FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 985

Similar documents
UNIVERSITY OF CAPE COAST CAPE COAST - GHANA BASIC OLIGOPOLY MODELS

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Boston Library Consortium IVIember Libraries

Graham Romp Dynamic Game Theory.

Managerial Economics & Business Strategy Chapter 9. Basic Oligopoly Models

Chapter 9: Static Games and Cournot Competition

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

INDUSTRIAL ECONOMICS, WITH APPLICATIONS TO E-COMMERCE An Option for MSc Economics and MSc E-Commerce Autumn Term 2003

Chapter 12: Limit Pricing and Entry Deterrence

ECONOMICS. Paper 3 : Fundamentals of Microeconomic Theory Module 28 : Non collusive and Collusive model

Contents. Concepts of Revenue I-13. About the authors I-5 Preface I-7 Syllabus I-9 Chapter-heads I-11

Chapter 14 TRADITIONAL MODELS OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

The Basic Spatial Model with a Single Monopolist

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Managerial Economics

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Ph.D. MICROECONOMICS CORE EXAM January 2018

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

5/2/2016. Intermediate Microeconomics W3211. Lecture 25: Recap 2. The Story So Far. Organization for the Week. Introduction

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

Part II. Market power

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Economics 323 Microeconomic Theory Fall 2016

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Microeconomics (Fall term) Syllabus

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Econ 101A Solutions for Final exam - Fall 2006

Chapter 15: Industrial Organization

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Part III: Big Applications

1.. Consider the following multi-stage game. In the first stage an incumbent monopolist

14.27 Economics and E-Commerce Fall 14. Lecture 2 - Review

This paper is not to be removed from the Examination Halls

Imperfect Competition

EXAMINATION #4 VERSION C General Equilibrium and Market Power November 24, 2015

ECONOMICS I 2008/2009 EXERCISES 2ND PART

9 The optimum of Oligopoly

BS2243 Lecture 9 Advertisement. Spring 2012 (Dr. Sumon Bhaumik)

KEELE UNIVERSITY MOCK EXAMINATION PAPER ECO MANAGERIAL ECONOMICS II

Solution to Midterm 2 Lecture 1 (9:05-9:55) 50 minutes Econ 1101: Principles of Microeconomics Thomas Holmes November 13, 2006

Economics 384 B1. Intermediate Microeconomics II. Assignment 2. S Landon Winter 2007

Entry Deterrence and Predation. Chapter 9: Entry Deterrence and Predation

Chapter 13. Game Theory. Gaming and Strategic Decisions. Noncooperative v. Cooperative Games

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

Lecture 3: Further static oligopoly Tom Holden

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

Solutions to Final Exam

Renting or Selling A Strategic Choice in a Durable Good Market

Econ 201 Review Notes - Part 3

Econ8500_Game_Theory. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Final Exam Study Questions:

Oligopoly. Fun and games. An oligopolist is one of a small number of producers in an industry. The industry is an oligopoly.

EconS Asymmetric Information

ECON111 Sample Questions. 1.) Please fill in the table below for a perfect competetive firm.

Best-response functions, best-response curves. Strategic substitutes, strategic complements. Quantity competition, price competition

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A)

The Economics of the European Union

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

Copyright (C) 2001 David K. Levine This document is an open textbook; you can redistribute it and/or modify it under the terms of version 1 of the

sample test 3 - spring 2013

Economics II - October 27, 2009 Based on H.R.Varian - Intermediate Microeconomics. A Modern Approach

Boston Library Consortium Member Libraries

Game Theory Exam, June 2015

INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND THE WORLD ECONOMY. Answers to * exercises in chapter 9 of the Study Guide

Umbrella Branding Can Leverage Reputation, but only with Market Power. May 19, Eric B. Rasmusen

Econ 121b: Intermediate Microeconomics

Case: An Increase in the Demand for the Product

Department of Economics. Harvard University. Spring Honors General Exam. April 6, 2011

Sales Restriction, Quality Selection and the Mode of Competition

Managerial Economics

AP Microeconomics: Test 5 Study Guide

Contents in Brief. Preface

Chapter 15 Oligopoly

Commitment and excess capacity: a new look with licensing

PROBLEM SET 3. a) Find the pure strategy Nash Equilibrium of this game.

Harvard University Department of Economics

14.01 Principles of Microeconomics, Fall 2007 Chia-Hui Chen November 7, Lecture 22

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition

Econ 302: Microeconomics II - Strategic Behavior. Problem Set #8 July 5, 2016

Networks, Telecommunications Economics and Strategic Issues in Digital Convergence. Prof. Nicholas Economides. Spring 2006

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS (EC201)

Chapter 6. Competition

Product Differentiation and Innovation in Markets

Industrial Organization 04

Instructor: Wooyoung Lim Games and Strategic Behavior (MBA & MSc Econ) Office: LSK 6080

Advanced Microeconomics Theory. Chapter 8: Game Theory and Imperfect Competition

Oligopoly is a market structure in which Natural or legal barriers prevent the entry of new firms. A small number of firms compete.

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Markets and Strategy. Topics. Strategic Behavior. Intermediate Microeconomics

EconS Oligopoly - Part 1

Supplimentary material for Research at the Auction Block: Problems for the Fair Benefits Approach to International Research

Name FIRST HOUR EXAM ECN 4350/6350

H3 Economics: Game Theory and the Economics of Cooperation. theme 2: firms and market failure game theory notes

Extra Credit. Student:

INTRODUCTORY ECONOMICS

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

Strategic Investment in Merchant. Capacity Utilization Rules

Please Write Your Name and ID # (as these appear in ROSI) Last Name: First Name: ID #

Transcription:

r^ ir) 3 FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 985 THE LIBRARY OF. IHB DEC 5«ois A Note on the Role of Investment in Entry-Deterrence Lanny Arvan College of Commerce and Business Administration Bureau of Economic and Business Research university oi Illinois. Urbana-C^ampaign

BEBR FACULTY WORKING PAPER NO. 985 College of Commerce and Business Administration University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign November 1983 A Note on the Role of Investment in Entry-Deterrence Lanny Arvan, Assistant Professor Department of Economics

A Note on the Role of Investment in Entry-Deterrence by Lanny Arvan* Abstract In this note it is argued that post-entry should be distinguished from pre-entry by the incurrence of capacity costs on the part of the entrant rather than by the incurrence of set-up charges, as is done in Dixit (1980). That Is, capacity costs should be thought of as fixed costs for both incumbent and entrant and set-up charges are linked to the decision whether to produce or not, but not to the purchase of capacity. With this approach there is the possibility of multiple equilibria in Dixit' s model, as is described in Dixit (1974). By viewing the pre-entry capacity commitment and the post-entry play as different stages of an extensive form game, as is done in Spulber (1981), we examine which of these equilibria is perfect. It is shown that multiple perfect equilibria are possible. *Departraent of Economics University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign 1206 South Sixth Street Champaign, IL 61820

Digitized by the Internet Archive in 2011 with funding from University of Illinois Urbana-Champaign http://www.archive.org/details/noteonroleofinve985arva

A Note on the Role of Investment in Entry-Deterrence by Lanny Arvan Department of Economics University of Illinois I. Introduction Dixit (1980) analyzes a post-entry and pre-entry duopoly game when an incumbent firm can make a prior capacity commitment and both entrant and incumbent face declining average production costs in the form of fixed set-up charges. As a consequence of the declining average costs, there is a limiting output level by the incumbent at which the entrant's best response yields the entrant zero profit. When the incumbent firm is committed to this output level the entrant is indifferent between entering or not but, were it to enter under these circumstances, it would do so at an output bounded away from zero. Dixit poses the following two questions. When is a prior commitment by the incumbent to a capacity level larger than the limiting output equivalent to a commitment to produce beyond the limiting output? If this equivalence holds, when does the incumbent prefer to limit entry and when would it rather accommodate entry? In a related paper, Dixit (1979) has shown that in a static duopoly model where both firms face declining average cost curves, there can be multiple Cournot equilibria. The monopoly output will yield a Cournot equilibrium if the monopoly output is greater than the limiting output. Under the identical cost and demand conditions there can also be the standard Cournot equilibrium with both firms producing positive amounts. Yet in Dixit (1980), though market conditions satisfy the assumptions of the 1979 paper, this multiplicity does not

-2- arise. In this note it will be shown that Dixit discarded a potential equilibrium in his analysis, i.e., one must confront the multiple equilibria issue in general. One way of doing so is to recast the model in extensive form, as in Spulber (1981), and then employ a more restrictive solution concept to eliminate this multiplicity. In this context, perfect equilibrium would seem to be the appropriate concept. In deciding on the appropriate extensive form game the critical question is whether it is proper to view capacity costs as part of entrant marginal cost in the post-entry game. In this paper, we adopt the point of view that post-entry is distinguished from pre-entry by the incurrence of capacity costs on the part of the entrant. Hence, in the post-entry game capacity costs do not enter into the marginal cost calculation. This aproach differs from that of Dixit who distinguishes post-entry from pre-entry by the incurrence of set-up costs. To justify our approach we cite Dixit [1980, p. 96] I shall reduce the dynamic aspects to the barest essentials by ignoring all lags. Either entry does not occur at all, in which case the established firm continues in a stationary state, or else it occurs at once, and the post-entry equilibrium is also established at once, so that the resulting duopoly continues in its stationary state. It is as if the two players see through the whole problem and implement the solution immediately... In the stationary, post-entry duopoly, capacity costs are fixed rather than variable costs because, according to Dixit, The established firm chooses a pre-entry capacity level k][. This may subsequently be increased, but cannot be reduced... In all periods subsequent to the period of entry the entrant is also an established firm. Hence, it should treat Dixit' s constraint in the

-3- same manner as the incumbent firm. Dixit' s formal model, which has capacity costs in the entrant marginal cost calculation, is really an examination of in and out entry rather than the stationary, post-entry duopoly that it purports to be. The results of this paper show that when there is a unique perfect equilibrium of the extensive form game, the conclusions of Dixit (1980) still hold, i.e., the discarded equilibrium is not perfect. However, it is possible for there to be multiple perfect equilibria. We demonstrate when this is the case. The presence of multiple perfect equilibria leaves open the question concerning the equivalence of a prior capacity commitment to a commitment to produce beyond the limiting output level. II. The Model and Results We assume the identical cost and revenue functions posited by Dixit (1980). Let the subscript 1 denote the established firm and 2 the prospective entrant. If firm i has capacity k. and is producing output x. (with x. < k.), its costs per period will be 1 11 r r (1) C, - fa + w.x. + r k if x. i i 11 i i l > =0 if x. l = where f. is the fixed set-up cost, r. the constant cost per unit of l l capacity, and w the constant average variable cost for output. The revenues per period for the two firms will be functions R (x,x_). The following properties are assumed to hold

-4- (2) R. > 0, R.. < 0, and R. < for i,j = 1,2 and i * j and R 1 (0,x ) = R 2 (x 0) = 0. In the absence of prior capacity, profits of firm i are given by (3) Tr i (x 1,x 2 ) = R i (x 1,x 2 ) - f± - (w i +r i )x i if x ± > = if x = 0. With prior capacity, k, profits of firm i are given by (3*) ir.(x,x 2,k.) = R (x,x ) - f. - w.x. - r. max(k.,x ) if x > = -r k if x. «0. i l l In Figure 1 (Figure 1 is a reproduction of Figure 3, Dixit [1980, p. 99]), MM' and RR' represent the static reaction function for Firms 1 and 2 respectively, when capacity costs are included in marginal costs and start-up costs are ignored. NN' is the static reaction function for Firm 1 when capacity costs and start-up costs are ignored. When start-up costs are present there is a point on RR' call it B, B = (B, B ), such that ir (B), the profits of Firm 2 at the joint output vector B, equals 0. B. is the limiting output by Firm 1. For any output by Firm 1 greater than B,, Firm 2 would rather make zero profits by not entering than choose the output that would put it on RR*

N' M' R Figure 1

-5- Figure 1 Since Firm 1 makes a prior capacity commitment of k its reactic.on function is given by the kinked curve in Figure 2 shown in heavy lines. In what follows we do not concern ourselves with the effect of start-up costs on Firm l's output decision. Figure 2

N' M' Figure 2

-6- Dixit apparently claims that when tt.(v) > 0, V is the only Nash equilibrium as long as k. _>_ V.. According to Dixit [1980, p. 100] Case 2. tt (V) > 0. Here the prospective entrant will make a positive profit in any post entry equilibrium so the established firm cannot hope to prevent entry. It can only seek the best available duopoly position... When tt (V) > 0, B 1 > V.. When B.. > N, Dixit is correct. But when V < B _<_ N and k > B there is a limiting Nash equilibrium, just as in Dixit (1979). This limiting equilibrium is where x.. = min[max (k., M, ), N. ] and x~ = 0. Suppose the limiting equilibrium prevails over the equilibrium V when B < k and 3 _<_ N. One must still resolve whether it is preferable for Firm 1 to choose k, > B,. Note however, that in some instances this is obvious as it is possible for M > B > V. By Dixit 's own arguments it is conceivable that Firm 1 limits even when tt (V) > 0. As discussed in the introduction, the above equilibrium really addresses the situation where the entrant is around for only one period. One might reasonably ask the following question. Suppose Firm 2 does enter, even if this entails losses. How does Firm 1 respond to this entry? This question cannot be solved by pure static analysis. Spulber (1981) solves this problem when post-entry duopoly lasts for one period. Through a small modification in his model we can interpret this solution as Dixit wishes us to; the post-entry duopoly continues in a stationary state. In addition, we include the start-up costs that are not included in Spulber' s analysis. Our extensive form game occurs in three stages. In the first stage Firm 1 acts as a monopolist and purchases capacity, k. This first stage is identical to the first period of Spulber' s model. In

-7- the second stage the entrant can purchase capacity, k. There is no production in the second stage. This stage can be thought of as occurring between the first and second period in Spulber's model. In the third stage Firms 1 and 2 have prior capacity of k. and k respectively. Both firms can buy additional capacity if they wish in this stage and both firms are Nash quantity setters in their respective outputs. We first look at the equilibrium in the third stage given k. and k. This equilibrium can be thought of as a stationary state in the post-entry duopoly. Firm l's reaction function for this third stage game is given in Figure 2. However, Firm 2's reaction function is no longer given by RR' to the left of B. Instead it is given by the kinked curve in Figure 3 shown in heavy lines. As k has already been choosen in the second stage, capacity costs do not enter into the marginal cost calculations for Firm 2 until its output reaches the prior capacity, k_. However, since set-up charges are still incurred in the third stage, when output is positive, Firm 2 might still find it advantageous to produce nothing in the third stage to avoid the set-up charges. Hence, there is a point, L, on Firm 2's reaction function such that Tr (L,k_) -(- rk_ = 0. Since the fixed capacity costs do not enter into the decision whether to produce in the third stage, it is evident that

-8- Figure 3 Suppose tt (V) > 0, k > B., and k = V. There are two cases to consider in understanding equilibrium of the third stage game. The first is when L- > N_. Then the only equilibrium in this stage is at V. The second possibility is B. <_ L. _<_ N.. Then for k- > L. there is a limiting equilibrium in the third stage. There is still the equilibrium at V. If for k. 2L V., '^2. V 9' v ^ s c^ e unique equilibrium of the third stage game, the limiting equilibrium of the extensive form game is not perfect. However, when there are multiple equilibria of the third stage game there can be multiple perfect equilibria. In the first equilibrium, Firm 1 acts on its "rational belief" in stage one that if it purchases capacity greater than L., it will keep Firm 2 out. In the second equilibrium, Firm 1 acts on the rational belief that it can never keep Firm 2 out. Note that even with the first type

R k rt Figure 3

-9- of beliefs, Firm 1 may choose k < L.., i.e., there is a unique perfect equilibrium. This will happen when limiting entry is too costly. III. Conclusion The results of the previous section suggest that whether capacity is a credible entry deterrent depends on the beliefs of firms as to which Nash equilibrium will arise post-entry. It seems reasonable then to look at other actions by the incumbent, aside from capacity investment, which might affect the beliefs of a potential entrant. Expansion of the formal model to include the possibility of other actions may be helpful in this regard.

-10- References Dixit, A. (1980) "Investment and Entry Deterrence/' The Economic Journal, Vol. 90, March 1980, pp. 95-106.. (1979) "A Model of Duopoly Suggesting a Theory of Entry Barriers," Bell Journal of Economics, Vol. 10, No. 1 (Spring), pp. 20-32. Spulber, D. (1981) "Capacity, Output, and Sequential Entry," American Economic Review, Vol. 77, No. 3, June 1981, pp. 503-514 D/167