UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

Similar documents
UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly Behavior Advanced Pricing with Market Power

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module II

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Leftovers, review and takeaways Lectures Oct.

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Price discrimination by a monopolist

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

ECN 3103 INDUSTRIAL ORGANISATION

Part IV. Pricing strategies and market segmentation

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Principles of Economics. January 2018

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. ) of firms Product differentiation may or may not exist ) to entry. Chapter 12 2

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Game theory. (PR

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

Producer Theory - Monopoly

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

Unit 13 AP Economics - Practice

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

7 The Optimum of Monopoly, Price Discrimination

Prof. Wolfram Elsner Faculty of Business Studies and Economics iino Institute of Institutional and Innovation Economics. Real-World Markets

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

EXAMINATION #4 VERSION C General Equilibrium and Market Power November 24, 2015

University of Victoria Winter Econ 203 Problem Set 3

SECOND-DEGREE PRICE DISCRIMINATION (P-R pp )

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall Module III

Preface. Chapter 1 Basic Tools Used in Understanding Microeconomics. 1.1 Economic Models

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

Managerial Economics Chapter 9 Practice Question

Microeconomics (Fall term) Syllabus

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly and Market Power. Session V Sep 18, 2010

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Lecture 2 OLIGOPOLY Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Finance 510 Midterm #2 Practice Questions

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 22: Game Theory 4 Not Really Game Theory. The Story So Far. Today. Two Part Tariff.

Intermediate Microeconomics IMPERFECT COMPETITION BEN VAN KAMMEN, PHD PURDUE UNIVERSITY

Price Discrimination: Part 1

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 1

Chapter 10: Monopoly

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

Econ8500_Game_Theory. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

Chapter 12. Oligopoly. Oligopoly Characteristics. Oligopoly Equilibrium

Solutions to Final Exam

On the mode of Competition as a Collusive Perspective in Unionized Oligopoly

Economics 101A (Lecture 19) Stefano DellaVigna

MARKETS. Part Review. Reading Between the Lines SONY CORP. HAS CUT THE U.S. PRICE OF ITS PLAYSTATION 2

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 13 Sections 13.1, 13.2, 13.3 and 13.6 continued

Lesson-28. Perfect Competition. Economists in general recognize four major types of market structures (plus a larger number of subtypes):

Firm Supply. Market demand. Demand curve facing firm

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Microeconomics. Claudia Vogel EUV. Winter Term 2009/2010. Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

Topic 10: Price Discrimination

Economics 323 Microeconomic Theory Fall 2016

Lecture 7 Pricing with Market Power

PROBLEM SET 3. a) Find the pure strategy Nash Equilibrium of this game.

Brown University ECON 1130, Intermediate Microeconomics (Mathematical) Spring 2017 Class meets Tuesdays and Thursdays, 1:00-2:30 p.m.

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

ECONOMICS SOLUTION BOOK 2ND PUC. Unit 6. I. Choose the correct answer (each question carries 1 mark)

Lecture 12. Monopoly

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

MICROECONOMICS. DAVID A. SESANKO Northwestern University, Kellogg School of Management

The Economics of the European Union

Economics 101A (Lecture 19) Stefano DellaVigna

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

ECON 4550 (Summer 2014) Exam 3

1. For a monopolist, present the standard diagram showing the following:

Lecture 3 OLIGOPOLY (CONTINUED) 13-1 Copyright 2012 Pearson Education. All rights reserved.

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

Business Economics BUSINESS ECONOMICS. PAPER No. 1: MICROECONOMIC ANALYSIS MODULE No. 24: NON-COLLUSIVE OLIGOPOLY I

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

University of California, Davis

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Transcription:

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly and oligopoly (PR 11.1-11.4 and 12.2-12.5) Advanced pricing with market power and equilibrium oligopolistic markets Lectures 9-10 Sep. 17, 2011

In a competitive market there are many firms selling an identical product. When one of these firms raises its price above the market price it loses all its customers. In a monopolized market, there is only one firm selling a given product. When a monopolist raises its price it loses some, but not all, its customers.! In reality, most industries are somewhere in between these two extremes.

If a firm has some degree of monopoly power then it has more strategies than a firm in a perfectly competitive market. The problem faced by firms with some monopoly power is how to enhance and exploit their market power most effectively. Their objective capturing more consumer surplus and converting it into additional profits for the firm. This goal can be can be achieved using price discrimination, that is charging different prices for different consumers.

The deficiencies of simple pricing [1] If the firm can charge only one price for all it consumers, to maximize profit, it would pick the price and corresponding output where its marginal cost ( ) and marginal revenue ( ) curves intersect. [2] But although simple pricing or uniform pricing is quite prevalent, it is neither the only nor the most desirable form of pricing. If the firm could sell different units of output at different prices, then we have another story.

What simple pricing loses?! 1. It leaves potential profit in the hands of consumers in the form of their consumer surplus (the surplus under region of the demand curve). 2. It leaves money on the table (deadweight loss) due to the drivingdown-the-price effect (the surplus under region of the demand curve).

Two observations: 1. Under simple pricing, the firm cannot charge a price for the +1 unit that is different than the price it charges for the other units. And the fact that it would, have to lower the price on all units in order to induce someone to buy the +1unit, makes selling that unit unprofitable.

2. The firm would like to charge a higher price to consumers willing to pay more than.thefirm would also like to sell to consumers willing to pay prices lower than, but only if doing so does not entail lowering thepricefortheotherconsumers.! This is the basis for price discrimination charging different prices to different consumers.

Price A B MC MR D=AR Output

Price discrimination Economists typically consider three degrees of prices discrimination: 1 st The firm sells different units of output for different prices and these prices may differ from consumer to consumer. 2 nd The firm sells different units of output for different prices but every consumer who buys the same amount of the good pays the same price. 3 rd The firm sells output for different consumers at different prices, but every unit of output sold to a given consumer sells for the same price. Next, we look at each of these types of prices discrimination to see what economics can say about how prices discrimination works!

First-degree (or perfect) price discrimination = A firm that is able to perfectly price discriminate will sell each unit of output at the highest price it will command, that is, at each consumer s reservation price. = Since the firm can capture all the welfare generated from selling any number of units, it will want to produce to the point at which demand intersects marginal cost.

Price First degree price discrimination MC D=AR Output

Producing units and capturing all of welfare is the very best the firm could ever do (the Holy Grail of pricing). Perfect price discrimination is an idealized concept but it is interesting theoretical because it achieves Pareto efficiency. Clearly, firms typically cannot know the reservation price of every consumer, but sometimes reservation prices can be roughly identified. There are very few real-life examples. Perhaps to closest example would be tuition rates in Ivy League colleges, based on ability to pay.

Second-degree price discrimination Under second-degree price discrimination the price per unit of output is notconstantbutdependsonhowmuchyoubuy(non-linearpricing). One form of second-degree price discrimination is via quantity discounts liter bottle of Coke is less than twice as expensive as the half-liter bottle. Typically, each price-quantity package is targeted toward different consumers, giving consumers an incentive to self-select. In practice, firms often encourage this self-selection not by adjusting quantity of the good, but rather by adjusting the quality of the good.

The airline industry has been very successful in prices discrimination (the industry spokesperson prefer to use the term yield management ): [1] restricted and unrestricted fares [2] first-class and couch-class travel [3] Saturday night stayovers [4] advance-ticketing! In the 19 th century, the French railroads removed the roofs from secondclass carriages to create third-class carriages...

Price Second degree price discrimination (two different price quantity packages) MC MR D=AR Output

Third-degree price discrimination Third-degree price discrimination means charging different prices to different consumers on the basis of identifiable characteristics. An example of third-degree discrimination is charging different prices on the basis of observed group membership (children, seniors, students, etc). Geography-based third-degree price discrimination is quite prevalent in air travel, a round-trip SFO-JFK has a different price than JFK-SFO... Clearly, the market with the higher price must have a lower elasticity of demand.

An example Let 1 ( 1 ) be the demand of students and 2 ( 2 ) be the demand of non-students where 1 and 2 are the amount sold to students and non-students, respectively. Let ( ) for = 1 + 2 be the firm s cost function. The firm s profit is its revenue from each population less its costs is given by ( )= 1 ( 1 ) 1 + 2 ( 2 ) 2 ( )

The profit-maximizing quantity of output 1 (resp. 2 ) is such that the marginal (incremental) profit resulting from a small increase in 1 (resp. 2 ) equals zero, that is, and 1 = 1 1 1 2 = 2 2 2 1 =0 2 =0 Thus, at the profit-maximizing quantities 1 and 2 1 ( 1 )= 2( 2 )= ( 1 + 2 )

To determine relative prices, we can write the marginal revenues in terms of elasticity of demand: and 1 = 1 (1 + 1 1 ) 2 = 2 (1 + 1 2 ) By equating 1 and 2,wemusthave 1 2 = 1+1 2 1+1 1! This analysis generalizes to any (finite) number of populations.

Price Third degree price discrimination (two populations) Output

Price Third degree price discrimination Output

Price Third degree price discrimination Output

Two-part tariffs (The Disneyland Dilemma) A two-part tariff can help get a firm closer to the Grail than can simple pricing. It is a pricing scheme (tariff) with, as the name indicates, two parts: I An entry fee the amount that the consumer must pay before she can buy any units at all (overhead charge). II A per-unit charge the amount that the consumer must pay for each unit she chooses to purchase.! In some instances, as with some but not all amusement parks, the per-unit charge might even be set to zero (so-called Disneyland pricing).

= Identical consumers Suppose consumers have identical demands (are homogeneous). Under the profit-maximizing two-part tariff, the firm produces units, where ( )= ( ) sets the per-unit charge equal ( ) setsanentryfee to equal where is the number of consumers.

Price Two part tariff CS MC D Output

= Consumers are heterogeneous If consumers do not all have the same demand curves then designing the optimal two-part tariff becomes much more complicated. One strategy would be to divide customers into homogeneous subgroups (third-degree price discrimination), and then employ the optimal two-part tariff on each group.! Real-life use of two-part tariffs are hard to recognize initially club stores, tech support (some has service-call charge), land-line phones, and more.

Takeaways 1. If all consumers are identical, then perfect price discrimination can be achieved by a two-part tariff. When consumers are not identical, then it is typically not possible to achieve perfect discrimination. 2. When consumers are heterogeneous it is sometimes possible to divide them into different populations that are more homogeneous. If so, then the firm can engage in third-degree price discrimination. 3. When the firm cannot freely identify consumers types, it can try to induce them to reveal their types. This form of price discrimination is known as second-degree price discrimination.

4. Two prevalent forms of second-degree price discrimination are using quality distortions and quantity discounts. 5. Another method of price discrimination is bundling. Bundling allows the firm to take advantage of the correlations that exist between consumers preferences for different products. 6. All discriminatory pricing is, in theory, vulnerable to arbitrage the advantaged reselling to the disadvantaged. Firms seek to deter or reduce arbitrage.

Oligopoly (preface to game theory) Another form of market structure is oligopoly a market in which only a few firms compete with one another, and entry of new firms is impeded. The situation is known as the Cournot model after Antoine Augustin Cournot, a French economist, philosopher and mathematician (1801-1877). In the basic example, a single good is produced by two firms (the industry is a duopoly ).

Cournot s oligopoly model (1838) A single good is produced by two firms (the industry is a duopoly ). The cost for firm =1 2 for producing units of the good is given by ( unit cost is constant equal to 0). If the firms total output is = 1 + 2 then the market price is = if and zero otherwise (linear inverse demand function). We also assume that.

The inverse demand function P A P=A-Q A Q

To find the Nash equilibria of the Cournot s game, we can use the procedures based on the firms best response functions. But first we need the firms payoffs (profits): and similarly, 1 = 1 1 1 = ( ) 1 1 1 = ( 1 2 ) 1 1 1 = ( 1 2 1 ) 1 2 =( 1 2 2 ) 2

Firm 1 s profit as a function of its output (given firm 2 s output) Profit 1 q' q 2 2 q 2 A c 1 q 2 2 A c 1 q' 2 2 Output 1

To find firm 1 s best response to any given output 2 of firm 2, we need to study firm 1 s profit as a function of its output 1 for given values of 2. If you know calculus, you can set the derivative of firm 1 s profit with respect to 1 equaltozeroandsolvefor 1 : 1 = 1 2 ( 2 1 ) We conclude that the best response of firm 1 to the output 2 of firm 2 depends on the values of 2 and 1.

Because firm 2 s cost function is 2 6= 1, its best response function is given by 2 = 1 2 ( 1 2 ) A Nash equilibrium of the Cournot s game is a pair ( 1 2 ) of outputs such that 1 is a best response to 2 and 2 is a best response to 1. From the figure below, we see that there is exactly one such pair of outputs 1 = + 2 2 1 3 and 2 = + 1 2 2 3 which is the solution to the two equations above.

The best response functions in the Cournot's duopoly game Output 2 A c 1 BR 1 ( q 2 ) A c 2 2 Nash equilibrium BR 2 ( q 1 ) A c 1 2 A c 2 Output 1

Nash equilibrium comparative statics (a decrease in the cost of firm 2) Output 2 A c 1 BR 1 ( q 2 ) Nash equilibrium II Nash equilibrium I A c 2 2 BR 2 ( q 1 ) A c 1 2 A c 2 Output 1 A question: what happens when consumers are willing to pay more (A increases)?

In summary, this simple Cournot s duopoly game has a unique Nash equilibrium. Two economically important properties of the Nash equilibrium are (to economic regulatory agencies): [1] The relation between the firms equilibrium profits and the profit they could make if they act collusively. [2] The relation between the equilibrium profits and the number of firms.

[1] Collusive outcomes: in the Cournot s duopoly game, there is a pair of outputs at which both firms profits exceed their levels in a Nash equilibrium. [2] Competition: The price at the Nash equilibrium if the two firms have the same unit cost 1 = 2 = is given by = 1 2 = 1 3 ( +2 ) which is above the unit cost. But as the number of firm increases, the equilibrium price deceases, approaching (zero profits!).

Stackelberg s duopoly model (1934) How do the conclusions of the Cournot s duopoly game change when the firms move sequentially? Is a firm better off moving before or after the other firm? Suppose that 1 = 2 = and that firm 1 moves at the start of the game. We may use backward induction to find the subgame perfect equilibrium. First, for any output 1 of firm 1, wefind the output 2 of firm 2 that maximizes its profit. Nest, we find the output 1 of firm 1 that maximizes its profit, given the strategy of firm 2.

Firm 2 Since firm 2 moves after firm 1, a strategy of firm 2 is a function that associate an output 2 for firm 2 for each possible output 1 of firm 1. We found that under the assumptions of the Cournot s duopoly game Firm 2 has a unique best response to each output 1 of firm 1, given by (Recall that 1 = 2 = ). 2 = 1 2 ( 1 )

Firm 1 Firm 1 s strategy is the output 1 the maximizes 1 =( 1 2 ) 1 subject to 2 = 1 2 ( 1 ) Thus, firm 1 maximizes 1 =( 1 ( 1 2 ( 1 )) ) 1 = 1 2 1( 1 ) This function is quadratic in 1 that is zero when 1 = 0 and when 1 =. Thus its maximizer is 1 = 1 ( ) 2

Firm 1 s (first mover) profit in Stackelberg's duopoly game Profit 1 1 1 q1( A q1 c) 2 A 2 c 1 A c Output 1

We conclude that Stackelberg s duopoly game has a unique subgame perfect equilibrium, in which firm 1 s strategy is the output and firm 2 s output is 1 = 1 ( ) 2 2 = 1 2 ( 1 ) = 1 2 ( 1 ( ) ) 2 = 1 ( ) 4 By contrast, in the unique Nash equilibrium of the Cournot s duopoly game under the same assumptions ( 1 = 2 = ), each firm produces 1 ( ). 3

Output 2 The subgame perfect equilibrium of Stackelberg's duopoly game A c BR 2 ( q 1 ) 2 Nash equilibrium (Cournot) Subgame perfect equilibrium (Stackelberg) A c 3 A c 2 A c Output 1

Bertrand s oligopoly model (1883) In Cournot s game, each firm chooses an output, and the price is determined by the market demand in relation to the total output produced. An alternative model, suggested by Bertrand, assumes that each firm chooses a price, and produces enough output to meet the demand it faces, given the prices chosen by all the firms. = As we shell see, some of the answers it gives are different from the answers of Cournot.

Suppose again that there are two firms (the industry is a duopoly ) and that the cost for firm =1 2 for producing units of the good is given by (equal constant unit cost ). Assume that the demand function (rather than the inverse demand function as we did for the Cournot s game) is ( ) = for and zero otherwise, and that (the demand function in PR 12.3 is different).

Because the cost of producing each until is the same, equal to, firm makes the profit of on every unit it sells. Thus its profit is = where is the other firm. ( )( ) if 1 2 ( )( ) if = 0 if In Bertrand s game we can easily argue as follows: ( 1 2 )=( ) is the unique Nash equilibrium.

Using intuition, If one firm charges the price, then the other firmcandonobetter than charge the price. If 1 and 2,theneachfirm can increase its profit by lowering its price slightly below. = In Cournot s game, the market price decreases toward as the number of firms increases, whereas in Bertrand s game it is (so profits are zero) even if there are only two firms (but the price remains when the number of firm increases).

Avoiding the Bertrand trap If you are in a situation satisfying the following assumptions, then you will end up in a Bertrand trap (zero profits): [1] Homogenous products [2] Consumers know all firm prices [3] No switching costs [4] No cost advantages [5] No capacity constraints [6] No future considerations

Problem set V PR 11 exercises 4, 5, 7 and 8. PR 12 exercises 3-7.