Ch. 9 LECTURE NOTES 9-1

Similar documents
AP Microeconomics Chapter 10 Outline

CH 14: Perfect Competition

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

Slides and Images, Worth Publishers Inc. 8-1

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

4. Which of the following statements about marginal revenue for a perfectly competitive firm is incorrect? A) TR

INTRODUCTION ECONOMIC PROFITS

Lecture 11. Firms in competitive markets

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Chapter 14 Perfectly competitive Market

Perfect Competition CHAPTER14

2010 Pearson Education Canada

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

23 Perfect Competition

Introduction. Learning Objectives. Chapter 24. Perfect Competition

Chapter 6. Competition

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

ECONOMICS CHAPTER 9: FORMS OF MARKET

2007 Thomson South-Western

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

microeconomics II first module

FINALTERM EXAMINATION FALL 2006

CH 15: Monopoly. Lecture

CH 13. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 98 (CHIU) Midterm 1 Review: Part A Fall 2004

Firms in Competitive Markets

Four Market Models. 1. Perfect Competition 2. Pure Monopoly 3. Monopolistic Competition 4. Oligopoly

Lesson22: Trade under Monopolistic Competition

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

Chapter 1- Introduction

micro2 first module Basic assumptions of PC 2. Product homogeneity 1. Large number of firms Profit maximization in general 3. Free entry and exit

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

MICRO EXAM REVIEW SHEET

Chapter 10 Pure Monopoly

BUSINESS ECONOMICS (PAPER IV-PART I)

CONTENTS. Introduction to the Series. 1 Introduction to Economics 5 2 Competitive Markets, Demand and Supply Elasticities 37

Quiz #4 Week 04/05/2009 to 04/11/2009

ECON 2100 (Summer 2014 Sections 08 & 09) Exam #3D

AP Microeconomics Review With Answers

Perfect Competition CHAPTER 14. Alfred P. Sloan. There s no resting place for an enterprise in a competitive economy. Perfect Competition 14

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

Pure Competition in the Short Run

AGENDA Mon 10/12. Economics in Action Review QOD #21: Competitive Farming HW Review Pure Competition MR = MC HW: Read pp Q #7

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

The Four Main Market Structures

Lecture 12. Monopoly

Short-Run Costs and Output Decisions

Principles of. Economics. Week 6. Firm in Competitive & Monopoly market. 7 th April 2014

Chapter 13. What will you learn in this chapter? A competitive market. Perfect Competition

2) A production method that relies on large quantities of labor and smaller quantities of capital equipment is referred to as a: 2)

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH PERFECT COMPETITION.

MICROECONOMICS CHAPTER 10A/23 PERFECT COMPETITION. Professor Charles Fusi

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

Pure Monopoly. The antithesis of Pure Competition!

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3A

Principles of Economics. January 2018

Firms in competitive markets: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

2007 Thomson South-Western

REDEEMER S UNIVERSITY

Market structures Perfect competition

IB Economics Microeconomics Review Mr. Dachpian

Microeconomics: MIE1102

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Section I (20 questions; 1 mark each)

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

Firms in Competitive Markets

Perfect Competition. What is a market structure? What is a Perfectly Competitive Market/Perfect Competition? David Kelly

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

1.3. Levels and Rates of Change Levels: example, wages and income versus Rates: example, inflation and growth Example: Box 1.3

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

ECON 311 MICROECONOMICS THEORY I

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

Microeconomics. Use the graph below to answer question number 3

FIRMS IN COMPETITIVE MARKETS

Where are we? Second midterm on November 19. Review questions on th course web site. Today: chapter on perfect competition

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

WHAT IS A COMPETITIVE MARKET?

Unit 7. Firm behaviour and market structure: monopoly

Monopoly CHAPTER 15. Henry Demarest Lloyd. Monopoly is business at the end of its journey. Monopoly 15. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Three Rules and Four Models

Three Rules and Four Models

Econ 111 2nd MT 16 17

Textbook Media Press. CH 12 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

ECON 102 Kagundu Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

short run long run short run consumer surplus producer surplus marginal revenue

Transcription:

Ch. 9 LECTURE NOTES I. Four market models will be addressed in Chapters 9-11; characteristics of the models are summarized in Table 9.1. A. Pure competition entails a large number of firms, standardized product, and easy entry (or exit) by new (or existing) firms. B. At the opposite extreme, pure monopoly has one firm that is the sole seller of a product or service with no close substitutes; entry is blocked for other firms. C. Monopolistic competition is close to pure competition, except that the product is differentiated among sellers rather than standardized, and there are fewer firms. D. An oligopoly is an industry in which only a few firms exist, so each is affected by the price-output decisions of its rivals. II. Pure Competition: Characteristics and Occurrence A. The characteristics of pure competition: 1. Pure competition is rare in the real world, but the model is important. a. The model helps analyze industries with characteristics similar to pure competition. b. The model provides a context in which to apply revenue and cost concepts developed in previous chapters. c. Pure competition provides a norm or standard against which to compare and evaluate the efficiency of the real world. 2. Many sellers means that there are enough so that a single seller has no impact on price by its decisions alone. 3. The products in a purely competitive market are homogeneous or standardized; each seller s product is identical to its competitor s. 4. Individual firms must accept the market price; they are price takers and can exert no influence on price. 5. Freedom of entry and exit means that there are no significant obstacles preventing firms from entering or leaving the industry. B. There are four major objectives to analyzing pure competition. 1. To examine demand from the seller s viewpoint, 2. To see how a competitive producer responds to market price in the short run, 3. To explore the nature of long-run adjustments in a competitive industry, and 4. To evaluate the efficiency of competitive industries. 9-1

III. IV. Demand from the Viewpoint of a Competitive Seller A. The individual firm will view its demand as perfectly elastic. 1. Figures 9.1 and 9.7a illustrate this. 2. The demand curve is not perfectly elastic for the industry: It only appears that way to the individual firm, since they must take the market price no matter what quantity they produce. 3. Note from Figure 9.1 that a perfectly elastic demand curve is a horizontal line at the price. B. Definitions of average, total, and marginal revenue: 1. Average revenue is the price per unit for each firm in pure competition. 2. Total revenue is the price multiplied by the quantity sold. 3. Marginal revenue is the change in total revenue and will also equal the unit price in conditions of pure competition. (Key Question 3) Profit Maximization in the Short-Run: Two Approaches A. In the short run the firm has a fixed plant and maximizes profits or minimizes losses by adjusting output; profits are defined as the difference between total costs and total revenue. B. Three questions must be answered. 1. Should the firm produce? 2. If so, how much? 3. What will be the profit or loss? C. An example of the total-revenue total-cost approach is shown in Table 9.2. Note that the costs are the same as for the firm in Table 9.2 in the previous chapter. 1. Firm should produce if the difference between total revenue and total cost is profitable, or if the loss is less than the fixed cost. 2. In the short run, the firm should produce that output at which it maximizes its profit or minimizes its loss. 3. The profit or loss can be established by subtracting total cost from total revenue at each output level. 4. The firm should not produce, but should shut down in the short run if its loss exceeds its fixed costs. Then, by shutting down its loss will just equal those fixed costs. 5. Graphical representation is shown in Figures 9.2a and b. Note: The firm has no control over the market price. 9-2

D. Marginal-revenue marginal-cost approach (see Table 9.3 and Figure 9.3 Key Graph). 1. MR = MC rule states that the firm will maximize profits or minimize losses by producing at the point at which marginal revenue equals marginal cost in the short run. 2. Three features of this MR = MC rule are important. a. Rule assumes that marginal revenue must be equal to or exceed minimum-averagevariable cost or firm will shut down. b. Rule works for firms in any type of industry, not just pure competition. c. In pure competition, price = marginal revenue, so in purely competitive industries the rule can be restated as the firm should produce that output where P = MC, because P = MR. 3. Using the rule on Table 9.3, compare MC and MR at each level of output. At the tenth unit MC exceeds MR. Therefore, the firm should produce only nine (not the tenth) units to maximize profits. 4. Profit maximizing case: The level of profit can be found by multiplying ATC by the quantity, 9 to get $880 and subtracting that from total revenue which is $131 x 9 or $1179. Profit will be $299 when the price is $131. Profit per unit could also have been found by subtracting $97.78 from $131 and then multiplying by 9 to get $299. Figure 9.3 (Key Graph) portrays this situation graphically. 5. Loss-minimizing case: The loss-minimizing case is illustrated when the price falls to $81. Table 9.4 is used to determine this. Marginal revenue does exceed average variable cost at some levels, so the firm should not shut down. Comparing P and MC, the rule tells us to select output level of 6. At this level the loss of $64 is the minimum loss this firm could realize, and the MR of $81 just covers the MC of $80, which does not happen at quantity level of 7. Figure 9.4 is a graphical portrayal of this situation. 6. Shut-down case: If the price falls to $71, this firm should not produce. MR will not cover AVC at any output level. Therefore, the minimum loss is the fixed cost and production of zero. Table 9.4 and Figure 9.5 illustrate this situation, and it can be seen that the $100 fixed cost is the minimum possible loss. 9-3

7. CONSIDER THIS The Still There Motel E. Marginal cost and the short-run supply curve can be illustrated by hypothetical prices such as those in Table 9-6. At price of $151 profit will be $480; at $111 the profit will be $138 ($888-$750); at $91 the loss will be $3.01; at $61 the loss will be $100 because the latter represents the close-down case. 1. Note that Table 9.5 gives us the quantities that will be supplied at several different price levels in the short-run. 2. Since a short-run supply schedule tells how much quantity will be offered at various prices, this identity of marginal revenue with the marginal cost tells us that the marginal cost above AVC will be the short-run supply for this firm (see Figure 9.6 Key Graph). F. Changes in prices of variable inputs or in technology will shift the marginal cost or short-run supply curve in Figure 9.6 (Key Graph). 1. For example, a wage increase would shift the supply curve upward. 2. Technological progress would shift the marginal cost curve downward. 3. Using this logic, a specific tax would cause a decrease in the supply curve (upward shift in MC), and a unit subsidy would cause an increase in the supply curve (downward shift in MC). G. Determining equilibrium price for a firm and an industry: 1. Total-supply and total-demand data must be compared to find most profitable price and output levels for the industry. (See Table 9.6) 2. Figure 9.7a and b shows this analysis graphically; individual firm supply curves are summed horizontally to get the total-supply curve S in Figure 9.7b. If product price is $111, industry supply will be 8000 units, since that is the quantity demanded and supplied at $111. This will result in economic profits similar to those portrayed in Figure 9.3. 3. Loss situation similar to Figure 9.4 could result from weaker demand (lower price and MR) or higher marginal costs. H. Firm vs. industry: Individual firms must take price as given, but the supply plans of all competitive producers as a group are a major determinant of product price. (Key Question 4) 9-4

VI. Profit Maximization in the Long Run A. Several assumptions are made. 1. Entry and exit of firms are the only long-run adjustments. 2. Firms in the industry have identical cost curves. 3. The industry is a constant-cost industry, which means that the entry and exit of firms will not affect resource prices or location of unit-cost schedules for individual firms. B. Basic conclusion to be explained is that after long-run equilibrium is achieved, the product price will be exactly equal to, and production will occur at, each firm s point of minimum average total cost. 1. Firms seek profits and shun losses. 2. Under competition, firms may enter and leave industries freely. 3. If short-run losses occur, firms will leave the industry; if economic profits occur, firms will enter the industry. C. The model is one of zero economic profits, but note that this allows for a normal profit to be made by each firm in the long run. 1. If economic profits are being earned, firms enter the industry, which increases the market supply, causing the product price to gravitate downward to the equilibrium price where zero economic profits are earned (Figure 9.8). 2. If losses are incurred in the short run, firms will leave the industry; this decreases the market supply, causing the product price to rise until losses disappear and normal profits are earned (Figure 9.9). D. Long-run supply for a constant cost industry will be perfectly elastic; the curve will be horizontal. In other words, the level of output will not affect the price in the long run. 1. In a constant-cost industry, expansion or contraction does not affect resource prices or production costs. 2. Entry or exit of firms will affect quantity of output, but will always bring the price back to the equilibrium price (Figure 9.10). E. Long-run supply for an increasing cost industry will be upward sloping as industry expands output. 1. Average-cost curves shift upward as the industry expands and downward as industry contracts, because resource prices are affected. 2. A two-way profit squeeze will occur as demand increases because costs will rise as firms enter, and the new equilibrium price must increase if the level of profit is to be maintained at its normal level. Note that the price will fall if the industry contracts as production costs fall, and competition will drive the price down so that individual firms do not realize above-normal profits (see Figure 9.11). F. Long-run supply for a decreasing cost industry will be downward sloping as the industry expands output. This situation is the reverse of the increasing-cost industry. Average-cost curves fall as the industry expands and firms will enter until price is driven down to maintain only normal profits. (Key Question 7) 9-5

VII. Pure Competition and Efficiency A. Whether the industry is one of constant, increasing, or decreasing costs, the final long-run equilibrium will have the same basic characteristics (Figure 9.12 Key Graph). 1. Productive efficiency occurs where P = minimum AC; at this point firms must use the least-cost technology or they won t survive. 2. Allocative efficiency occurs where P = MC, because price is society s measure of relative worth of a product at the margin or its marginal benefit. And the marginal cost of producing product X measures the relative worth of the other goods that the resources used in producing an extra unit of X could otherwise have produced. In short, price measures the benefit that society gets from additional units of good X, and the marginal cost of this unit of X measures the sacrifice or cost to society of other goods given up to produce more of X. a. If price exceeds marginal cost, then society values more units of good X more highly than alternative products the appropriate resources can otherwise produce. Resources are underallocated to the production of good X. b. If price is less than marginal cost, then society values the other goods more highly than good X, and resources are overallocated to the production of good X. 3. Allocative efficiency implies maximum consumer and producer surplus. a. Consumer surplus is the benefit buyers receive by having the market price less than their maximum willingness to pay (as also seen in Chapter 6). b. Producer surplus is the benefit sellers receive by having the market price greater than their minimum willingness to accept for payment. c. Combined consumer and producer surplus is maximized at equilibrium (see Figure 9.12b Key Graph). d. Any quantity less than equilibrium would reduce both consumer and producer surplus (reducing the green and blue areas of Figure 9.12b Key Graph) e. Any quantity greater than equilibrium would occur with an efficiency loss that would subtract from combined consumer and producer surplus. 4. Dynamic adjustments will occur automatically in pure competition when changes in demand or in resource supplies or in technology occur. Disequilibrium will cause expansion or contraction of the industry until the new equilibrium at P = MC occurs. 5. The invisible hand (introduced in Chapter 2) works in a competitive market system since no explicit orders are given to the industry to achieve the P = MC result. (Assumes private goods with no externalities.) 9-6

VIII. LAST WORD: Efficiency Gains from Entry: The Case of Generic Drugs A. When a pharmaceutical company introduces a new drug, it typically owns the patent and can price and produce as a monopolist, earning economic profits. B. When patent rights expire, however, firms pursuing economic profits enter the market for that drug (producing generics) and the market changes to more closely resemble pure competition. C. The introduction of competition drops prices of these drugs typically 30-40 percent. Those lower prices increase efficiency and consumer surplus. (See Last Word figure) 9-7