as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

Similar documents
Estimation of a DSGE Model Lawrence J. Christiano

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

Discussion of: Structural Models of Inflation Dynamics. By Lawrence J. Christiano

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2011

Over the past decade or so,

METHODS EXAMINATION - MAY MACROECONOMICS Meyer (chair), Conlin, Doblas Madrid, Wilson, Wooldridge

New Keynesian DSGE model

THE RESPONSE OF FINANCIAL AND GOODS MARKETS TO VELOCITY INNOVATIONS: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION FOR THE US*

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

Discussion of The Inflation Persistence Project. Robert G. King Boston University, NBER, and Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond

Chapter 3. Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics. Measuring Business Cycles. Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS PROGRAMME SPECIFIC OUTCOME

habit persistence Habit persistence and the equity premium puzzle

RBC Models of Small Open Economies

Temperature impacts on economic growth warrant stringent mitigation policy

Estimation, Solution and Analysis of Equilibrium Monetary Models Assignment 6: Tutorial on Analysis of an Equilibrium Monetary Model

Remarks on Central banker s modeling toolbox: one-for-all or all-for-one

Sustainability Economics of Groundwater Usage and Management

Central European University Department of Economics. 2. Lecturer Attila Ratfai (Part 2 of the course is taught by Alessia Campolmi)

THE IMPLICATIONS OF HYPERBOLIC DISCOUNTING FOR PROJECT EVALUATION. Maureen Cropper and David Laibson

Managerial Economics, 01/12/2003. A Glossary of Terms

Macroeconomic Experiments (my take) Charles Noussair Tilburg University June 15, 2012

DIFFERENTIATED PRODUCTS SOLUTIONS TO EQUILIBRIUM MODELS

Luca Spataro Lectures 2. Public Economics. Efficiency (Ref. Myles 1995, ch. 2) March 2015, University of Pisa

A Primer on IRBC Theory

Test Codes: QEA and QEB (Both are of 'Descriptive' type) (Junior Research Fellowship in Quantitative Economics)

Markup Pricing and Monetary Policy: A Reexamination of the Effectiveness of Monetary Policy under Imperfect Competition

Concepts of Equilibrium and Their Role in Economic Simulation Models

Trend inflation, inflation targets and inflation expectations

Fluctuations. Organization of the course, and facts

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

FIFTH EDITION B BARRON'S. Walter J.Wessels. BUSINESS REVIEW BOOKS Economics

Intermediate Macroeconomic Theory, 01/07/2003. A Glossary of Macroeconomics Terms

Fluctuations. Organization of the course, and facts

16. Wrap Up John B. Taylor, May 22, 2013

MRW model of growth: foundation, developments, and empirical evidence

Lecture 1 : The Diamond- Mortensen- Pissarides framework

30/10/2013. The Belgian TIMES model

SHORT QUESTIONS AND ANSWERS FOR ECO402

Keywords: macroeconomics, economic growth, human capital, economic policy

Economic Dynamics in Discrete Time. Jianjun Mia o/ The MIT Press Cambridge, Massachusetts London, England

M.Sc. Agril. Economics

Intermediate Macroeconomics

The Cobb-Douglas Production Function and Political Economy

Vector Space Modeling for Aggregate and Industry Sectors in Kuwait

Fragmentation and The Product Cycle

Economics Department 2009 Honors General Exam

Environmental Policy and the Business Cycle: The Role of Adjustment Costs on Abatement

Eco402 - Microeconomics Glossary By

TEACHING MICRO AND MACRO AS SEPARATE COURSES

Leigh Tesfatsion (Prof. of Econ, Iowa State University, Ames, IA ) Last Updated: 1 January 2018

Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices

NEW KEYNESIAN THEORY: MONOPOLY PRICING MARCH 29, 2010 RELEVANT MARKET STRUCTURE(S)? Introduction

The Delayed Effects of Monetary Shocks in a Two-sector New. Keynesian Model

Reconstructing Macroeconomics: A Perspective from Statistical Physics and Combinatorial Stochastic Processes

Comment on A Macroeconomic Framework for Quantifying Systemic Risk by He and Krishnamurthy

Frictions, persistence, and central bank policy in an experimental dynamic stochastic general equilibrium economy

GACE Economics Assessment Test at a Glance

Price setting problem: Rigidities

No 10. Chapter 11. Introduction. Real Wage Rigidity: A Question. Keynesianism: Wage and Price Rigidity

Fundamentals of Economics. 3 June Marking Scheme

INTRODUCTION TO WALRASIAN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODELING. Structural and Behavioral Underpinnings of the Walrasian General Equilibrium Model

College: Department: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID: Full Course Description: Course ID:

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Introduction to computable general equilibrium (CGE) Modelling

Labor demand in a macro-econometric model: Neo-classical vs. Keynesian specifications

Asset Price Bubbles and Endogenous Growth [PRELIMINARY DRAFT] Abstract

Economics. E.1.4 Describe how people respond predictably to positive and negative incentives.

ECO-401 Economics Online Quiz 5

19 Unemployment in Europe

Inventory Behavior and the Cost Channel of Monetary Transmission

Microeconomics. Use the Following Graph to Answer Question 3

Time varying effects of oil price shocks on euro area exports

October 25, Your Name: Midterm Exam Autumn Econ 580 Labor Economics and Industrial Relations

) ln (GDP t /Hours t ) ln (GDP deflator t ) capacity utilization t ln (Hours t

ECON 269A. Winter Time and Location: Tu-Th PM Course Webpage:

The Asymmetric Effects of Monetary Policy in General Equilibrium

Hyperbolic Discounting and Consumer Patience During Financial Crises in Korea *

PRINCIPLES OF ECONOMICS IN CONTEXT CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION TO WALRASIAN GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM MODELING. Basic assumptions underpinning the Walrasian General Equilibrium (WGE) Model

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D. EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. University of Minnesota. June 16, 2014 MANAGERIAL, FINANCIAL, MARKETING

Wage bargaining under an employment target

Chapter 9: The IS-LM/AD-AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis

The Excess Smoothness Puzzle, Habit Formation, and Forward-Looking Behavior in Aggregate Consumption

Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) Models: A Short Course. Hodjat Ghadimi Regional Research Institute

Beyond balanced growth: The effect of human capital on economic growth reconsidered

Chapter 9. The IS LM/AD AS Model: A General Framework for Macroeconomic Analysis. Copyright 2009 Pearson Education Canada

Lecture 10: THE AD-AS MODEL Reference: Chapter 8

Economics. Synopsis. 1. Economic Concepts, Issues and Tools. 2. An Overview of Economics. Sections. Learning Summary. Sections

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture

September 2006 REAL RIGIDITIES * David Romer University of California, Berkeley

DISSERTATION ABSTRACT. Essays on Economic Growth and Development: New Perspectives from Health, Education, and Wealth. Kei Hosoya

UNIVERSITY OF MALTA THE MATRICULATION EXAMINATION ADVANCED LEVEL

ECO401 Latest Solved MCQs.

Fundamentals of Economics. 2 September Exam Paper. Time: 2.5 hours

MULTIPLIERS: IMPERFECT COMPETITION OR INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE?

Chapter 1. The Intertemporal General Equilibrium Model (IGEM) 1.1 Introduction Intertemporal general equilibrium models represent worthwhile

New Forecasting Model of the CNB

On Macroeconomic Theories and Modeist

Transcription:

THE HOUSEHOLD SECTOR IN THE SMETS-WOUTERS DSGE MODEL: COMPARISONS WITH THE STANDARD OPTIMAL GROWTH MODEL L. Tesfatsion, Econ 502, Fall 2014 Last Revised: 19 November 2014 Basic References: [1] ** L. Tesfatsion, A Simple Illustrative Optimal Growth Model www.econ.iastate.edu/classes/econ502/tesfatsion/optgrow.pdf [2] * Frank Smets and Raf Wouters, An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium Model of the Euro Area, National Bank of Belgium Working Paper, 2003, 71pp. On-Line www.econ.iastate.edu/classes/econ502/tesfatsion/smetswoutersnotes.lt.pdf Note: The Smets-Wouters DSGE model has been used by the European Central Bank over the past several years to analyze macroeconomic policy for the Euro area, i.e., the particular set of European countries that have commonly adopted the Euro as their currency. QUESTION 1: Compare and contrast the DSGE modeling of the household sector in Section 2.1 of Smets-Wouters [2] with the standard optimal growth modeling of the household (consumer) sector described in [1]. NOTES FOR Q1: The closest comparison is obtained if in [1] one adopts the single representative household (consumer) interpretation for the optimizing agent in the optimal growth model rather than thinking of this optimizing agent as a social planner. This interpretation will be assumed throughout the remaining parts of these notes without further comment. The household sector in [1] is developed in continuous time for a continuum of time points t, whereas the household sector in [2] is developed in discrete time for a countable sequence of time periods t = [t, t + 1). In [1], households are assumed to supply labor inelastically in each time period t, so there is no labor/leisure choice ; the only argument of the household utility function at each time point t is amounts of a single produced consumption good (or a scalar index for real consumption). In contrast, in [2] the household utility function has two arguments in each time period t: (i) (produced) goods; and (ii) leisure. Moreover, labor is differentiated over households so that there is some monopoly power over wages. Model [1] assumes the existence of a single representative optimizing household. In contrast, model [2] permits the existence of a limited degree of heterogeneity across households. More precisely, in model [2] there is a continuum of representative optimizing households, one representative optimizing household for each type of labor supplied. That is, 1

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many households. Households with distinct indices are assumed to supply a distinct type of labor. In particular, note that households are structurally identical apart from the fact that they supply distinct types of labor with differing disutilities. In particular, the household instantaneous (period t) utility functions (2) are structurally identical except that different households supply different types of labor with different coefficients σ ι representing the inverse of their elasticity of work effort with respect to the real wage. In both models the households own the capital stock, a homogeneous factor of production. In model [1] there are no explicitly modeled external firms. Rather, the one representative household is also the one representative firm. (This is why model [1] is often referred to as a Robinson Crusoe model of an economy think of a single agent shipwrecked on an island who produces breadfruit and who is also the sole consumer of this produced breadfruit.) In contrast, as explained on pages 8-9, model [2] has an explicitly modeled continuum of intermediate-good firms/producers to whom the households supply both capital and labor services. The intermediate goods produced by the intermediate-good firms are then used to produce a final good that is used for both consumption and investment by the households. In both models [1] and [2] the households decide how much of their current income to allocate towards investment (production of new capital). In model [1] the remainder is entirely consumed (capital investment is the only form of saving); there are no financial assets in model [1]. However, in model [2] the households can also save part of their income in the form of bond holdings. Note, however, that model [2] does not include outside (government-issued) money; see [2, footnote 7]. In model [1] there is no modeled source of uncertainty. Hence the representative household in model [1] at the initial time point 0 maximizes its lifetime utility with respect to a choice of consumption and investment paths over its lifetime [0, T ] subject to macro technological feasibility constraints (see below), where T can be either finite or infinite. Remark: The household s objective function in model [1] is a standard discounted utility (DU) model (as defined in Course Packet 21). Hence, even if the household were to be allowed to re-optimize at a later time, it would not choose to do so. In model [2], each household maximizes its expected lifetime utility (1) with respect to choices of paths for consumption, investment, and bond holdings over its infinite lifetime [0, ] subject to an intertemporal budget constraint (4) and a capital accumulation equation (14), where the discount rate β is common across households. Household utility is perturbed by two exogenous shocks, commonly experienced across households, as follows: A shock to the discount rate β; and a shock to the labor supply. Remark: In model [2], each household s lifetime utility function is a discrete-time version of the standard DU model used in model [1], extended to include habit persistence (see below). 2

In model [1] there is no habit persistence, i.e., the utility of consumption attained by a household at any time point t is a function only of the household s consumption at t. It does not depend on the amount of consumption that the household consumed in the past or will consume in the future. In contrast, habit persistence is introduced in model [2] in an attempt to obtain a better fit with empirical data. In particular, as seen in relations (2) and (3), a household s utility of consumption in time period t is assumed to depend on a habit variable H t that is a constant h times consumption in the previous period t 1. In model [1], household income at time t is identified with national income Y t, which is then divided between consumption C t and gross investment I t. In short, the household s budget constraint is the national income accounting identity for a closed economy: Y = C + I. In contrast, in model [2] each household s income (5) is determined from three sources: roughly, labor income; income from sale of capital services (i.e., from renting out capital this is misstated on page 5); and dividends received from firms. A separate budget constraint (4) is imposed on each separate household because the income (5) for each household is determined in part by the supply of a distinct type of labor at a distinct wage level. However, a trick is used on page 5 that effectively eliminates heterogeneity in the budget constraints across households: namely, it is assumed that households can insure against variations in their household-specific labor income by purchasing state-contingent securities. Also, in model [2, p. 6] it would appear that the household constraints involve an equilibrium condition; namely, that each household set their wages and labor supply so that their labor supply equals demand (9) for their type of labor, where the latter depends on aggregator functions for total labor demand and the the aggregate nominal wage. Technical Remark for Q1: Game-theoretic issues are avoided here by the assumption that households form a continuum. The latter assumption means that the integrals in (10) and (11) are not affected by the point decisions of any one household, conditional on given decisions for all other households, because what happens at a single household point is a measure zero event from the vantage point of the integrals as a whole. QUESTION 2: Discuss the motivation and justification provided in Smets-Wouters [2] for the modeling of the household sector in Section 2.1. In particular, to what extent does this modeling appear to be based on theoretical considerations? on empirical considerations? NOTES FOR Q2: Based on Section 1 and Section 2.1 in [2], it would appear that the Smets-Wouters modeling of the household sector is motivated by two primary concerns: 1. Theoretical Considerations: Stick as closely as possible to the assumptions employed in previous DSGE modelings, in particular in the DSGE modeling by Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (CEE,2001). 3

2. Empirical Considerations: Modify these modeling assumptions only to the extent that the modifications appear to enable a better goodness-of-fit between the resulting DSGE model outputs and macroeconomic data for the main euro area of Europe over a given data sample period: namely, 1980:2-1999:4 (p. 16). Regarding 2., Smets-Wouters note (p. 2) that they measure goodness-of-fit for their estimated DSGE model by its ability to capture the empirical stochastics and dynamics in the data. As they further clarify on page 15, this involves an ability to match not only the contemporaneous correlations in the observed data series, but also the serial correlation and cross-covariances. There is no explicit attempt by Smets-Wouters in [2, Section 2.1] to motivate their modeling choices in terms of input empirical validation, i.e., in terms of trying to capture structural characteristics of the true data generating mechanism underlying the macroeconomic data for the euro area used for goodness-of-fit checks. However, Smets-Wouters would presumably argue that input empirical validation is implicitly used in their selection of key representative agents for their model (households, intermediate-good firms, a final-good firm, and a government implementing a Taylor-like monetary policy rule in an attempt to control bond gross interest rates {R t }). The authors mention the possibility of using predictive performance for empirical model validation in footnote 22 (p. 16). However, the authors also caution that such a validation method can be very computationally intensive. Nevertheless, in Section 3.3.1 the authors attempt to calculate the marginal likelihood for their estimated DSGE model, roughly defined as the overall likelihood of their model given their data sample. The authors claim (p. 21) that the marginal likelihood of a model also reflects its predictive performance. However, what they mean by this turns out to be predictions of observables over the same data sample period that they originally used to estimate their model; the authors do not actually use their model for prediction out of sample (i.e., using completely new data). Possibly this is due to the shortness of the data series for the euro area, which was slowly implemented in stages following a treaty in 1992. Specifically, the authors show (Table 2, p. 34) that the marginal likelihood of (their) estimated DSGE model is very close to that of the best VAR (vector auto-regressive) model when used to predict the seven observable variables of their model over their data sample period 1980:2-1999:4. Apparently (footnote 36) it has been very difficult in the past for estimated DSGE models to match the performance of VAR models over data sample periods. QUESTION 3: Advocates of DSGE models claim it is possible to use DSGE models to evaluate the performance of macroeconomic policies on the basis of Pareto optimality and other social welfare criterion derived from household preferences, an improvement over simple aggregate welfare measures such as the real GDP gap. Carefully explain how monetary policy is represented and evaluated in the Smets-Wouters DSGE model [2]. In particular, is 4

monetary policy evaluated on the basis of Pareto optimality or other social welfare criterion derived from household preferences? NOTES FOR Q3: Form of Monetary Policy in [2]: Smets-Wouters assume [2, pp. 13-14] that government uses a monetary policy rule ( reaction function ) taking the particular form (36). As the authors note, (36) is a generalized Taylor rule that dictates that bond gross interest rates { ˆR t } for their DSGE model linearized around the non-stochastic steady state should be set in response to two types of gaps: (i) deviations of lagged inflation from an inflation objective (normalized to zero); and (ii) the lagged output gap, where the output gap corresponds to what we have been referring to in class as the real GDP gap. Evaluation of Monetary Policy in [2]: Interestingly, despite the efforts by Smets-Wouters [2] to explicitly include within their DSGE model the preferences of households in the form of lifetime utility functions, and then to estimate the resulting DSGE model, they do not evaluate their monetary policy rule on the basis of Pareto optimality or other social welfare criteria derived from estimated household preferences. See, in particular, [2, footnote 2, p. 2]. Instead, Smets-Wouters [2, p. 14] justify the form of their monetary policy rule by appeal to empirical studies by other authors in which a Taylor rule specification was claimed to be able to capture the behavior of average interest rates in the euro area and the behavior of central banks for Germany, France, and Italy prior to the formation of the European Central Bank in 1998. In Section 5 (p. 27), the authors note that in Michael Woodford s canonical New Keynesian DSGE model developed in 1999 the output gap or the real interest rate gap, both defined as deviations from their flexible price levels, are useful indicators for optimal monetary policy. However, the authors then go on to say how some of the modifications they introduced into their DSGE model (e.g., nominal rigidities in both prices and wages, and shocks arising from sources other than technology and preferences) invalidate this conclusion for their model. The authors conclude (p. 32): In this paper we have not analysed optimal monetary policy. A deeper analysis of the appropriate welfare function and the various trade-offs faced by the monetary authorities in the context of this model would be very welcome. 5