pricing, the low type was given a smaller quantity of the good, while in vertical di erentiation, the low type is simply given a lower quality good. The low type pays their valuation in both cases, while the high type pays a lower price to ensure incentive compatibility. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 32 / 41

It s really interesting that the rm gives the low type a purposefully lower quality good. The book has a great quote on this from 1849 (well before these ideas were formalized): "It is not because of the few thousand francs which would have to be spent to put a roof over the third-class seats that some company or other has open carriages with wooden benches. What that company is trying to do is prevent the passengers who can pay the second class fare from travelling third class; it hits the poor, not because it wants to hurt them, but to frighten the rich. And it is again for the same reason that the companies, having proved almost cruel to the third-class passengers and mean to the second-class ones, become lavish in dealing with rst-class passengers. Having refused the poor what is necessary, they give the rich what is super uous. (Jules Dupuit, 1849)" Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 33 / 41

What Dupuit was explaining is incentive compatibility. If they improved the third-class seats, many passengers who could a ord second-class tickets would likely ride third-class in order to save some money. Thus the quality is kept so low to guarantee that those passengers pay the second-class price. On the other hand, since they can t lower the second-class quality relative to rst-class, they have to make rst-class extravagant in order to ensure that rst-class passengers wouldn t rather ride second-class. Basically, it s not because the train operator is cheap, it s because they want to get the most pro t out of their passengers as possible. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 34 / 41

Purposely lowering the quality of a product is actually very common today. If a rm wants to sell to a segment of the market that is excluded due to the price being too high, they can o er a lower quality version of that product. They have to make sure that the low quality product doesn t take from their high type consumers, though. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 35 / 41

Example: Table vs. Cooking wine. Many people like to use wine while cooking. Wine, however, can be an expensive ingredient for a meal. As a wine rm, if you wanted to o er a cheap type of wine speci cally marketed for cooking, you run into the problem where consumers may want to drink that wine instead of the more expensive table wine meant for drinking. How do you solve this problem? You take the table wine, purposely damage it by adding enough salt to it to make it undrinkable, then sell it as cooking wine. Other examples: Laser printers, student versions of software, iphone 5C, etc. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 36 / 41

What s interesing about the case of cooking wine is that the marginal cost to produce the low quality product is actually higher than the marginal cost to produce the high quality product, i.e., c L > c H. Intuitively, you can t make the low quality product without starting from the high quality product, so it has to be more expensive. Remember from our rst example that the rm will want to o er both qualities if N 1 (V L 1 c L ) > N 2 (V L 2 V L 1 ) and thus, a "purposely damaged" product like this will be harder to implement in this case. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 37 / 41

N 1 (V L 1 c L ) > N 2 (V L 2 V L 1 ) However, if the high type consumer puts a very low valuation on the low quality good (V2 L, think of a master chef wanting to use cooking wine rather than table wine) relative to the low type s valuation (V1 L), this constraint can still hold, implying that it might be better for the rm to sell both qualities of the good. The interesting thing is that if purposely damaging a good allows more consumers into the market, it actually reduces deadweight loss. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 38 / 41

Summary Vertical Di erentiation is a useful tool to a rm in order to implement price discrimination. If quality can be varied, the rm can get consumers to self-select into the best product for themselves. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 39 / 41

Next Time A brief explanation of horizontal di erentiation, then budling and tying. I don t like the book s coverage of horizontal di erentiation, so skip over section 6.2 for now; we ll cover it in more depth after we do game theory. Reading: 6.3. Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 40 / 41

Homework 3-1 Consider a rm that wants to o er two di erent qualities of a good marketed to a low type and a high type consumer. The rm cannot tell the di erence between the two consumers, but knows that the high type values the good twice as much as the low type, i.e., θ 1 = 1 and θ 2 = 2. In order to produce quality in their product, the rm faces the cost function c(s) = 1 3 s3 where s is the quality level. The proportion of low type consumers is γ and the proportion of high type consumers is 1 γ where γ N 1 N 1 +N 2 = N 1 N. 1. Set up the rm s pro t maximization problem and list all four constraints. 2. Assume PC 1 and IC 2 bind. Calculate the equilibrium qualities and prices o ered to each type of consumer. 3. For what values of γ does the rm o er any quality at all to the low type consumer? (Hint: look at s1 ). Eric Dunaway (WSU) EconS 425 Industrial Organization 41 / 41