The proposed Code appears (inappropriately) to support incumbents investment models at the expense of competition

Similar documents
BEREC views on the European Parliament first reading legislative resolution on the European Commission s proposal for a Connected Continent Regulation

BT s response to Ofcom consultation document. Price Rises in Fixed Term Contracts

BEREC views on Article 74 of the draft Code Co-investment and very high-capacity (VHC) networks

Telecoms: how the Article 7 consultation and notification mechanism works: frequently asked questions (see also IP/10/644)

ACT position on the proposal for a Directive on contracts for the supply of digital content - April 2016

The new European Electronic Communications Code (EECC)

GSMA comments on the Draft BEREC Report on OTT services (BoR (15) 142)

BEREC Opinion. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case FI/2012/ :

Contribution of Orange France Telecom Group to the public consultation on the Draft BEREC report on best practices to facilitate switching

Undue discrimination by SMP providers How Ofcom will investigate potential contraventions on competition grounds of Requirements not to unduly

CONSULTATION ON THE COMMISSION'S BROADBAND GUIDELINES ON THE APPLICATION OF EU STATE AID RULES TO PUBLIC FUNDING OF BROADBAND NETWORKS

Introducing Carrier Selection & Carrier Pre- Selection in Malta

Retail Bundling in Hull. KCOM Bundling of SMP and non-smp Products

Regulating oligopolies in telecoms: the new European Commission guidelines

RECOMMENDATIONS. (Text with EEA relevance) (2014/710/EU)

Consumer Switching. Response by KCOM

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. The new Universal service and Users rights Directive

DTI/HMT Review on Concurrent Competition Powers in Sectoral Regulation

RESPONSE BY BRITISH SKY BROADCASTING GROUP PLC TO OFCOM S CONSULTATION DOCUMENT Simplifying Non-Geographic Numbers 1 April 2011

Telecom Italia response to Draft BEREC report on relevant market definition for business services BoR (10) November 2010

Position Paper. Cable Europe position paper on the Telecoms Review. Executive Summary. Policy objectives

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case ES/2013/1466

ETNO contribution to the BEREC consultation on the Broadband Promotion Report

Session 3: Competition Policy and European Regulation

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case FI/2013/1498

COMMISSION RECOMMENDATION. of (Text with EEA relevance)

The EU electronic communications framework: is it on track?

ETNO Comments on the BEREC report on the impact of premium content on ECS markets and the effect of devices on the open use of the Internet

Price regulation of unbundled broadband services

Ofcom review of additional charges. Including non-direct debit charges and early termination charges

The opinions expressed in this presentation are the personal views of the author and do not prejudge decisions of the RRT

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

NEXT GENERATION ACCESS IN NEW BUILD DEVELOPMENTS SKY S RESPONSE TO OFCOM S CONSULTATION

Ofcom review of additional charges Including non-direct debit charges and early termination charges

Mobile call termination market review Ofcom. 4 June Response by Telefonica UK Ltd

Fixed Narrowband Retail Services Market Review

BoR (10) 34 Rev1b. BEREC report of the consultation on the best practices to facilitate switching BoR (10) 34

EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

Telecommunications Retail Service Quality Framework

Wholesale call origination on the public telephone network provided at a fixed location

Review of the Electronic Communications Regulatory Framework. Executive Summary 6: NRAs and BEREC

BEREC Opinion. Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC:

BEREC Opinion. Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC:

experience Principal, International Ofcom April 2008

BEREC Opinion Phase II investigation pursuant to Article 7of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC

AIIP comments on the

ETNO comments on the ERG draft common position on geographic aspects of market analysis

Undue discrimination by SMP providers Consideration of responses to a proposal for investigating potential contraventions on competition grounds of

SESSION 4: STRATEGIC COSTING FOR BROADBAND SERVICES

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

Cable Europe response to BEREC s consultation on its draft report on oligopoly analysis and regulation

Official Journal of the European Union L 344/65 RECOMMENDATIONS COMMISSION

ECTA RESPONSE DRAFT BEREC PRELIMINARY REPORT IN VIEW OF A COMMON POSITION ON MONITORING MOBILE COVERAGE TO THE PUBLIC CONSULTATION BY BEREC ON THE

The Clean Energy package. Position of the Austrian electricity industry

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7 of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case NL/2015/1727

DCMS Future Telecoms Infrastructure Review: Call for Evidence, BT s response (January 2018) Annex 1: Referenced responses to DMCS Questions

How to regulate next-generation access (if at all)?

QUESTIONNAIRE on the BB Guidelines ( Guidelines )

Introducing Carrier Selection & Carrier Pre- Selection in Malta

3 Group response to BEREC s consultation on the draft report on best practices to facilitate switching.

NOTIFICATION OF DRAFT MEASURES PURSUANT TO ARTICLE 7(3) OF DIRECTIVE 2002/21/EC For the markets for

Set free by competition? Transitional access regulation of telecoms incumbents

The BEREC Opinion on the draft. methodologies. Dr Iris Henseler-Unger, Vice President BNetzA 8th EETT International Conference Athens, 16/17 May 2013

BIS Call for Evidence on Switching Principles. BT s response. December 2015

BoR (12) 40. BEREC Report of the Consultation on the draft BEREC report on Co-investment and SMP in NGA networks

ETNO Reflection Document on the ERG Draft 2010 Work Programme

The FTTH Council is concerned by a number of specific aspects of this consultation which it would like to set out at the outset.

BEREC input to the European Commission Implementing Act on fair use policy and sustainability of the abolition of retail roaming surcharges

BoR (11) 20 final. BEREC monitoring report on Broadband Common Positions

Charge controls for Wholesale Line Rental implementation and cost orientation

OECD Policy Guidance for Protecting and Empowering Consumers in Communication 1 Services

BEREC Opinion on. Phase II investigation. pursuant to Article 7a of Directive 2002/21/EC as amended by Directive 2009/140/EC: Case DE/2014/1642

Contents. BoR (18) 34

European Association of Co-operative Banks Groupement Européen des Banques Coopératives Europäische Vereinigung der Genossenschaftsbanken

COMISIÓN DEL MERCADO DE LAS TELECOMUNICACIONES

Response to the consultation on the Draft review of the BEREC Common Position on geographical aspects of market analysis (definition and remedies).

ECTA POLICY POSITION

EUROPEAN ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS CODE

National Grid s specific response to questions raised in E10- GNM-13-03b: ERGEG consultation on Pilot Framework Guidelines on gas balancing rules.

WindEurope considers that repowered projects could be further provided with a clear path-to-market via:

Regulatory certainty to support investment in full-fibre broadband. Ofcom s approach to future regulation

10109/14 KM/ek 1 DG E2B

Proposal for a REGULATION OF THE EUROPEAN PARLIAMENT AND OF THE COUNCIL

Scottish Parliament Edinburgh EH99 1SP. Dear Convener

Proposal for a Directive on Better Enforcement and Modernisation of EU Consumer Protection Rules

Price rises in fixed. term contracts Issued 3 January Contact for response: Michael Eagle

INTUG Position Statement on the European Commission s proposals following review of the European Telecommunications Framework.

AmCham EU comments on the European Commission s Preliminary Report on the E-Commerce Sector Inquiry

Mark Naftel Norton Rose

Response to the Consultation on the BEREC Guidelines on the Implementation by National Regulators of European Net Neutrality Rules 18.

Review of the General Conditions of Entitlement. Transposition table for general conditions

Oligopolies in electronic communications: more concentration, more regulation?

AUSTRIA INTRODUCTION REGULATORY ENVIRONMENT. Main regulatory developments

Telecoms and Pay TV Complaints Q1 (January to March) 2014

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Dear Mr Homann,

Telecoms and Pay TV Complaints Q2 (April to June) 2016

BRITISH FILM INSTITUTE EUROPEAN COMMISSION ISSUED PAPER ASSESSING STATE AID FOR FILMS AND OTHER AUDIVISUAL WORKS SEPTEMBER 2011

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

Strategic and Retail Market Review. 3 June 2008

Transcription:

Sky s response to the European Commission s consultation on the proposed Directive establishing a new European Electronic Communications Code Introduction 1. Sky plc ( Sky ) 1 is Europe s leading pay TV operator 2 and the UK s second largest broadband and telephony provider. 2. Sky s top line views on the draft Directive establishing a new European Electronic Communications Code ( the proposed Code ) are set out below. In the time available we have focused on two areas of reform: access regulation and consumer protection. 3. On access regulation, our top line position is that we reject the proposed Code s central premise of reducing competition from access seekers in return for entrenching incumbents control over investment. We disagree with the proposed extension of the periodicity of market reviews from three years to five years as it enables greater regulatory forbearance and the introduction of a double-lock system which may weaken a national regulatory authority s ( NRA s ) ability to impose SMP remedies. 4. On consumer protection, the proposed maximum harmonisation approach is overly prescriptive, doesn t recognise differences between how national markets are structured and unduly changes the rules on how and when communications providers communicate with their customers. I. Changes to access regulation The proposed Code appears (inappropriately) to support incumbents investment models at the expense of competition 5. A thriving UK communications sector is crucial for the development of the economy. In this digital age, communications services have rapidly and inextricably become woven into the fabric of the everyday lives of nearly all businesses and individuals. As commerce and society moves online, the central role that the communications sector plays in driving growth and productivity has become even more pronounced. 6. The successful development of the sector over the last ten years has been in part attributable to a regulatory regime that created conditions that were conducive for efficient investment and innovation and which led to effective and sustainable competition over large parts of the value chain. 1 2 Sky plc is a registered company under the EU Transparency Register. Our ID number is 62536168216-12. See http://ec.europa.eu/transparencyregister/public/consultation/displaylobbyist.do?id=62536168216-12 for further information. Sky plc provides pay TV services in the United Kingdom, Ireland, Germany, Austria and Italy. 1

7. The strength of the existing European telecoms framework is that it gives NRAs autonomy to weigh factors like promoting investment against promoting competition based on what they see in their own markets. 8. Our main concern is that, throughout the proposed Code, the Commission has placed weight on the fact that certain commercial models (such as co-investment models) are, on their face, pro-competitive. This may be true in some cases but should not be presumed to be true in all cases. Instead, NRAs should assess each commercial model or market development on a case-by-case basis, looking solely on effects on competition. By being more prescriptive about how certain business models or market structures should be treated, the proposed Code may limit NRAs ability to assess the market. This may inappropriately bias NRAs towards entrenching incumbents control over investment and access rather than competition (to the ultimate detriment of consumers) and has the potential to distort the market by promoting certain business models and market structures over others. 9. The following proposed changes are of particular concern: a. Regulatory treatment of new network elements Article 74 appears to be intended to drive co-investment models by allowing co-investors the ability to benefit from firstmover advantages. Effectively, Article 74 acts as a carve-out for 'new network elements' from the requirement to impose remedies on SMP operators under Articles 66 and 67-72. In our view it s unclear why the Commission saw the need to develop a specific regulatory carve-out for a single investment model. This should be assessed on a case-by-case basis, as explained above, and by reference to the Article 3 objectives. We also argue that access seekers, like Sky, should be able to benefit from access to all products made available through any new network elements on fair and reasonable terms. b. Market analysis procedure - in assessing whether a market tends towards effective competition under Article 65(1)(b), NRAs must, under Article 65(2), take into account (among other things): 'the existence of market developments which may increase the likelihood of the relevant market tending towards effective competition, such as those commercial co-investment or access agreements between operators which benefit competitive dynamics sustainably.' Our concern here is that the Commission is not applying an evidence-based framework and instead appears to assume that coinvestment or access agreements have a positive impact on competition. As explained above, this may be true in some cases but cannot be assumed in all cases. NRAs should be required to look solely at effects on competition and not make generalised assumptions based on the type of business structures used by the operators involved. c. Pricing flexibility - the proposed Code promotes the use of pricing flexibility to encourage investment in next generation networks. For example, Article 72(1) states that '[i]n determining whether or not price control obligations would be appropriate, national regulatory authorities should take into account long-term end-user interests related to the deployment and take-up of next-generation networks, and in particular of very high capacity networks' and that NRAs must 'take into account the benefits of predictable and stable wholesale prices in ensuring efficient entry and sufficient incentives for all operators to deploy new and enhanced networks.' In Sky s view, this reflects a policy shift towards preferring investment over competition, even though investment in very high capacity networks is often dependent on maintaining strong competition. While it may be appropriate to not impose price regulation on significant, risky fibre investments at least for a period in order to encourage appropriate investment, there is a strong risk that competition and consumers will be harmed in the long run from high ongoing prices for wholesale access to the new fibre services. Given the importance of vibrant retail competition in underpinning consumer demand and hence scale for these new fibre investments, it is inappropriate to position pricing flexibility as taking primacy over price regulation in order to promote investment. In practice, an NRA will need to weigh carefully 2

based on the available evidence the use of both pricing forbearance and charge controls in serving its objectives, including the promotion of appropriate investment and competition. NRAs already have this power and, in this regard, it is not justified for the proposed Code to elevate the use of one remedy over the other. Extension of the periodicity of market reviews 10. The proposed Code proposes to extend the maximum review period from three to five years to 'allow operators longer term planning' and to 'provide national regulators with greater flexibility as regards the timing of market reviews' (Article 65). In addition, NRAs may request a one year extension to the five year maximum provided that the NRA provides the Commission with a reasonable basis for the extension and that the Commission doesn't object within 1 month of the notified extension. 11. Experience to date shows that there is no sound case for extending the current three year review process, which works well in practice. The key benefit of a shorter cycle is its ability to keep up with changing circumstances and to take into account the very dynamic nature of the telecoms sector. Indeed, to revert back to a longer cycle for review would be to reverse the progress made in 2009 which shortened the cycle to three years. It would also introduce greater uncertainty (e.g. as to the appropriateness of remedies and the impact of market developments). 12. Moreover, there is no evidence at all that the three year review cycle has discouraged investment. On the contrary, infrastructure investments are typically long term with long payback periods much longer than three or even five years and have been possible under the current market review periods. BT constantly claims that since 2010 it has invested substantial amounts in upgrading its network with VDSL technology. It recently stated that it has invested over 10 billion in broadband services over the past decade. New double-lock system allowing EU-level vetoes of proposed SMP remedies 13. Currently, where standard remedies are imposed by an NRA, the Commission may provide comments but ultimately may not veto the imposition of an SMP remedy. As part of the reform of BEREC, a new double-lock system is proposed. Where BEREC and the Commission agree on their position regarding an NRA s draft remedies, the NRA could be required to amend or withdraw the draft measure. 14. In Sky s view, this proposal is unhelpful, as it may weaken NRAs ability to impose remedies. We also question whether the proposed double lock system is compatible with the principle of subsidiarity. II. Changes to consumer protection 15. Sky considers that the current legislative framework or existing market mechanisms are fully adequate to deal with issues that arise in respect of the consumer protection regime applicable to electronic communications services. 16. In this context, the proposed maximum harmonisation approach (Recital 232 and Article 94) is overly prescriptive, doesn t recognise differences between how national markets are structured and unduly changes the rules on how and when communications providers communicate with their customers. Changes in the following areas are of particular concern: a. Switching- Sky notes that the proposed Code envisages (in Article 99(1)) a make before break model for switching (i.e. a new service would need to be up and running before an old service was stopped). The proposed Code also provides that the receiving provider shall lead the switching and porting process (Article 99(5)). 3

However, in Sky s view, no further measures are required to facilitate switching, as the current switching processes work well for consumers. There is no evidence of serious consumer harm; nor is there any evidence of any adverse effects on competition, whether in the provision of bundles, or of individual services to justify further intervention and a move to a receiving provider led process. Further, we consider that it is inappropriate to examine switching issues, in any sector, through the lens of a pre-determined preference for a receiving provider led process, given the significant costs for consumers associated with receiving provider led processes. These costs include: i. Many switches taking longer; ii. Consumers receiving fewer retention offers from their existing provider and there being fewer opportunities for the existing provider to right-size the consumer s existing package so it best meets the consumer s needs and budget; iii. Consumers not knowing the implications of switching when they agree to switch; iv. Consumers are more likely to be the victim of slamming, erroneous transfers or mis-selling and v. The underlying processes are complex and costly to implement with those costs invariably being passed on to consumers. National regulatory authorities should be expected to evaluate the costs and benefits of different switching processes carefully to ensure than any changes are necessary and proportionate before introducing process reforms. The Code, to the extent it includes prescriptive rules on switching, should reflect that approach instead of a pre-determined preference for receiving provider led processes in all cases. b. Bundled offers - the proposed extension of certain key articles in the Code to all elements of a bundle (Article 100), is far too broad and ill-considered and, in the absence of evidence of consumer harm or market failure, causes Sky serious concern. In the first instance, it is so broad that there appears to be no limit to the type of bundled products that the provision could apply to. Second, in the context of pay TV, the provision of pay TV services is fundamentally different to communications services not least as no physical infrastructure (namely a telephone line) is required to be switched. Moreover, pay TV is already extensively regulated under consumer protection laws deriving from various existing EU Directives (e.g. Unfair Contract Terms Directive, the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive, and the Consumer Rights Directive) in addition to the UK Consumer Rights Act which has new provisions specific to digital content. The draft Digital Content Directive 3 is a more appropriate vehicle to address any perceived gaps in the legal framework covering pay TV services. Inclusion in the Code risks muddling content services with communications services when the two are fundamentally different. c. Early termination charges ( ETCs ) - The proposed Code (Article 98(4)) appears to lay down only two bases for calculating ETCs To reflect the value of subsidised equipment bundled with the contract or reimbursement for any other promotional advantages marked as such at the moment of the contract conclusion. The first of these reflects the mobile model of subsidised handsets and the second reflects the current legal approach in some countries (e.g., Italy). Neither of these reflects what is common across the UK market which is to base ETCs on the subscription 3 Proposal for a Directive on certain aspects concerning contracts for the supply of digital content,com(2015)634 final. 4

price that the consumer would have paid if they had adhered to the terms of the contract they agreed. This approach is broadly designed to ensure providers are able to recover a broad range of sunk acquisition costs (e.g., for equipment and services such as installation) that are typically not passed on to consumers as upfront payments. ETCs are already regulated by unfair terms legislation which ensures that consumers are protected by only having to pay fair ETCs. This means that Article 98(4) is unnecessary. If it does remain in the proposed Code in some form, at the very least, NRAs should have discretion to reflect the different market structures and pricing models in place in the Member State. d. Notice and churn right if any changes that are not exclusively to the benefit of the end-user - Article 20(2)) of the current Universal Services Directive provides a penalty-free churn right and prescriptive notification requirement in the event of a modification to the contractual conditions. However, Ofcom s rules (General Condition 9.6) include a threshold of material detriment before this applies. Ofcom s approach is a sensible one but Ofcom could not maintain it under the Code due to maximum harmonisation A materiality threshold is necessary as it limits the number of contract change notices providers need to give in highly competitive and innovative sectors where products and services change regularly to meet evolving consumer needs. The new language in Article 98(3) would conceivably require contract change notices to be issued on a durable medium for modest changes that are likely to only impact a few customers (for example changes to call rates to obscure destinations). This change would cause annoyance to consumers (who would receive notices from their provider that they do not consider important) and would have a significant and costly operational impact on all providers in the UK. e. Prescribed form of contract information Under the proposed Code (Article 95(5)) BEREC will be expected to issue a contract summary template that providers will need to complete and provide to customers. In Sky s view this approach mandates how communications providers communicate with their customers in an overly-prescriptive manner. 17. On a more positive note, we note that under the proposed Code 24 month contracts will remain possible (Article 98(1)). This is particularly useful when set against the de facto 12 month limit in the draft Digital Content Directive. There is now a clear and very fundamental inconsistency between the Digital Content Directive and the proposed Code which we hope will be resolved in the context of the ongoing Council negotiations on the Digital Content Directive. In our view, contracts of up to 24 months are preferable to 12 month contracts as they preserve flexible cost recovery options that benefit consumers looking for low entrycost access to innovative new products and services. Sky December 2016 5