CLIMATE POLICY IN A DISORGANIZED WORLD

Similar documents
Separate Markets for Externalities: Regional versus State-by-State Regulation of a Global Pollutant

The Implications of Heterogeneity for the Regulation of Energy-Consuming Durable Goods

PJM Phase 1 Long-Term Economic Analysis of the EPA s Final Clean Power Plan Rule

PERFORMANCE, PROCESS, AND DESIGN STANDARDS IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION

Strategic Policy Choice in State-Level Regulation: The EPA s Clean Power Plan

Dominion Virginia Power and Clean Power Plan Costs: A brief review of the Dominion s 2015 Integrated Resource Plan compliance cost estimates

December Subject: Commission on Carbon Prices Call for Input. Dear Professor Stiglitz and Lord Stern:

A Review of Markets for Clean Air: The U.S. Acid Rain Program

1. Supply and demand are the most important concepts in economics.

Copyright 2009 by all authors. Published and used by MIT ESD and CESUN with permission.

Impacts of Announced Nuclear Retirements in Ohio and Pennsylvania

PJM Analysis of the EPA Clean Power Plan

Vertical Targeting and Leakage in Carbon Policy

European Union Emissions Trading Scheme enough for climate mitigation?

Transmission Congestion and Loss Only Virtual Product. Overview

Cumulative carbon and its implications What they could agree in Paris

MISO/PJM Joint Modeling Case Study: Clean Power Analysis

Emission Portfolio Standards

EPA's Clean Power Plan Proposal: A Summary of Key Results from PJM's Economic Analysis

Non-Horizontal Mergers Guidelines: Ten Principles. A Note by the EAGCP Merger Sub-Group

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA ENERGY INSTITUTE EDITOR: KAREN NOTSUND

TODAY S ORGANIZED MARKETS A STEP TOWARD COMPETITION OR AN EXERCISE IN RE-REGULATION?

Web Appendix to "Incomplete Environmental Regulation, Imperfect Competition, and Emissions Leakage"

How well does the current EU climate policy mix perform? A look at the non-ets sector Insights from the CECILIA2050 project

Game Theory & Firms. Jacob LaRiviere & Justin Rao April 20, 2016 Econ 404, Spring 2016

Strategic Policy Choice in State-Level Regulation: The EPA's Clean Power Plan

Dynamic Responses to Carbon Pricing in the Electricity Sector

Statement of Stephen A. Smith, DVM Executive Director Southern Alliance for Clean Energy

ENERGY ECONOMICS. Stef Proost & Guido Pepermans. Leuven / Den Haag

Economics 155/Earth Systems 112 Spring Final Exam

Optimal Pricing of Electricity in a World with Affordable Distributed Energy

PJM Perspective of the EPA Clean Power Plan: Analysis

Comparison of CAIR and CAIR Plus Proposal using the Integrated Planning Model (IPM ) Mid-Atlantic Regional Air Management Association (MARAMA)

Don t Short Circuit the Ohio Electricity Market: A Q&A with Dr. Joe Bowring on State Subsidies and Power Plant Bailouts

Overview of EPA Analysis of the American Clean Energy and Security Act of 2009 H.R in the 111 th Congress

Lecture 12. Monopoly

CO 2 Emissions from Electricity Generation and Imports in the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative: 2011 Monitoring Report

Subject: Comments on Virginia s proposal to join the Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative. Dear Executive Director McKeon and Members of the RGGI Board,

Economics Bulletin, 2012, Vol. 32 No. 4 pp Introduction

Lecture 17 - Externalities, the Coase Theorem and Market Remedies

Getting in touch with reality

Maintaining Baseload Generation Capacity

SYMPOSIUM PAPER. Renewable Electricity Policies, Heterogeneity, and Cost-Effectiveness

Vertical Mergers. The retailer has marginal cost of Pu+lOO where PU is the price per unit charged by the upstream manufacturer Grapefruit.

The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative (RGGI)

B. S. Fisher and M. D. Hinchy Australian Bureau of Agricultural and Resource Economics, Canberra, Australia

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA BEFORE THE FEDERAL ENERGY REGULATORY COMMISSION

The economics of competitive markets Rolands Irklis

DRAFT. Mike Walker A brief survey of the economic thinking on bundling and tying

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model

Imperfect Price Information and Competition

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS AND FINANCE COLLEGE OF BUSINESS AND ECONOMICS UNIVERSITY OF CANTERBURY CHRISTCHURCH, NEW ZEALAND

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling

Carbon Tariffs in Climate Policy A Critical Appraisal

Climate Change and Energy Sector Transformation: Implications for Asia-Pacific Including Japan

The Final Clean Power Plan An Initial Assessment

The Value of Markets. The History of Markets

European Commission DG Energy Unit B2: Wholesale markets, electricity & gas Office: DM24, 6th floor Rue De Mot 24 B 1049 Brussels/Belgium

Real Options Application Portfolio:

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

Catalyzing carbon markets globally to realize the promise of Paris: The power of markets to increase ambition

An Assessment of the Efficacy and Cost of Alternative Carbon Mitigation Polices for the State of Indiana under the Framework of IN-MARKAL

Collaborative EPRI Analysis of CO 2 Price Impacts on Western Power Markets:

Informal Input Suppliers

EDF EU Group entities are regulated under EU ETS and EDF operates on the carbon market (EUAs and CERs/ERUs) through EDF-T, its trading entity

8. Consumption, uncertainty, and the current account

MARGIN SQUEEZE IN THE U.S. AND THE EU: WHY THEY DIFFER?

The Benefits of Fostering Innovation in Storage and Grid Management Technologies under Imperfect Information

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Reducing Carbon Pollution in Maryland s Renewable Portfolio Standard Will Clean the Air without Impacting Ratepayers. Frequently Asked Questions

KLEINMAN CENTER. PROCEEDING REPORT Exploring Clean Power Plan Compliance Options for Pennsylvania March 23 rd, for ENERGY POLICY.

Competition or Regulation? The Texas Electricity Market. Bill Peacock Vice President of Research Director, Center for Economic Freedom

Pathways to 2050 The role of nuclear in a low-carbon Europe. 19 November 2018

Measuring exclusionary effects under Article 82

The Marginal Effects of the Price for Carbon Dioxide: Quantifying the Effects on the Market for Electric Generation in Florida

Squeezed and damaged: follow-on damages actions in margin squeeze cases

Carbon leakage: theory and evidence

Market Power Mitigation in Organized Electricity Markets

Perfect surcharging and the tourist test interchange. fee

Recent Trends and Experience in US Capacity Markets

The Economics of Carbon Capture and CO 2 Emission Charges

Evaluating Cooperation Opportunities Under CAA 111(d)

GLOBAL CLIMATE CHANGE MITIGATION: Role of BECCS

Mergers in the energy sector. Xavier Vives IESE Business School

COMMENTS OF COMVERGE, INC. NEW JERSEY CAPACITY ISSUES TECHNICAL CONFERENCE

Regulating oligopolies in telecoms: the new European Commission guidelines

EPA s Clean Power Plan Proposal Review of PJM Analyses Preliminary Results

Fall Application Portfolio: East Coast Offshore Wind Farm Development. David Hwang ESD.71 Prof. Richard de Neufville

Marginal Price Assumptions For Estimating Customer Benefits of Air Conditioner Efficiency Standards:

Some remarks on pricing abuses

Implications of Policy-Driven Residential Electrification

Using Competitive Markets to Achieve Policy Objectives

Wind Energy in Canada

Independent Assessment of Conservation and Energy Efficiency Potential for Connecticut and the Southwest Connecticut Region FINAL REPORT June 2004

Principles of implementation and best practice regarding the application of Retail Minus pricing methodologies IRG (05) 39

University of California, Davis

Carbon Pricing Straw Proposal. A Report Prepared for the Integrating Public Policy Task Force. April 30, 2018 DRAFT FOR DISCUSSION PURPOSES ONLY

Transcription:

1 CLIMATE POLICY IN A DISORGANIZED WORLD SEPARATE VERSUS SINGLE MARKETS FOR EXTERNALITIES December 14, 2017 By Dr. Jose Miguel Abito

1 CLIMATE POLICY IN A DISORGANIZED WORLD SEPARATE VERSUS SINGLE MARKETS FOR EXTERNALITIES Dr. Jose Miguel Abito, December 14, 2017 kleinmanenergy.upenn.edu ECONOMISTS HAVE LONG ADVOCATED FOR MARKET- BASED SOLUTIONS TO CORRECT ENVIRONMENTAL EXTERNALITY PROBLEMS SUCH AS HARMFUL EMISSIONS FROM COMBUSTION OF FOSSIL FUELS, IN PLACE OF TRADITIONAL COMMAND AND CONTROL REGULATIONS. A well-known example of a market-based solution is to create a market for emission permits. In this market, polluting firms have to carry enough permits for every ton of emissions they pollute. Firms that tend to emit more need to buy permits, while firms that reduce emissions through their own efforts can sell their excess permits for a profit. In theory, market-based solutions leave the guesswork out of regulators hands, and let firms decide the best way to reduce emissions. For market-based solutions to be effective, one has to cover multiple jurisdictions to take advantage of trade gains from heterogeneous polluting sources. Efficiency requires that the marginal abatement cost across sources be equal, otherwise it would be beneficial to shift abatement from higher cost sources to lower cost ones. With the United States planning to withdraw from the Paris Climate Accord, the future of a coordinated, global solution to climate change seems bleak. Only separate markets, at best, may be feasible due to the difficulty of coordinating regulations across jurisdictions, be it states within a given country such as the U.S., or individual nation-states. The near-infeasibility of organizing a single market raises the question to what extent having separate markets will be an adequate substitute for a single market. We seek to answer this question in a recent project that we summarize in this article. 1 The project s main objective is to empirically address this question by examining the relative economic efficiency of single versus separate markets in an actual, real-life setting. MOTIVATION Our work is motivated by recent failures to coordinate environmental policies across states or countries. One such example that closely motivates our work is the current legal and political challenge to the U.S. Clean Power Plan (CPP), a federal regulation based on the Clean Air Act that sets CO 2 emissions limits from electric power plants for 2022 to 2030. Although the CPP is designed as a federal mandate, the final form of CO 2 regulation is likely to be at the state level. There are two reasons that CPP implementation may be at the state level. First, the Clean Air Act only authorizes the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) to set targets at the state level and solicit state implementation plans to achieve these targets. Second, the Trump administration ordered a CPP review in March 2017 that may delay or even terminate efforts to regulate CO 2 emissions at a federal level. If the second and less optimistic scenario materializes, any regulation of CO 2 emissions will be a state-level effort. A second example is the withdrawal of the United Kingdom from the European Union (EU). This process, known as Brexit, may imply a UK departure from the European Union Emissions Trading System (EU-ETS) as well, and force the UK to create its own carbon market. The discussion of which type of environmental policy the UK can implement by itself has already started. This is particularly important in light of the fact that, while the UK pledged a 57% emission reduction in the Paris Agreement, the EU as a whole was less ambitious, proposing only a 40% reduction (Hepburn and Teytelboym, 2017). 1 This article is based on the paper Separate Markets for Externalities: Regional versus State-by-State Regulation of a Global Pollutant by Mike Abito (Wharton), Chris Knittel (MIT), Kostas Metaxoglou (Carleton), and Andre Trindade (FGV).

2 SETTING We estimate a structural model of production and investment decisions, and use this model to simulate firms' behavior under single and separate CO 2 markets. We use data from electric utilities that participate in the Pennsylvania-New Jersey-Maryland (PJM) wholesale electricity market and consider CO 2 emissions regulation implemented through the Clean Air Act. PJM operates one of the world s largest wholesale markets as the regional transmission organization that covers 13 states. into account the allocation of production and the resulting distribution of CO 2 prices across markets. All else equal, profit-maximizing firms move production from markets with higher CO 2 prices to markets with lower CO 2 prices. In a frictionless environment, output reallocation and CO 2 price readjustment will lead to convergence of CO 2 prices, as if there were a single market for emissions. In practice, frictions exist that would prevent perfect reallocation of output and readjustment of CO 2 prices. Here, we focus on capacity constraints as the main friction and this is the motivation for including investment in new generating capacity in our analysis. Figure 1: PJM Footprint (Source: www.ieefa.org/pjmsreform) Figure 1 shows the PJM footprint. Electric utilities own plants scattered across these states. Plants generate electricity that is then sold in the PJM wholesale market and distributed across the region. In terms of CO 2 emissions regulation, the Clean Air Act authorizes the EPA to set state-wide emissions limits for existing plants, and separate source-specific regulations for new plants. Although states are free to coordinate and meet the targets as a group, the EPA does not have the authority or power to compel states to do so, even if it would be efficient from a social welfare objective. The main economic insight of our policy digest is that the negative effects of separate markets for CO 2 emissions are greatly mitigated by firms participation in an integrated wholesale market for electricity. Facing an integrated electricity market, firms will optimally make their output and investment decisions, taking MODEL Our model consists of a set of firms that own portfolios of plants across different states. Differences in plant age, technology, and location affect the cost of electricity generation. In each period, firms produce electricity using their existing plants and sell it in the PJM wholesale electricity market. Although the wholesale electricity market is approximately competitive due to forward contracts (Bushnell, Mansur, and Saravia, 2008), we assume that investment decisions are strategic in the sense that firms take into account capacity reactions by rivals and the impact of investment on future prices, similar to the model in Dixon (1985). Firms decide how much to invest in coal- and gas-fired generation. Investment in new capacity allows firms to produce at lower cost and, potentially, increase profits from electricity sales in subsequent periods. To capture in a realistic way firms' supply decisions and incentives to invest in response to regulation, we need a model that preserves the heterogeneity of costs across plants, and tracks their evolution as firms add new capacity. Plant costs depend on a number of factors: efficiency (heat rate), emission rates for various pollutants and associated compliance costs, fuel prices, and other operations-and-maintenance (O&M) costs. As a result, a high-dimensional state vector is required to track the evolution of all these factors for the existing plants and the new capacity in which firms invest. Our approach is novel and consists of leveraging on the observation that new capacity will be infra-marginal in the wholesale electricity market at least, in the medium run. Because of this, it suffices to keep track of the average heat and emission rates of cumulative

3 investment over time. As a result, we substantially reduce the dimension of the state vector, which significantly alleviates the computational burden for our structural model while still incorporating the relevant information on plants' costs. We construct estimates for plant-level marginal cost using information directly from the data (Bushnell, Mansur, and Saravia, 2008; Mansur, 2007); Firm-level marginal costs are then step-functions, where each step represents a firm's plant. To get investment costs, we estimate the model using the two-step approach in Bajari, Benkard, and Levin (2007), following closely the application in Ryan (2012) and Fowlie, Reguant, and Ryan (2016). The production and investment cost estimates (together with demand and fuel cost estimates) allow us to predict supply and investment decisions of firms facing CO 2 emissions regulation, and we solve a series of dynamic investment problems for single and separate markets to compare outcomes across these two counterfactual scenarios. RESULTS Table 1 contains our main results. Dollar values are present discounted lifetime values from 2013 onward. New capacity is cumulative investment from 2013 until 2030. Fixing capacity and investment to be equal for both single and separate market scenarios, we find welfare losses of at most $1 billion under separate markets. Note that this loss is relatively small: It reflects less than 0.1% of welfare. In other words, the ability of firms to reallocate output alone allows separate markets to achieve almost the same welfare outcome as with a single market. If we allow firms to optimally invest in response to the type of CO 2 market(s) they face, we actually find welfare across the two scenarios to be closer to equal or even higher under separate markets in cases where investment is concentrated to a few firms. 2 The reason is that investment incentives are stronger in separate markets. Intuitively, since firms under separate markets do not have the option to buy permits from potentially lower cost units in other markets, CO 2 compliance costs are higher, leading to greater increases in plants' generating cost. But greater increases in cost can encourage more investment as long as new capacity has a sufficient cost advantage relative to the expost marginal plant. Of course, this will depend on several factors such as: the existing plant portfolio, characteristics of marginal and infra-marginal plants for each possible investment choice, evolution of new capacity efficiency, and investment cost which stresses the importance of having a model that preserves the rich heterogeneity of plants within and across firms. Scenerio New Capacity (GW) Consumer Surplus Firm Profits Emissions Damages Total Welfare Single Market 19 1016 224 110 1130 Separate Markets (fixed capacity) Separate Markets (optimal investment) Single Market (highly concentrated) Separate Markets (highly concentrated) 19 986 248 107 1129 20 944 244 108 1131 16 944 263 101 1106 20 952 266 102 1116 Single Market w/ NSC 0.1 925 251 99 1077 Table 1: Main results 2 For example, in the case where the top 10 utilities coordinate investment decisions, BAT capacity under separate markets is 20 GW compared to 16 GW under a single market, which leads to $10 billion higher welfare under separate markets. This gap narrows down quickly however as more utilities decide their investment independently. In the case of free entry and zero profits, we find that investment and welfare under the two scenarios are exactly equal.

4 An important point in our exercise is that CO 2 regulation under the Clean Air Act treats existing and new capacity differently. Essentially, existing capacity pays a CO 2 price while new capacity does not. However, new capacity is required to meet a specific emissions standard, so it does not necessarily mean new capacity is fully exempt from regulation. This institutional feature influences our results, since new capacity becomes very attractive relative to existing capacity. Nevertheless, new capacity tends to be more efficient and cleaner than existing capacity. In fact, although there will certainly be emissions leakage, i.e. output intended to be produced by existing plants now going to essentially unregulated new capacity, emissions damages are actually lower with separate markets. 3 To combat emissions leakage to new capacity, policymakers allow states to adopt what is called a New Source Complement (NSC). If a state decides to adopt the NSC, the allowed emissions of the state will be increased by some amount that depends on forecasted future load. The idea is that future load will be met by investment, and the emissions limit will be adjusted accordingly via the NSC. Note however that the NSC is built-in ex-ante, that is, before investment actually materializes, and cannot be conditioned on investment. Otherwise, existing and new capacity will have different CO 2 prices. This means that firms will optimally decide on the level of investment after the limit has already been increased with the NSC, i.e. a more lax regulation. As we see in the table, this drastically decreases investment and leads to welfare inferior outcomes. The takeaway here is that any form of adjustment based on future action has to be carefully thought of so as not to introduce perverse and unintended incentives. 3 It is slightly higher when investment decisions are highly concentrated, however the difference is not huge.

5 BIBLIOGRAPHY Bajari, P., C. Benkard, and J. Levin (2007): Estimating Dynamic Models of Imperfect Competition," Econometrica, 75, 1331-1370. Bushnell, J., E. Mansur, and C. Saravia (2008): Vertical Arrangements, Market Structure, and Competition: An Analysis of Restructured US Electricity Markets," American Economic Review, 98, 237-266. Dixon, H. (1985): Strategic investment in a competitive industry," Journal of Industrial Economics, 33, 483-500. Fowlie, M., M. Reguant, and S. Ryan (2016): Market-based emissions regulation and industry dynamics," Journal of Political Economy, 124, 249-302. Hepburn, C. and A. Teytelboym (2017): Climate change after Brexit, Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 33:1, S144-S154. Mansur, E. T. (2007): Upstream Competition and Vertical Integration in Electricity Markets," Journal of Law and Economics, 50, pp. 125-156. Ryan, S. (2012): The Costs of Environmental Regulation in a Concentrated Industry," Econometrica, 80, 1019-1061.

ABOUT THE AUTHOR Dr. Jose Miguel Abito is assistant professor in the business economics and public policy department at the Wharton School. The research featured here was supported by grant funding from the Kleinman Center. The author wishes to acknowledge the helpful comments of Dr. James R. Hines. Any remaining errors are the responsibility of the author alone.