Policy Evaluation Tools. Willingness to Pay and Demand. Consumer Surplus (CS) Evaluating Gov t Policy - Econ of NA - RIT - Dr.

Similar documents
Embedded Economies. No Net Flow of Goods. Embedded Economies - Econ. of NA - RIT - Dr. Jeffrey Burnette

Welfare economics part 2 (producer surplus) Application of welfare economics: The Costs of Taxation & International Trade

Econ 101, section 3, F06 Schroeter Exam #2, Red. Choose the single best answer for each question.

DEMAND AND SUPPLY. Chapter 3. Principles of Macroeconomics by OpenStax College is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 3.

Homework 4 Economics

ECON 101 KONG Midterm 2 CMP Review Session. Presented by Benji Huang

1. Suppose that policymakers have been convinced that the market price of cheese is too low.

Basics of Economics. Alvin Lin. Principles of Microeconomics: August December 2016

1. Welfare economics is the study of a. the well-being of less fortunate people. b. welfare programs in the United States.

MICROECONOMICS Midterm Test (sample)

Downloaded for free from 1

Homework 2 Answer Key

Problem Set 5. The price will be higher than the equilibrium price. There will be a surplus of cheese.

SOLUTIONS TO TEXT PROBLEMS 6

Queen s University Department of Economics ECON 111*S

Government Regulation

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Spring Semester

Government Intervention - Taxes and Subsidies (SOLUTIONS)

Choose the single best answer for each question. Do all of your scratch-work in the side and bottom margins of pages.

6) Consumer surplus is the red area in the following graph. It is 0.5*5*5=12.5. The answer is C.

EXAMINATION #3 VERSION A Firms and Competition October 25, 2018

Lecture # 4 More on Supply and Demand

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester

Topic 3. Demand and Supply

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

Econ 200, Summer 2011, Dr. Alan and Prof. Crossley. Problem Set 2. (Reference: Mankiw and Taylor, Chapters 6, 7, 8, 13)

Government Policy, Efficiency, and Welfare

Midterm 2 Sample Questions. Use the demand curve diagram below to answer the following THREE questions.

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

MICRO FINAL EXAM Study Guide

ECONOMICS 103. Topic 3: Supply, Demand & Equilibrium

Introduction to Economic Institutions

Econ 2113 Test #2 Dr. Rupp Fall 2008

Econ Test 2B Dr. Rupp Tuesday, March 3, 2009 Pledge: I have neither given or received aid on this exam Signature

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Final Exam December 8, 2006

1. Demand: willingness to buy a good or service and the ability to pay for it; how much of an item an individual is willing to purchase at each price

Perfectly Competitive Markets, Market Equilibrium, Welfare Economics, Efficiency, and Market Failure

CFA Exam Review CFA PREREQUISITE ECONOMICS READINGS

Instructions: DUE: day of your unit exam Block Period 1/31 st or 2/1 st

Economics E201 (Professor Self) Sample Questions for Exam Two, Fall 2013

Class Agenda. Note: As you hand-in your quiz, pick-up graded HWK #1 and HWK #2 (due next Tuesday).

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 3

Now suppose a price ceiling of 15 is set by the government.

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

2. Demand and Supply

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question. Each correct answer gives you 1 pt.

Thanksgiving Handout Economics 101 Fall 2000

Outline. Introduction. ciency. Excise Tax. Subsidy 2/29

Managerial Economics Prof. Trupti Mishra S.J.M School of Management Indian Institute of Technology, Bombay. Lecture -29 Monopoly (Contd )

P S1 S2 D2 Q D1 P S1 S2 D2 Q D1

SAMPLE FINAL. Part I - Multiple Choice Questions:

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Economic efficiency. Who gains and who loses when prices change?

University of Victoria. Economics 325 Public Economics

Econ 98 (CHIU) Midterm 1 Review: Part A Fall 2004

LECTURE NOTES ON MICROECONOMICS

Econ Introduction to Microeconomics X3-B. Name:

Chief Reader Report on Student Responses:

ECON 101 MIDTERM 1 REVIEW SESSION SOLUTIONS (WINTER 2015) BY BENJI HUANG

Problem Set #2 - Answers. Due February 2, 2000

Page 1. AP Economics Mid-Term January 2006 NAME: Date:

Chapter 9. Applying the Competitive Model

1) Your answer to this question is what form of the exam you had. The answer is A if you have form A. The answer is B if you have form B etc.

Hours needed to produce one unit of manufactured goods agricultural goods Pottawattamie 6 3 Muscatine 3 2

Individual & Market Demand and Supply

Do not remove any pages or add any pages. No additional paper is supplied

Lecture 12. Monopoly

To do today. Efficiency MB and MC Consumer surplus Producer surplus Deadweight loss. Theories of fairness

This is the midterm 1 solution guide for Fall 2012 Form A. 1) The answer to this question is A, corresponding to Form A.

AP Microeconomics Chapter 4 Outline

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

EXAMINATION 2 VERSION B "Applications of Supply and Demand" October 14, 2015

Test your understanding 4.5 (b) 1 2 (a) (c) (b) 4.5 Price controls (c) Introduction to price controls (d) (e) Price controls 3 (a) (b) (c) (d) 4

Competitive markets. Microéconomie, chapter 9. Solvay Business School Université Libre de Bruxelles

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 7, 2017 Version 01

EC101 DD/EE Midterm 2 November 7, 2017 Version 04

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Evaluating the Gains and Losses from Government Policies Consumer and Producer Surplus

Exam 01 - ECON Friday, October 1st

Econ 200 Fall Opportunity Cost and the Gains from Trade Supply and Demand Firms and Industries

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

Exam 01 - ECON Friday, October 1st

Government Price Setting, and Taxes

Econ 001: Midterm 1 Answer Key October 7th, 2010

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH. 5 - CONSUMER AND PRODUCER SURPLUS; PRICE CEILINGS AND FLOORS

Econ 98 (CHIU) Midterm 1 Review: Part A Fall 2004

ECONOMICS. Chapter 4 The Market Strikes Back

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Chapter 4. Demand, Supply and Markets. These slides supplement the textbook, but should not replace reading the textbook

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #2A

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #2B

Top 10 Most Common Errors AP Economics 2011

Professor Christina Romer SUGGESTED ANSWERS TO PROBLEM SET 2

Figure 1 MC ATC. Demand. April 1, Exam 2

January Examinations 2014

Assessment Schedule 2015 Economics: Demonstrate understanding of the efficiency of market equilibrium (91399)

Transcription:

Policy Evaluation Tools Evaluating Gov t Policy - Econ of NA - RIT - Dr. Jeffrey Burnette In economics we like to measure the impact government policies have on the economy and separate winners and losers. This way we can properly assess the effectiveness of the policy and determine whether it is having its intended result. Marginal Benefit - the extra happiness that a person receives from consuming one more unit of a good or service. Marginal Cost - the additional cost (including opportunity cost) of producing one more unit of a good or service. Willingness to Pay and Demand Since we derived the demand curve by asking the question: If the price of the product is $x how many units would you like to buy? Therefore, the demand curve is the maximum amount that an individual is willing to pay for the last unit of a good or service consumed. The maximum amount they are willing to pay for a particular unit is equal to the marginal benefit they receive from consuming that unit. Consumer Surplus (CS) Since people are not forced to pay the maximum price they are willing to pay for each unit, they receive a consumer surplus. The value of a good minus the price paid for each unit consumed. Consuming Infinitely Divisible Units Vs. Whole/Partial Units Products are sold in either infinitely divisible units or whole units only. Products like gasoline can be purchased in the exact amount you would like; these are infinitely divisible. Other products can only be purchased in specific increments. It s not possible to purchase half a bottle of soda or half of a slice of pizza. 1

Consumer Surplus with Whole Units CS n = n (MB i P ) i=1 Assume Q D = 10 - P and the P = $7 If the price of the product is $7 then the consumer will buy 3 units. The individual is willing to pay $9 for the first unit, $8 for the second unit and $7 for the third unit. However she pays only $5 for each unit. Therefore, the consumer surplus will be CS 3 = 3 i=1 (MB i P ) = (9-7) + (8-7) + (7-7) = $3. Consumer Surplus with Infinitely Divisible Units If however, the individual can consume infinitely divisible units then we calculate the Consumer Surplus as the area of the triangle between the demand curve and the price paid for the product. Often times this is a triangle or trapezoid but this is not always the case. 2

Producer Surplus (PS) Since firms are not forced to receive the minimum price for which they are willing to sell each unit, they receive a producer surplus. The producer surplus is the price of the good received minus the minimum supply price for each unit consumed. Producer Surplus with Whole Units P S n = n (P MC i ) i=1 Assume Q s = P and the P = $3 If the price of the product is $3 then the firm will sell 3 units. The firm is willing to sell the first unit for $1, the second unit for $2 and the third unit for $3. However it receives $3 for each unit. Therefore, the producer surplus will be P S 3 = 3 i=1 (P MC i) = (3-1) + (3-2) + (3-3) = $3. 3

Producer Surplus with Infinitely Divisible Units If however, the firm can sell infinitely divisible units then we calculate the Producer Surplus as the area of the triangle between the supply curve and the price received for the product. This is discussed in the book on page 107. Social Welfare 1 (SW) - The aggregate benefit to society due to the existence of a good or service. In the previous cases there are only two types of actors in the market consumers and firms therefore Social Welfare is given by the following equation, SW = CS + PS. In later cases government will levy a tax or provide a subsidy changing the Social Welfare to the following equation, SW = CS + PS + TAX or SW = CS + PS - SUB. 1 Note: When determining the social welfare for a particular market you need to remember to include all participants in the market and measure the amount of happiness they receive because the market exists. 4

Underproduction When the market produces a quantity less than the equilibrium quantity then the MSB>MSC. Conceivably, we could pay firms a lump-sum to increase production. Overproduction When the market produces a quantity greater than the equilibrium quantity then the MSC>MSB. If firms produce a lower quantity than equilibrium then a social planner could make society better off by reducing the quantity produced. Deadweight Loss - the decrease in social welfare that results from producing an inefficient quantity. Taxes In the previous discussion of equilibrium the price paid by consumers to purchase a product was equal to the price received by firms. When taxes are imposed the price paid by the individual consumer (P P ) is greater than that received by the selling firm (P R ). The relationship between the price paid and that received is: where T is the per unit tax levied on consumers. P P = P R + T (1) If the government imposes a per unit tax on firms the relationship is: P R = P P T (2) Government Imposes a Tax on Consumers If government levies a per unit tax on consumers then we need to substitute Equation (??) into the demand equation and then solve for equilibrium. To illustrate this we will use the following information: 5

10 P P = P R (4) Evaluating Gov t Policy - Econ of NA - RIT - Dr. Jeffrey Burnette Q D = 10 P P Q S = P R T = 2 (3) From before we know that the equilibrium price is $5 and that the equilibrium quantity is 5 units. Setting supply and demand equal results in: Q D = Q s At this point we have 1 equation and 2 unknowns (P P, P R ). This is where we need the information on taxes. Since, the tax is imposed on the buyer we use Equation (??). 10 (P R + 2) = P R 10 P R 2 = P R 8 = 2P R P R = 4 Now that we know the price that sellers receive we can plug this into the supply equation to calculate the equilibrium level of output. (Q T = 4) We can also find out the price purchasers pay. (P P = P R + 2 = 6) Revenue raised from the tax is equal to T Q T. (TR = $8) 6

Government Imposes a Tax on Firms When government enacts a per unit tax to be paid by firms we have to modify the supply function by substituting Equation (??) into the supply equation. This is just like what we did when calculating equilibrium with a tax on buyers. Using the same information we now impose a $2 tax on firms. 10 P P = P R 10 P P = (P P 2) 12 P P = P P 12 = 2P P P P = 6 Now that we know the price that consumers pay we can plug this into the demand equation to calculate the equilibrium level of output. (Q T = 4) We can also calculate the price firms receive. (P R = P P - 2 = 4) Revenue raised from the tax is equal to T Q T. (TR = $8) You should notice that it makes no difference if the tax is imposed on consumers or firms. Consumers end up paying $6 and firms end up receiving $4 with an equilibrium quantity of 4 units. Furthermore, in this instance consumers and firms end up dividing the tax equally. Consumers used to pay $5 for the product and are now forced to pay $6. So, they are paying $1 more for the same product and therefore $1 of the $2 tax. Firms used to receive $5 for their product but now they only get $4. So, they also pay $1 of the $2 tax. In general, the largest tax burden is borne by the group that is less sensitive to price changes, the elasticity of demand relative to that of supply. In this example the slope of the demand curve (-1) is the same magnitude as that of the supply curve (1). This is why the tax is 7

divided equally. 2 If the slope of the supply curve were greater than 1 in magnitude then consumers would bear a larger portion of the tax. Social Welfare and Taxes Earlier we analyzed the social benefit due to the existence of a market. Social benefit was initially separated into consumer and producer surplus. In the diagram above, the consumer surplus is the area of the upper left triangle ($12.50) while the producer surplus is the area of the lower left triangle ($12.50). Social welfare is the sum of all participants in the market ($12.50 + $12.50 = $25) The addition of taxes causes each consumer to pay a higher price for the same product and purchase fewer units. This means that the consumer surplus has decreased. (The new consumer surplus is now $8) Likewise, the producer surplus decreases because firms receive a lower price for their product and sell fewer units. (The new producer surplus is now $8.) This reduction in consumer and producer surplus is illustrated in the graph below. 2 While it s true that slope and elasticity are different measurements and we generally can t compare them it is possible in this instance because the units on both the x and y axis are exactly the same. 8

The imposition of a tax causes a new participant to gain from the market s existence, government is going to generate tax revenue. (The amount of tax revenue generated is $8) When tax revenue is added to the new consumer surplus and producer surplus the total benefit to society is now $24. This is $1 less than the social welfare without the tax, so society is worse off because of this policy. The lost $1 of social welfare is called the deadweight loss, and is illustrated in the above diagram by the 2 very small triangles just to the left of the intersection of the supply and demand curves. Subsidies In the previous discussion, taxes were imposed and the price paid by the individual consumer (P P ) is greater than that received by the selling firm (P R ). In the case of a subsidy we get the opposite relationship, the price received by the firm is greater than the price paid by the consumer. The relationship between the price paid and that received is: where S is the per unit subsidy given to firms. P R = P P + S (5) If the government gives a per unit subsidy to consumers the relationship is: P P = P R S (6) 9

Government Gives a Subsidy to Firms When government gives a per unit subsidy to firms we have to modify the supply function by substituting Equation (??) into the supply equation. This is just like what we did when calculating equilibrium with a tax. Using the same information as the tax example we now give a $2 subsidy to firms. 10 P P = P R 10 P P = (P P + 2) 8 P P = P P 8 = 2P P P P = 4 Now that we know the price that consumers pay, we can plug this into the demand equation to calculate the equilibrium level of output. (Q S = 6) We can also find out the price firms receive. (P R = 4 + 2 = 6) The total amount of the subsidy given is equal to S Q S. (Total subsidy = $12) You should notice that a subsidy has the opposite effect as a tax on quantity produced. However, like taxes where the burden was split, the benefit of a subsidy is also divided up between firms and consumers based upon the relative elasticities of supply and demand. Here consumers used to pay $5 for the product and now only pay $4. So, they are receiving $1 of the $2 subsidy. Firms used to receive $5 for their product but now receive $6. So, they are getting $1 of the $2 subsidy. 10

Social Welfare and Subsidies A subsidy causes each consumer to pay a lower price for the same product and therefore she purchases more units. This means that the consumer surplus increases. (The new consumer surplus is now $18) Likewise, the producer surplus increases because they receive a higher price for their product and sell more units. (The new producer surplus is now $18.) Initially it might appear that society is better off and should therefore subsidize every product however remember the government had to spend money increase production. When the amount of the subsidy is subtracted from the sum of the new consumer surplus and producer surplus the total benefit to society is now $24. ($18 + $18 - $12 = $24) This is $1 less than the social welfare without the tax, so society is also worse off by this policy. The deadweight loss is again $1 and is illustrated in the above diagram by the 2 small triangles just to the right of the intersection of the supply and demand curves. Efficiency of Government Intervention In all interventions examined there has been a reduction in the quantity of units sold in the market and therefore the government intervention created a Deadweight Loss. 11

Embedded Economies Embedded Economy - a sovereign economy contained within a larger economy. An embedded economy is different from that surrounding it. However, it is still largely governed by policies and activities of its encompassing economy. For any market, there are three possible relationships between an embedded and its surrounding economy: There is no net flow of goods between the two economies, The embedded economy is a net importer or The embedded economy is a net exporter. No Net Flow of Goods In the above case the equilibrium prices in both markets would be the same in both markets. This results in no change in consumer surplus, producer surplus or social welfare as a result of embedding the smaller economy. All of these measures of agent welfare would be the same if these economies were completely separated from one another and there no interaction is allowed. 12

Embedded Economy is a Net Importer The embedded economy is a net importer for a market when the price of the surrounding economy is less than what would clear the embedded market. This lower price results in consumers in the embedded economy purchasing additional units of this good or service because they are able to travel to the surrounding economy to procure the product. Firms are worse off and this is illustrated by the smaller producer surplus. However, the amount that producers are worse off is smaller than the benefit obtained by consumers. Consequently, there is a net increase in social welfare for the embedded economy. Embedded Economy is a Net Exporter The embedded economy is a net exporter for a market when the price of the surrounding economy is greater than what would clear the embedded market. This higher price results in firms within the embedded economy producing additional units of this good or service because they are able to sell them to consumers from the surrounding economy. Consumers are worse off and this is illustrated by the smaller consumer surplus. However, the amount that households are worse off is smaller than the benefit obtained by firms. Consequently, there is a net increase in social welfare for the embedded economy. 13

Effect of Tax by Surrounding Economy When the surrounding economy imposes a tax on its product the price consumers pay will increase. Since the encompassing economy is larger, the price in the embedded economy is that which clears the surrounding economy. In all cases the price paid for consumers in the embedded economy increases. No Net Flow of Goods In the graph below, the loss to consumer surplus caused by the higher price for households is surpassed by the increase in producer surplus because firms produce additional units of the product and receive a higher price for its sale. This results in an overall increase in social welfare for the embedded economy and in the embedded economy becoming an net exporter of the good to the surrounding economy. 14

Embedded Economy is a Net Importer When the embedded economy is a net importer in the market, the loss to consumer surplus caused by the higher price for households is greater than the increase to producer surplus. This results in an overall decrease in social welfare (or dead-weight loss) and net imports for the embedded economy. This makes sense because embedded consumers are primarily obtaining the product from the outside economy and are much better off doing so because the cost of producing these units by embedded firms is larger than the price of the product in the outside market. 15

Embedded Economy is a Net Exporter When the embedded economy is a net exporter in the market, the gain to producer surplus from the higher price for firms is greater than the decrease to consumer surplus. This results in an overall increase in social welfare and net exports for the embedded economy. Again, this is because embedded firms are more efficient at producing the product than the outside economy. As a consequence, embedded firms are much better off producing these units and the extra benefit obtained by embedded households from consuming these fewer units is less than the price firms receive from producing it for outside consumers. 16

Effect of Subsidy by Embedded Economy When the surrounding economy pays out a subsidy to its firms for producing goods and services firms will produce additional units but the embedded consumers will not benefit from a lower price. Again, price is determined in the larger encompassing economy. In all cases the embedded economy suffers a dead-weight loss. No Net Flow of Goods In the situation below, the embedded economy turns into a net exporter of the good or service and there is an increase in the producer surplus. However, since the consumer does not receive a lower price, the firm is the sole beneficiary from any subsidy. Furthermore, the extra benefit to the firm from the subsidy is less than the pay out by the embedded government. The end result is a dead-weight loss for the embedded economy from this policy. 17

Embedded Economy is a Net Importer 18

When the embedded economy is a net importer, there is a decrease in the level of imports and it may even turn into a net exporter of the good or service. As a consequence, there is an increase in the producer surplus and again the firm is the sole beneficiary from any subsidy. As in earlier cases, the extra benefit to the firm from the subsidy is less than the pay out by the embedded government and there is a dead-weight loss for the embedded economy. Embedded Economy is a Net Exporter When the embedded economy is a net exporter, there is an increase in the level of exports and an increase in the producer surplus. Again, the firm is the sole beneficiary from any subsidy, the extra benefit to the firm from the subsidy is less than the pay out by the embedded government and there is a dead-weight loss for the embedded economy. 19

Special Cases Change in Profits for Individual Firm As you would expect, firms in the embedded economy benefit from the surrounding economy imposing a tax. Hence, the propensity for Native Nations to sell cigarettes and gasoline; two goods that are heavily taxed. The individual firm will produce additional units and sell its product for a higher price. This result could have been inferred from our earlier analysis concerning the relationship between taxes and the producer surplus. Impact of Minimum Wage in Surrounding Economy When the surrounding economy imposes a price floor, or Minimum wage, the embedded economy looses. The wage rate is too high for the embedded economy to achieve equilibrium and it becomes a net exporter. In the case of the labor market, workers who wish to remain on the reservation will find it hard to find a job and the level of unemployment will be significant. We do not need a minimum wage in the encompassing economy to achieve this result. This is still likely to happen when the prevailing wage in the outside market is higher than that in the embedded economy. This result mirrors what we see in the Native Labor market in that the model predicts high unemployment rates and highly educated individuals leaving to participate in the surrounding labor market. 20