Response prepared by Augusta Maciuleviciuté, Agustín Reyna and Jean Allix

Similar documents
THE ROLE OF PUBLISHERS IN THE COPYRIGHT VALUE

BEREC DRAFT STRATEGY

DRAFT DELEGATED REGULATION ON STRONG CUSTOMER AUTHENTICATION AND SECURE COMMUNICATION

PROPOSAL FOR A BETTER ENFORCEMENT AND

EUROPEAN ELECTRONIC COMMUNICATIONS CODE

PUBLIC CONSULTATION ON GEO-BLOCKING AND OTHER GEOGRAPHICALLY-BASED RESTRICTIONS WHEN SHOPPING AND ACCESSING INFORMATION IN THE EU

BEREC DRAFT REPORT ON OTT SERVICES

EU ECOLABEL FOR FLUSHING TOILETS AND URINALS EEB, INFORSE and BEUC position on criteria proposal to be voted on 20 th of June 2013

Cooperation between data protection agencies and competition authorities could be two-way depending on the area of work involved.

HOW MANY LIKES FOR THE GERMAN FACEBOOK ANTITRUST PROBE?

BEUC RESPONSE TO EUROPEAN BANKING AUTHORITY DISCUSSION PAPER

Financial Support for Energy Efficiency in Buildings

EMPOWERING THE NATIONAL COMPETITION

Competition and personal data protection

Network Effects and the Efficiency Defense in Mergers among Two-Sided Platforms

ENABLING CONSUMERS TO GENERATE THEIR OWN RENEWABLE ELECTRICITY

New merger control guidelines for transaction value thresholds in Austria and Germany

ENERGY BILLING: LANDSCAPE REPORT AND SUMMARY

What do changing business models in the telecoms industry mean for competition law and regulation in the digital era?

EU and German Competition Law II (Abuse of a dominant position, Merger Control)

Vertical restraints, digital marketplaces, and enforcement tools

MANDATORY TRANSPARENCY REGISTER

In electronic form on the EUR-Lex website under document number 32017M8640

Big Data and Competition: The policies, issues and challenges ahead

GREENER, BETTER, FASTER, STRONGER ECODESIGN

European Association of Co-operative Banks Groupement Européen des Banques Coopératives Europäische Vereinigung der Genossenschaftsbanken

Dynamic markets and dynamic enforcement: a focus on merger control

&DVH 1R,90 %8+50$11 &25325$7( (;35(66 5(*8/$7,21((&1R 0(5*(5352&('85( Article 6(1)(b) NON-OPPOSITION Date: 08/09/1999

Big Data and Competition Law Preliminary thoughts

Report A closer look at Online video platforms

Simplified procedure: EU Practice

Mergers: Commission clears proposed merger between Telefónica Deutschland (Telefónica) E-Plus subject to conditions-frequently asked questions

Samson Esayas, NRCCL

2. Facebook is a US American company. Why does the Bundeskartellamt have competence to investigate in this case?

COLLABORATIVE ECONOMY

Bundeskartellamt prohibits Facebook from combining user data from different sources

PSD2 AND SECURITY ISSUES

VDA competition law guidelines. A manual for our Association work

ECONOMIC CONCENTRATION IN THE CONTEXT OF THE WORLD ECONOMY GLOBALIZATION

INPUT FORECLOSURE IN TELECOMS/MEDIA VERTICAL MERGERS: THE MEO/GMC CASE

Payments pricing and competition rules the European debates

November 22, To whom it may concern,

PLUGGING THE GAP IN CONSUMER RIGHTS

CONTENT MEDIA TELECOM COMPETITITION ISSUES

Regulation of multilateral interchange fees MIF : An experiment with an uncertain outcome!

Online advertising: more antitrust enforcement to come

DIGITAL MARKETS AND MERGER CONTROL IN THE EU: EVOLUTION, NOT REVOLUTION?

Improving enforcement cooperation BEUC response to the consultation on the review of Consumer Protection Cooperation (CPC) Regulation

MULTI-TERRITORY LICENSING OF MUSIC ONLINE DG Competition s Online Commerce Roundtable. BEUC Statement

Anti-unfair competition developments

Enforcement of EU competition policy

Competition policy: The challenge of digital markets

DATA IN EU MERGER CONTROL

Privacy and Corporate Responsibility

David Stephenson European Card Payment Association. nexo Annual Conference Barcelona, 12 October 2016

THE LIBERALIZATION PROCESS OFTHE TELECOM MARKET IN ROMANIA AND EUROPEAN UNION

The application of competition law to small-and-medium enterprises: lessons from selected APEC countries

Data and competition law

Case No COMP/JV.45 - * BERTELSMANN / KOOPERATIVA FÖRBUNDET / BOL NORDIC. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE

5998/1/16 REV 1 FS/evt 1 DG G 3 C

Case No COMP/M MEXICHEM/ VESTOLIT

INSTANT PAYMENTS. The right time to share investments.

ETNO Comments on the BEREC report on the impact of premium content on ECS markets and the effect of devices on the open use of the Internet

COMPETITION COUNCIL. Art. 33 became art. 32 by republishing the Competition Law no. 21/1996;

Protecting Consumers in the Digital Single Market:

Presenting the Annual Competition Report

TOOL #22. THE "SME TEST"

EUROPEAN ASSOCIATION OF CO-OPERATIVE BANKS The Co-operative difference : Sustainability, Profitability, Governance

Simplified procedure: EU Practice

Implications of E-commerce for Competition Policy - Note by Romania

Case No IV/M Thomson / CSF / Finmeccanica / Elettronica. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE

Case M PGA / MSA. REGULATION (EC) No 139/2004 MERGER PROCEDURE. In electronic form on the EUR-Lex website under document number 32015M7747

Green Paper on Unfair Trading Practices (UTPs) in the business-to-business food and non food supply chain in Europe

UPS Response to the ERGP 2019 Work Program September 2018

COMMENTS ON THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION'S DRAFT CONSOLIDATED JURISDICTIONAL NOTICE. Lovells 1. SUMMARY OF PRINCIPAL COMMENTS

EUROPEAN COMMISSION. Comments pursuant to Article 7(3) of Directive 2002/21/EC

CERRE CENTRE ON REGULATION IN EUROPE

THE ESTONIAN MINISTRY OF FINANCE, THE BANK OF ESTONIA AND THE ESTONIAN FINANCIAL SUPERVISION AUTHORITY

Case No COMP/M UPS / Menlo. REGULATION (EC) No 139/2004 MERGER PROCEDURE. Article 6(1)(b) NON-OPPOSITION Date: 10/12/2004

Introduction. The findings. The wider context ANTITRUST

Après moi, le déluge! *

EDiMA response to European Commission Consultation on the application of the Unfair Commercial Practices Directive (2005/29/EC)

Antitrust Enforcement and the Two-sided Market Theory: EU Payment Card Cases. Katarzyna Czapracka (White & Case Brussels)

EU Commission Consultation on the Role of Online Platforms 1

Merger Control for the Acquisition of Non-controlling Minority Shareholdings: Using a Sledgehammer to Crack a Nut? Andreas Fuchs

COMP/M SITA SVERIGE AB / SYDKRAFT ECOPLUS

Enel Group response to EC Consultation on the White Paper "Towards more effective merger control".

COMMISSION OF THE EUROPEAN COMMUNITIES

Case No IV/M ICI / TIOXIDE. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE. Article 6(1)(b) NON-OPPOSITION Date:

Facebook / Germany a new frontier for privacy and competition?

Creating value from the open API economy A blueprint for banks

Antitrust Assessment of MIF and the tourist test

Journal of Internet Banking and Commerce

ERPB REACTION TO THE EUROPEAN COMMISSION S GREEN PAPER ON RETAIL FINANCIAL SERVICES

COMMISSION DELEGATED REGULATION (EU) No /.. of XXX

Case No COMP/M BAIN CAPITAL / DOR CHEMICAL / TRESPAPHAN. REGULATION (EEC) No 4064/89 MERGER PROCEDURE

Journal of Internet Banking and Commerce

Merger Review What s It All About?

EXPLANATORY MEMORANDUM

Transcription:

The Consumer Voice in Europe EU MERGER CONTROL BEUC s comments on jurisdictional thresholds Contact: Agustín Reyna - digital@beuc.eu Response prepared by Augusta Maciuleviciuté, Agustín Reyna and Jean Allix BUREAU EUROPÉEN DES UNIONS DE CONSOMMATEURS AISBL DER EUROPÄISCHE VERBRAUCHERVERBAND Rue d Arlon 80, B-1040 Brussels Tel. +32 (0)2 743 15 90 www.twitter.com/beuc consumers@beuc.eu www.beuc.eu EC register for interest representatives: identification number 9505781573-45 Co-funded by the European Union Ref: BEUC-X-2017-010 - 10/02/2017 1

Why it matters to consumers Consumer welfare in the Single Market depends on the existence of competitive markets. Market concentration resulting from mergers could restrict choice and lead to higher prices. Therefore, the European Commission and competition authorities must be equipped with the necessary tools to assess possible anticompetitive effects of corporate reorganisations. The current EU rules based on turnover thresholds are insufficient to allow the European Commission (DG Competition) to assess important mergers between companies whose assets are based on consumer data. This has the potential to harm consumers who are not only greatly exposed to unfair business practices based on the use of these large amounts of data but also lead to fewer choices among digital services since data concentration could raise barriers to new companies to innovate and enter markets already dominated by few online players. Summary BEUC welcomes the European Commission s consultation on procedural and jurisdictional aspects of EU merger control. The current system based on turnover thresholds does not cover situations of corporate reorganisation that could affect competition in the Single Market due to the transfer of high-value assets (such as Intellectual Property Rights or consumers data). Additionally, the current rules have proved to be insufficient to scrutinise mergers in twosided markets e.g. payment card schemes, social networks or auction sites. This is especially true for mergers between companies providing digital services which do not meet the turnover threshold but would nevertheless impact competition due to the number of consumers affected. Therefore, BEUC suggests to add two new criteria to the jurisdictional rules of the EU Merger Regulation, namely: The transfer of value given by the amount of the operation and, The number of consumers directly impacted by the operation in two-sided markets. These two new criteria would provide the necessary flexibility to scrutinise mergers which could impact competition in the Single Market as well as prevent that the concentration of data by few companies is used unfairly against consumers. Finally if the European Commission decides to introduce new rules for jurisdictional threshold, BEUC recommends that there is a mid-term evaluation about the number of mergers that have been scrutinised under each jurisdictional threshold. 1

1. Introduction Merger control plays a fundamental role to ensure that corporate reorganisation does not lead to market concentration restricting consumer choice and boosting prices. During the last decade, an increasing number of acquisitions by internet giants has raised serious competition concerns. For example, Apple has acquired over 80 companies (many of them US-based companies) but only one merger was scrutinised by DG Competition 1. Similarly, during the last two decades Google (today Alphabet) bought almost 200 companies and only 3 operations were scrutinised by DG Competition. It is worth noting that in the Google/Double Click case 2 DG Competition assessed the merger not because of its Union dimension (based on turnover thresholds) but because the concentration qualified for review under the national competition laws of at least three Member States (point 7). This is the same situation as with the acquisition of WhatsApp by Facebook 3. It is worrisome that due to the current jurisdictional thresholds of Article 1 of the EU Merger Regulation some of these merger operations did escape the oversight of DG Competition despite their eventual anti-competitive effects. Against this background, merger control as an ex-ante measure is essential to anticipate problems arising from market concentration that would impact directly consumers who could see less choices available in the market and higher prices. In the so-called zero price markets, there is a risk that mergers involving lots of consumer data could lead to less consumer choice or lower quality products. For examples this would happen if the merged company would no longer need to differentiate themselves from competing businesses based on the security or privacy features of their services or products. Additionally, data concentration increases the risks that companies will unfairly use consumers data and eventually breach data protection and consumer laws as seen in the recent cases brought by BEUC members UFC-Que Choisir (France) 4 and Verbraucherzentrale Bundesverband (Germany) 5. 2. Why the single criterion of turnover is problematic? If a merger has a Union dimension the concerned party has the obligation to notify it to DG Competition to be cleared before implementation. For the time being the only criterion under EU law to define the Union dimension is the turnover of the merging companies according to article 1 of the EU Merger Regulation 6. The turnover threshold criterion has been useful to scrutinise operations between companies with an important presence in the Single Market. However, it has failed to address corporate reorganisations of companies acquiring high-value assets in the form 1 M7290 Apple / Beats 2 M4731 Google / Doubleclick 3 M7217 Facebook / WhatsApp 4 Ref.: https://www.quechoisir.org/action-ufc-que-choisir-donnees-personnelles-l-ufc-que-choisir-attaque-lesreseaux-sociaux-et-appelle-les-consommateurs-a-garder-la-main-sur-leurs-donnees-n11951/ 5 Ref.: http://www.vzbv.de/pressemitteilung/vzbv-verklagt-whatsapp-verbraucher-muessen-hoheit-ueberdaten-behalten 6 Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 2

of Intellectual Property Rights or involving the transfer of a client base which do not (immediately) translate into an increased market turnover 7. This situation poses problems from a consumer perspective. There is no assessment of the potential negative effects on competition if a company acquires such high-value assets or a database of customers information. In the network economy, platforms are essential for the functioning of the market but their turnover can easily be below the EU thresholds. Payment cards are a classic example. In this case, the role of the platform is to organise a transfer of funds of the payment from the payer to the payee. Card payments represent a huge market in value, but the platform as such i.e. the card scheme receives only a very small fraction of the amount of the transactions. Thus, the turnover corresponding to the platform facility is usually very low. For example, in the nineties 3 international payment schemes existed in the EU: Visa, MasterCard and Eurocard. In 1992, MasterCard bought Eurocard, the only European scheme. DG Competition was not able to assess this merger due to the lack of competence based on the undertakings turnover. As a result, only two payment networks remain active in Europe leading to a number of competition problems reflected in the increase of multilateral interchange fees or abusive terms imposed on retailers by the payment providers. Two-sided markets 8 are not a new issue in competition policy. But this concept has gained importance due to the development of digital services which are based on intermediary platforms. There are various examples across different sectors including auction platforms, transportation services, etc. Platforms often ask a fee from their users for providing the intermediation service but sometimes these fees are paid by one category of users (e.g. a third party providing a service) and not by the other (e.g. a consumer). Therefore, the low level of turnover is not representative of the company s activities in the platform economy. Mergers falling in this category could easily escape the European Commission s scrutiny. For example, under the current EU rules DG Competition would not have had competence to look into the Facebook/WhatsApp acquisition if not because of the voluntary notification by Facebook under article 4(5) of the EU Merger Regulation 9. The merger was notified to the European Commission based on the fact that the operation was capable of being reviewed under the national competition law of three member states (point 10 of the decision). The two companies decided to ask to the European Commission to deal with the case and the concerned Member States did not oppose to it (point 12). This file became an EU investigation only due to the decision of the parties. The case of Facebook/WhatsApp is a very good example of how big data can have significant effects on a two-sided market. By aggregating the huge amount of data handled by WhatsApp, the merger gives a competitive advantage to Facebook. Even if there is some duplication between Messenger and WhatsApp activities, it is in the other features of Facebook (such as advertising and social networking) where consumers data 7 Commission Consolidated Jurisdictional Notice under Council Regulation (EC) No 139/2004 on the control of concentrations between undertakings, paragraph 24 8 Defined as markets where firms have to compete simultaneously for two groups of customers. For example, in auctions sites like ebay it would be sellers and customers and in transportation services like über it would be drivers and customers. 9 As indicated in the public version of the decision by the European Commission, this merger does not have a Union dimension within the meaning of article 1(2) and 1 (3) of the EU Merger Regulation (point 9) because the WhatsApp turnover was too low. 3

could strengthen the position of Facebook vis-à-vis competitors and other online service providers. Big data in itself cannot be an objective criterion for determining EU competence. However, data has a very crucial role in the digital economy. It is a very valuable asset. Even if services are presented as free to consumers, their data is being monetised for example by means of behavioural advertising. Therefore, it is important to find a way by which companies benefiting of these new resources could be captured by the EU control on mergers. 3. New criteria: value of the transaction and number of consumers affected by the merger BEUC suggests to add two new criteria to the jurisdiction rules on merger control based on the value of the transaction and the number of end-consumers which are directly impacted by the merger. 3.1. Value of the transaction Certain mergers consist in the transfer of high-value assets such as Intellectual Property Rights and client data bases. Under certain conditions, these mergers should be scrutinised under the EU rules even if they do not met the EU turnover thresholds. In Germany a proposal for a reform of the jurisdictional rules of the German merger control (Section 35 of the Act Against Restraints on Competition 10 ) follows this logic and introduces a threshold of 400 million EUR for the value of the operation combined with a an additional requirement based on the companies turnover in Germany 11. This is an innovative solution that would allow to scrutinise mergers involving companies with low annual turnovers which could raise competition concerns. This is an important element to take into account in corporate restructuration across sectors and is not exclusively relevant for digital markets. A similar concept could be introduced in EU Law in order to capture high-value transactions between companies that would not meet the requirements of the turnover thresholds but could nevertheless risk distorting competition in the Single Market. The transfer of value could be set up in the region of [1,000 million EUR 2,000 million] EUR of the transaction. This figure could be estimated by using as a variable the average European Union GDP. The use of the GDP as a base to approximate the value threshold of the EU could an adequate first approach as it uses the proportion of the Economic activity as base for its estimation. For example, the 400 million EUR value threshold for the German market could be used as a basis for calculating an adequate value threshold. Our suggestion employs the relation of the GDP of EU 28 and Germany for estimating an adequate value threshold for the EU. In simplified terms the logic of the calculation looks like: 10 Gesetz gegen Wettbewerbsbeschränkungen - GWB 11 The additional requirement is that the combined worldwide turnover of all companies is above 500 million EUR and in Germany at least one company has a turnover of 25 million Euros. 4

EU transfer value threshold = National transfer value threshold x EU 28 GDP National GDP To avoid bias due to yearly fluctuations in the GDP we employ the average relation of the GDP of the EU 28 and the GDP of Germany over the past five years. The average relation between the GDP of the EU 28 and Germany over the past five years (4.83) is multiplied with the proposed 400 million EUR value threshold of Germany (compare Figure 1). As a result, the proposed value threshold for the EU would be 1.9 billion EUR. Figure 1 Estimation value threshold for Merger Regulation of the European Union UNIT NA_ITEM Current prices, million euro Gross domestic product at market prices GEO/TIME 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 European Union (28 countries) 13.192.520,4 13.448.619,5 13.558.617,4 14.001.004,1 14.710.625,9 Average 2011-2015 Germany (until 1990 former territory of the FRG Relation GDP EU28/DE 2.703.120,0 2.758.260,0 2.826.240,0 2.923.930,0 3.032.820,0 4,880479 4,87576207 4,79740482 4,78841973 4,85047774 4,838508673 DE_Value Threshold (in million EUR as proposed by draft law in Germany Suggested EU28 Value Threshold (in million EUR) = 400m EUR + 4,838508673 400 1935,40 Source: Own calculation, Eurostat, main tables: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/national-accounts/data/main-tables 3.2. Number of consumers affected In two-sided markets the value of transfer criterion might not be the only and most suitable approach to cover transactions with a Union dimension. This is because in two-sided markets the margins are often very low except for big companies in a dominant position. Hence the transaction value even if reflecting the market power could be below the EU threshold. Additionally, in a two-sided market, the purchasing company might decide on an acquisition because of the other company s position in one side of the market, e.g. the consumer side, and this might not necessarily be reflected in the value of the transaction. Consequently, BEUC suggests to introduce a criterion applicable to mergers in two-sided markets based on the number of EU consumers directly impacted by the operation. 5

This criterion would kick-in when the previous conditions, namely the value of the transaction and the companies EU turnover threshold, are not met. However, the merger would nevertheless need to be approved by the European Commission due to the number of EU consumers affected. These directly impacted customers would be those that have a direct or indirect contract with one of the companies at a certain date. This contract could be of different nature including subscriptions to services and tacit agreements based on the use of the service e.g. search engines. In the case of a two-sided market with several layers such as in the payment sector, the platform has no direct contract with the consumers but an indirect contract through the bank for the use of the platform. This criterion could follow the same logic as article 1(3) of the EU Merger Regulation and includes two figures: one for the combined merger and one for each company. In this sense, the figures for the combined merger could be established according to the EU population e.g. between 5 and 10%. The figure for each country could be one quarter of the previous, as in the article 1(3). This criterion is objective and not related to the market share which is based on more subjective criteria because there is a need for an agreement on the definition of the market. It is also necessary to draw a distinction between consumers directly impacted (e.g. in Facebook / WhatsApp) and mergers where the impact is indirect because they occur in upstream markets. In the latter case (for example when a food producer purchases one of its providers) there is no link between the consumer and the producer even if at the end of the process the consumer will purchase the product. Thus, this criterion might not be always applicable. Finally, if the European Commission decided to introduce new jurisdictional thresholds, we suggest to include a mid-term evaluation of the number of mergers that have been thrusted under each jurisdictional threshold and which have not been scrutinised to better assess the effectiveness of the new systems. BEUC s recommendation The EU Merger Regulation should include in its rules on jurisdiction two additional criteria based on the value of transfer and, in case of two-sided markets, on the number of consumers affected by the operation. This would allow DG Competition to consider mergers between companies that do not reach the turnover thresholds but nevertheless have the potential to disrupt competition due to the number of consumers that will be aggregated by the purchasing company. 6

This publication is part of an activity which has received funding under an operating grant from the European Union s Consumer Programme (2014-2020). The content of this publication represents the views of the author only and it is his/her sole responsibility; it cannot be considered to reflect the views of the European Commission and/or the Consumers, Health, Agriculture and Food Executive Agency or any other body of the European Union. The European Commission and the Agency do not accept any responsibility for use that may be made of the information it contains. 7