Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices

Similar documents
Switching Costs and Market Competitiveness: De-constructing the Relationship

The Relationship between Pricing and Consumers Switching Costs: Comparisons between the Myopic and Perfect-foresight Equilibria

Understanding UPP. Alternative to Market Definition, B.E. Journal of Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

HANDBOOK OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION

The value of switching costs

Identification of the oligopoly solution concept in a differentiated-products industry

Universitat Autònoma de Barcelona Department of Applied Economics

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

WRITTEN PRELIMINARY Ph.D EXAMINATION. Department of Applied Economics. Trade, Development and Growth. June For students electing

Quasi linear Utility and Two Market Monopoly

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

MEMO. 1 Single-Product Monopolist. 1.1 Inverse Elasticity Rule. Date: October Subject: Notes from Tirole on Monopoly Ch.1: pp

Dynamic Price Competition with Network Effects

Information externalities in a model of sales. Abstract

Buyer Heterogeneity and Dynamic Sorting in Markets for Durable Lemons

A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing

Empirical Studies of Pricing: Homogenous Goods

Inequality and the Organization of Knowledge

Simple Market Equilibria with Rationally Inattentive Consumers

Is Dynamic Competition Socially Beneficial? The Case of Price as Investment

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 5

1.. There are two firms that produce a homogeneous product. Let p i

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

Sponsored Search Markets

Equilibria in an infinite horizon game with an incumbent, entry and switching costs

Entry on market with switching costs and network effects. How long does it take to catchup with incumbents when consumers are heterogeneous?

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

New goods, old theory, and the welfare costs of trade restrictions. Paul Romer

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

DYNAMIC PRICE COMPETITION WITH NETWORK EFFECTS

Industrial Organization Entry Costs, Market Structure and Welfare

Econ 8601 Fall 2018 Take-Home Final. You can choose when to work on it, but please work only one

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Do Switching Costs Make Markets Less Competitive?

Volume Title: The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited. Volume Author/Editor: Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, editors

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Price competition in a differentiated products duopoly under network effects

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

Third Degree. Distinguish from First-Degree or Perfect Price Discrimation

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

The effects of loyalty programs on markets

Ryan Oprea. Economics 176

Countervailing Power and Product Diversity

CS269I: Incentives in Computer Science Lecture #16: Revenue-Maximizing Auctions

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

!"#$#%&"'()#*(+,'&$-''(.#/-'((

Online Ad Auctions. By Hal R. Varian. Draft: December 25, I describe how search engines sell ad space using an auction.

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2011

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

Multiple Equilibria and Selection by Learning in an Applied Setting

Trade Liberalization and Firm Dynamics. Ariel Burstein and Marc Melitz

APPENDIX THEORY MODEL DETAILS

Revisiting the Relationship Between Competition, Patenting, and Innovation

ECONOMICS 600 YALE UNIVERSITY Prof. Phil Haile 37 Hillhouse, Rm 26

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Alexander Tarasov: Consumer Preferences in Monopolistic Competition Models

Review of the September 2000 Draft of Fair Market Value Analysis for a Fiber Optic Cable Permit in National Marine Sanctuaries

Re-visiting the Porter Hypothesis

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition

Employer Discrimination and Market Structure

ECO 2301 Spring EXAM 2 Form 2 Friday, April 4 th Solutions

Duopoly Competition Considering Waiting Cost

Inventory Systems with Transshipments and Quantity Discounts. A dissertation submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

Quiz #4 Week 04/05/2009 to 04/11/2009

Endogenous Sequential Entry in a Spatial Model Revisited. Georg Götz

Topic 1: Demand and Supply

History-based price discrimination in markets with switching costs: who gains and who loses?

Economics 448W, Notes on the Classical Supply Side Professor Steven Fazzari

GDP EFFECTS OF AN ENERGY PRICE SHOCK

Theory Appendix. 1 Model Setup

Mobility Costs and Localization of Labor Markets

1.. There are two complementary goods that are consumed together (each individual good

A Note on Expanding Networks and Monopoly Pricing

Module 11: A Simple Model of Reputation - Moral Hazard and Product Quality

Vertical Differentiation in Monetary Search-Theoretic Model: Revisited. Chia-Ying Chang Victoria University of Wellington, New Zealand.

MULTIPLIERS: IMPERFECT COMPETITION OR INCREASING RETURNS TO SCALE?

Modeling of competition in revenue management Petr Fiala 1

2009/55. Clean Technology Adoption and Its Influence on Tradeable Emission Permit Prices. Maria Eugenia SANIN Skerdilajda ZANAJ

The Implications of Alternative Biofuel Policies on Carbon Leakage

Contents. Consumer Choice: Individual and Market Demand- Demand and Elasticity. I) Markets and Prices. II) Demand Side. III) The Supply Side

VCG in Theory and Practice

Online shopping and platform design with ex ante registration requirements. Online Appendix

Vertical Integration and Distance to Frontier

Ec 11 Caltech Lecture 1 Notes (revised: version 2.0)

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Market Structure, Innovation, and Allocative Efficiency

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

A Walrasian Theory of Commodity Money: Paradoxical Results *

Loyalty Inducing Programs and Competition with Homogeneous

Lesson-8. Equilibrium of Supply and Demand

Lecture 7 - Auctions and Mechanism Design

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

Excludable Public Goods

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM August 2017

Transcription:

Small Switching Costs Lead to Lower Prices Luís Cabral New York University and CEPR October 2008 Abstract I argue that the numerical result obtained by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) is fairly general: in a dynamic model of price competition with switching costs, average price in a symmetric equilibrium decreases in the value of the switching cost for low values of the switching cost. Stern School of Business, 44 West Forth Street, New York, NY 10012; lcabral@ stern.nyu.edu.

1 Introduction Consumers frequently must pay a cost in order to switch from their current supplier to a different supplier (Klemperer, 1995; Farrell and Klemperer, 2007). These costs motivate some interesting questions: are markets more or less competitive in the presence of switching costs? Specifically, are prices higher or lower under switching costs? As Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) state echoing Farrell and Klemperer (2007), among others, we may divide the effects of switching costs into two categories: harvesting and investment. The former corresponds to the idea that switching costs increase a firm s static market power, which in turn leads the firm to increase prices. The latter corresponds to the dynamic incentives a firm has to increase its market share, which lead the firm to decrease prices. Which of the two effects dominates? Conventional wisdom and the received economics literature suggest that the harvesting effect dominates (Farrell and Klemperer, 2007). Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) cast doubt on this assertion, claiming that small levels of switching costs may actual decrease equilibrium prices. 1 In this note, I expand the theoretical argument underlying Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi s (2008) result. In doing so, I hope to clarify the intuition for the result and suggest the extent to which it generalizes. In a nutshell, while recognizing that the harvesting effect is generally positive (higher prices) and the investment effect generally negative (lower prices), I also argue that, for small values of the switching cost, the harvesting effect is of second order of magnitude, whereas the investment effect is of first order of magnitude. This note, which summarizes some of the results in Cabral (2008), is structured as follows. In Section 2, I lay down a fairly general framework of dynamic competition and characterize the harvesting and the investment incentives present in dynamic pricing. Then in Section 3 I argue that, if switching costs are small, then their effect on harvesting is of lower order of magnitude than their effect on investment. Finally, Section 4 presents some concluding remarks. 1. See also Doganoglu (2005) and Viard (2003). 2

2 Harvesting and investing Consider the dynamic optimization problem faced by a generic firm i. Its value is given by V i (x, p; s) = (p i c i ) q i (x, p; s) + δ Ṽi(x, p; s) where x denotes a vector of state variables (e.g., market shares), p a vector of current prices, and s the level of switching costs. 2 The variables indexed with an i are firm i specific variables: p i is price, c i unit cost, and q i quantity sold; V i is value and Ṽi continuation value. Finally, δ is the discount factor. Maximization with respect to p i implies q i (x, p; s) + (p i c i ) q i(x, p; s) + δ Ṽi(x, p; s) = 0 (1) At first, this seems like a complicated expression. I will try to show that it is actually quite simple. Define q i q i Ṽ i Ṽi q i (Notice the first derivative is taken with respect to p i, whereas the second is taken with respect to q i.) Suppose that firm i s future value only depends on current choices through firm i s output level. This is true in many models with switching costs, learning curves, etc. Then we have Ṽi(x, p; s) = Ṽi(x, p; s) q i q i = p Ṽ i i I can now re-write the first-order condition (1) in simpler notation (also omitting the functional arguments for simplicity): ( ) qi p i c i = δ Ṽ i (2) q i 2. Although I will be thinking about the problem of switching costs, much of what I develop in this section could be applied to other exogenous parameters, such as the degree of product differentiation or the steepness of learning curves. 3 q i

The right-hand side of (2) depicts the two main incentives present in dynamic strategic pricing: the harvesting incentive and the investment incentive. 3 The harvesting incentive refers to the increase in price-cost margin that follows from a firm s market power. In (2), this increase in market power comes from a greater market share (greater q i ) and a more inelastic demand curve (lower q i ). Consider now the second term. To the extent that greater sales today increase a firm s future value, that is, Ṽ i > 0, a firm will tend to lower its price cost margin. By doing so, the firm invests in market share: it lowers its current profit margin in exchange for a greater market share in the future. We thus have the investment incentive. In the next section, I specialize this framework by making some additional assumptions and by examining the specific case of small switching costs. 3 Small switching costs How do switching costs influence pricing? Since switching costs do no alter a firm s costs, from (2) we see that the question amounts to evaluating the effect of switching costs on harvesting and on investment pricing incentives. Specifically, d p i d s = d d s ( qi q i ) δ d d s ) (Ṽ i Let us then go by parts. First, let us examine the effect of switching costs on harvesting. Such harvesting effect is given by d d s ( qi ) Intuitively, we would expect higher switching costs to lead to lower q i and thus to higher p i : switching costs lead to more inelastic demand, and all else being equal this leads to higher prices. What about the effect of switching costs on q i? Suppose that, going into period t, firm 1 has a larger market share than firm 2. Then we would expect an increase in switching costs to 3. I will denote by harvesting (resp. investment) incentive the extent to which current profitability (resp. future profitability) influences optimal prices. I will denote by harvesting (resp. investment) effect the influence of switching costs on price through harvesting (resp. investment) incentives. q i 4

increase firm 1 s market share in period t and decrease firm 2 s market share in period t. In fact, some of the customers that firm 2 expected to attract in period t will now prefer to purchase from firm 1 because of higher switching costs. In other words, the effect of switching costs on q i is likely to be positive for some firms and negative for others. Consider now the effect of switching costs on Ṽ i : the investment effect. Suppose that the only intertemporal links are due to switching costs. In the limit when switching costs are zero, we have Ṽ i = 0: the firm s continuation value is independent of its current sales. The greater the value of switching costs, the more sensitive future value is to current sales. It follows that Ṽ i increases as switching costs increase. Notice that, unlike the harvesting effect of switching costs, the investment effect is positive for all firms: for large firms, Ṽ i increases because there is more to be lost from decreasing market share; for small firms, Ṽ i increases because there is more to be gained by increasing market share. In summary, the harvesting effect of higher switching costs is positive for some firms and negative for others, whereas the investment effect is negative for all firms. In Cabral (2008), I show that, under some additional assumptions, the overall effect is negative: higher switchings costs lead to lower average equilibrium prices. Specifically, I show that the average harvesting effect (average across all firms) is approximately equal to zero, whereas the investment effect is negative for all firms (and so is the average investment effect). In other words, the result obtained numerically by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) is valid more generally. Like Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008), I consider the case when sellers compete for one single buyer. In one respect, I make an additional simplifying assumption: I consider the case when there are only two sellers and there is no outside option, that is, the buyer always makes a purchase from one of the sellers. Other than this, my analysis is more general than Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008). In particular, I make very mild assumptions regarding the nature of product differentiation. My assumptions include as a particular case the extreme value distribution, the case considered by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008); but also many other standard distributions (normal, log-normal, uniform, t, etc). 5

4 Concluding remarks Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) have shown numerically that a small level of switching costs increases the level of market competition. One limitation of numerical simulations such as theirs is that they depend on particular choices of functional forms and parameter values. By contrast, one advantage of analytical results like the ones I present in Cabral (2008) is that very mild assumptions are made regarding functional forms. An additional advantage of the analytical approach is that the intuition for the results becomes more apparent. Having established the generality of the results in Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008), I conclude by noting two important assumptions on which they rely. First, as stressed by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) and as the title of my note suggests, the results depend on the value of switching cost being small. In fact, in Cabral (2008) I show that for higher values of the switching cost equilibrium prices are increasing in the value of switching cost and eventually become higher than they would be if there were no switching costs. 4 The case of large switching costs is perhaps closer to the conventional wisdom regarding the anti-competitive effects of switching costs. Beggs and Klemperer (1992), the standard reference in dynamic competition with switching costs, assume infinite switching costs and show that equilibrium prices are higher than if there were no switching costs. 5 Second, the competitive effect of switching costs depends on symmetry across firms. In the argument presented in Cabral (2008) and summarized above, I show that the harvesting effect of small switching costs is small; in particular, it is of second order of magnitude. The idea is that a small switching costs leads the incumbent firm (the firm to whom the consumer is attached) to increase price, and the challenger firm (the firm with no consumer attached) to lower price. In absolute value, these price variations are of the same size. Therefore, if each firm is expected to make a sale with approximately the same probability, it follows that average price remains about constant. But if the incumbent firm has a much higher probability of sale (because, say, its product is better) than the harvesting price changes no longer average to zero. To sum up, the effect of switching costs on market competitiveness is 4. This pattern was also shown by Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008), though again for the particular case of preference shocks that follow an extreme value distribution. 5. See Cabral (2000, p. 218) for an elementary treatment. 6

largely an empirical question. For this reason, papers like Dubé, Hitsch and Rossi (2008) represent important contributions to our understanding of this phenomenon. 7

References Beggs, Alan W, and Paul Klemperer (1992), Multi-period Competition with Switching Costs, Econometrica 60, 651 666. Cabral, Luís (2000), Introduction to Industrial Organization, Cambridge, Mass: MIT Press. Cabral, Luís (2008), Switching Costs and Price Competition, New York University. Doganoglu, Toker (2005), Switching Costs, Experience Goods and Dynamic Price Competition, University of Munich. Dubé, Jean-Piere, Günter J Hitsch, and Peter E Rossi (2007), Do Switching Costs Make Markets Less Competitive?, forthcoming in Journal of Marketing Research. Farrell, Joseph, and Paul Klemperer (2007), Coordination and Lock- In: Competition with Switching costs and Network Effects, in M. Armstrong and R. Porter (Eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, Vol. 3, Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing. Viard, Brian (2003), Do Switching Costs Make Markets More or Less Competitive? The Case of 800-number Portability, Stanford University. 8