The graphic below shows the effect on social welfare of a merger that reduces marginal costs.

Similar documents
At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

Jacob: W hat if Framer Jacob has 10% percent of the U.S. wheat production? Is he still a competitive producer?

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

All but which of the following are true in the long-run for a competitive firm that maximizes profits?

Textbook Media Press. CH 12 Taylor: Principles of Economics 3e 1

Contents. Concepts of Revenue I-13. About the authors I-5 Preface I-7 Syllabus I-9 Chapter-heads I-11

Oligopoly: How do firms behave when there are only a few competitors? These firms produce all or most of their industry s output.

Unit 13 AP Economics - Practice

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

If the industry s short-run supply curve equals the horizontal sum of individual firms short-run supply curves, which of the following may we infer?

Monopoly and How It Arises

Econ Microeconomic Analysis and Policy

Microeconomics (Oligopoly & Game, Ch 12)

INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMICS LECTURE 13 - MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION AND OLIGOPOLY. Monopolistic Competition

AP Microeconomics Review Session #3 Key Terms & Concepts

Microeconomics, marginal costs, value, and revenue, final exam practice problems

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Recall from last time. Econ 410: Micro Theory. Cournot Equilibrium. The plan for today. Comparing Cournot, Stackelberg, and Bertrand Equilibria

Principles of Economics. January 2018

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

29/02/2016. Market structure II- Other types of imperfect competition. What Is Monopolistic Competition? OTHER TYPES OF IMPERFECT COMPETITION

Perfect competition: occurs when none of the individual market participants (ie buyers or sellers) can influence the price of the product.

Principles of Microeconomics Module 5.1. Understanding Profit

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Introduction. Managerial Problem. Solution Approach

The Analysis of Competitive Markets

CH short answer study questions Answer Section

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH PERFECT COMPETITION.

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall with answers to MC

ANTITRUST ECONOMICS 2013

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition

The homework is due on Wednesday, December 7 at 4pm. Each question is worth 0.8 points.

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Chapter 6: Market Structure

Economic Profit. Accounting. Profit. Explicit. Costs. Implicit costs (including a normal profit) Accounting. costs (explicit costs only) T O T A L

ECON 230D2-002 Mid-term 1. Student Number MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

14.1 Comparison of Market Structures

ECON 102 Kagundu Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

Textbook questions: Competitors and Competition

CIE Economics A-level

Indicate whether the sentence or statement is True or False. Mark "A" if the statement is True or "B" if it is False.

Chapter 8 Competitors and Competition

ECON 102 Brown Final Exam (New Material) Practice Exam Solutions

Marginal willingness to pay (WTP). The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra unit of the good.

MARKETS WITH MARKET POWER Microeconomics in Context (Goodwin, et al.), 3 rd Edition

Do not open this exam until told to do so. Solution

Microeconomics Exam Notes

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2004

Many sellers: There are many firms competing for the same group of customers.

Lecture 12. Monopoly

Lecture 22. Oligopoly & Monopolistic Competition

Market Equilibrium, Price Floor, Price Ceiling

Monopolistic Competition

Unit 4: Imperfect Competition

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

MULTIPLE CHOICE. Choose the one alternative that best completes the statement or answers the question.

A few firms Imperfect Competition Oligopoly. Figure 8.1: Market structures

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

Syllabus item: 57 Weight: 3

a) I, II and III. b) I c) II and III only. d) I and III only. 2. Refer to the PPF diagram below. PPF

Market Structure & Imperfect Competition

Final Term Examination Spring 2006 Time Allowed: 150 Minutes. Question No. 1 Marks :1. Question No.

COST OF PRODUCTION & THEORY OF THE FIRM

Eco201 Review questions for chapters Prof. Bill Even ====QUESTIONS FOR CHAPTER 13=============================

ECON December 4, 2008 Exam 3

CH 13. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Firms in competitive markets: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

- pure monopoly: only one seller of a good/service with no close substitutes

Coffee is produced at a constant marginal cost of $1.00 a pound. Due to a shortage of cocoa beans, the marginal cost rises to $2.00 a pound.

Sample Multiple-Choice Questions

ECON6021. Market Structure. Profit Maximization. Monopoly a single firm A patented drug to cure SARS A single power supplier on HK Island

Refer to the information provided in Figure 12.1 below to answer the questions that follow. Figure 12.1

Econ8500_Imperfect_Competition

The above Figure 1 shows the demand and cost curves facing a monopolist.

EXAMINATION #4 VERSION C General Equilibrium and Market Power November 24, 2015

Monopoly and How It Arises

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

MARKETS. Part Review. Reading Between the Lines SONY CORP. HAS CUT THE U.S. PRICE OF ITS PLAYSTATION 2

OLIGOPOLY: Characteristics

Perfect Competition CHAPTER14

2013 sample MC CH 15. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

ECON 260 (2,3) Practice Exam #4 Spring 2007 Dan Mallela

Monopolistic Competition. Chapter 17

Microeconomics. More Tutorial at

Microeconomics, Module 4: Consumers in the Marketplace. Practice Problems. (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) Updated: July 10, 2006

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Economic Analysis for Business Decisions Multiple Choice Questions Unit-2: Demand Analysis

COMPETITION AND MARKETS BEFORE YOU BEGIN. Market Structures. Looking at the Chapter. Date Period. Chapter

11. Oligopoly. Literature: Pindyck and Rubinfeld, Chapter 12 Varian, Chapter 27

Price setting problem: Rigidities

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

Transcription:

Micro, Modules 13, 14, 15, Market power, cartels, oligopoly, practice problem s (The attached PDF file has better formatting.) ** Exercise 15.1: Costs savings with m onopoly The graphic below shows the effect on social welfare of a merger that reduces marginal costs.! The vertical axis is price; the horizontal axis is quantity.! The downward sloping line DD is the market demand curve.! The downward sloping line MR is the marginal revenue curve, with twice the slope of the demand curve.! P* is the equilibrium price under perfect com petition.! P is the equilibrium price under m onopoly.! Q* is the equilibrium quantity under perfect com petition.! Q is the equilibrium quantity under m onopoly.! MC* is the marginal cost curve under perfect competition.! MC is the marginal cost curve under monopoly. In the graphic, m arginal costs are constant; constant m arginal costs are not needed for this exercise. A. W hat is consumers surplus under com petition? B. W hat is producers surplus under com petition? C. W hat is consumers surplus under m onopoly? D. W hat is producers surplus under m onopoly? E. W hat is the difference in the social gain from trade between competition and monopoly?

Part A: Consumers surplus under competition is A + B + C + D + E. Part B: Producers surplus under competition is zero, since the marginal cost curve is flat. Part C: Consumers surplus under monopoly is A + B. Part D: Producers surplus under monopoly is C + D + F + G. Part E: The difference in social gain is A + B + C + D + F + G (A + B + C + D + E) = F + G E. Jacob: is the difference in social gain positive or negative? Rachel: In industries with relatively high price elasticities of dem and, where consum ers can buy other products if the price is too high, monopoly has little effect. Monopoly is important where the price elasticity of demand is low. An example is pharmaceutical drugs: people with cancer will pay almost any price for a cancer drug which works. Pharm aceutical drugs have high costs: research and developm ent, clinical trials, and approval by the FDA take about ten years. If five firms compete to produce a medication, each must spend the entire research and development costs. Society gains if the five firms merge into a monopoly and each pays one fifth the total research and development costs. The final market price for the medication is lower, since the costs are lower. In other cases, marginal costs are low, and monopoly raises prices. For example, auto insurance is required by law, so the price elasticity of demand is low. Marginal costs don t differ much by size of the insurer. The loss costs are the sam e, underwriting costs are the sam e, and even distribution costs (agents com m issions) are not that much lower for large insurers. Society gains by having a large number of small insurers. The world have only a few pharmaceutical drug makers and thousands of auto insurers. In these industries, actual markets are efficient. This is not always true, but it often occurs.

** Exercise 15.: Oligopoly / Market power Two identical firms sell the same product and compete as a Bertrand oligopoly.! The market demand curve is P = 40 ½ Q.! The marginal cost curve is MC = 0. A. W hat defines a Bertrand oligopoly? B. W hat is the equilibrium price? C. W hat is the equilibrium quantity? D. W hat is consumers surplus? E. W hat is producers surplus? F. W hat is the net social gain from trade? Part A: In a Bertrand oligopoly, firm s take their competitors prices as given. Part B: The equilibrium price in a Bertrand oligopoly is the equilibrium price in competition.! If a firm prices lower than the competitive price, it loses money.! If a firm prices higher than the com petitive price, its competitor prices slightly lower to take away its m arket share. The competitive price is the marginal cost = $0. Jacob: W hat if both firms use the monopoly price? Both firms do better than with the competitive price, so the m onopoly price is Pareto superior to the com petitive price. Rachel: This is the same as the prisoner s dilemma, where both players do better with not confess, but if either one fails to confess, the other choose confess. Here too, if either firms sets the monopoly price, the other firm sets a lower price and obtains the whole market. Landsburg explains the prisoner s dilemma as a prelude to the oligopoly m odels. Part C: If the price is the competitive price, the quantity is the competitive quantity, determined as P = MC: 40 ½ Q = 0 Q = 40. The two firms are identical, so each firm produces ½ 40 = 0. Part D: Consumers surplus is the area below the demand curve from 0 to the quantity supplied: ½ ($40 $0) 40 = $400 Part E: Producers surplus is zero for constant m arginal costs. Part F: The social gain from trade is consumers surplus + producers surplus = $400 + $0 = $400

** Exercise 15.3: Oligopoly / Market power Two identical firms sell the same product and compete as a Cournot oligopoly.! The market demand curve is P = 40 ½ Q.! The marginal cost curve is MC = 0. A. W hat defines a Cournout oligopoly? B. W hat is the marginal revenue curve? C. W hat is the equilibrium quantity? D. W hat is the equilibrium price? E. W hat is consumers surplus? F. W hat is producers surplus? G. W hat is the net social gain from trade? Part A: In a Cournot oligopoly, firms take their com petitors quantities as given. Part B: The total revenue curve (TR) is P Q = 40 Q ½ Q. The marginal revenue curve is MR = (TR)/ Q = (40 Q ½ Q )/ Q = 40 Q. Part C: Suppose firm #1 produces quantity of q*. Firm # faces a demand curve of P = 40 ½ (q q*), where q is its own quantity and q* is the fixed quantity of Firm #1.! The total revenue curve for Firm # is TR = 40q ½q ½ q* q.! The marginal revenue curve for Firm # is TR = 40 ½q* q. Setting marginal revenue = marginal cost gives 40 ½q* q = 0. The two firms are identical, so in equilibrium, q = q*. W e solve 40 ½q q = 0 q = b 0. Jacob: Is this result general? In a Cournot oligopoly, does each firm produce two thirds what it would produce in competitive equilibrium? Rachel: This result applies if the marginal cost curve is flat and the Cournot oligopoly has two firm s. If the marginal cost curve is flat and the Cournot oligopoly has N firms, each firm produces N/(N+1) what it would produce in a competitive equilibrium. Industry output is b of competitive quantity, so each firm s output is ½ b = a of the competitive quantity. The equilibrium quantity under competition is Q = 40, so the equilibrium quantity for a Cournot oligopoly is b 40 = 6.67. Each firm produces 13.33. Part D: The equilibrium price is read from the market demand curve: P = 40 ½ b 40 = b 40 = 6.67. Part E: Consumers surplus is the area below the demand curve from 0 to the quantity supplied: ½ ($40 $6.67) 6.67 = $177.78 Part F: Producers surplus is the area above the marginal cost curve from 0 to the quantity supplied: ($6.67 $0) 6.67 = $177.78

Part G: The social gain from trade is consumers surplus + producers surplus = $177.78 + $177.78 = $355.56. Jacob: Is the net social gain from trade always less for a Cournot oligopoly than for a Bertrand oligopoly? Rachel: The social gain from trade depends on the quantity supplied. The com petitive quantity gives the highest social gain from trade. Higher or lower quantity reduces the social gain from trade. So yes: the net social gain from trade always less for a Cournot oligopoly than for a Bertrand oligopoly.

** Exercise 15.4: Oligopoly / Market power Two identical firms sell the same product and compete as a Bertrand oligopoly.! The market demand curve is P = 40 ½ Q.! The marginal cost curve is MC = 0. The two firm s merge and reduce their operating costs. The m arginal cost declines by a factor of Z, so the new m arginal cost curve is MC = 0 (1 Z). The combined firm prices as a monopoly. Answer the questions below as functions of Z. A. W hat is the marginal revenue curve? B. W hat is the equilibrium quantity? C. W hat is the equilibrium price? D. W hat is consumers surplus? E. W hat is producers surplus? F. W hat is the net social gain from trade? G. If the net social gain from trade is the same as in the Bertrand scenario, what is Z? Part A: The total revenue curve (TR) is P Q = 40 Q ½ Q. The marginal revenue curve is MR = (TR)/ Q = (40 Q ½ Q )/ Q = 40 Q. Part C: Set marginal revenue = marginal cost: 40 Q = 0 (1 Z) Q = 0 + 0Z. Part D: The equilibrium price is read from the market demand curve: P = 40 ½ (0 + 0Z) = 30 10Z. Part E: Consumers surplus is the area below the demand curve from 0 to the quantity supplied: ½ ($40 (30 10Z) ) (0 + 0Z) = ($10 + 10Z) ) (10 + 10Z) = $100 + $00Z + $100Z Part E: Producers surplus above the marginal cost curve from 0 to the quantity supplied: ($30 10Z ($0 0Z) ) (0 + 0Z) = ($10 + 10Z) (0 + 0Z) = $00 + $400Z + $00Z Part F: The social gain from trade is consumers surplus + producers surplus $100 + $00Z + $100Z + $00 + $400Z + $00Z = $300 + $600Z + $300Z Part G: In the Bertrand oligopoly, the net social gain from trade is $400. Solve $400 = $300 + $600Z + $300Z 3Z + 6Z 1 = 0 Z = ( 6 ± (36 + 1) ) / 6 = ( 6 ± 6.980) / 6 = 0.15470. (Only the positive solution is relevant.)

** Exercise 15.5: Oligopoly The Price Theory textbook discusses two models of oligopoly: Cournot and Bertrand. A. W hat is the defining characteristic of the Cournot oligopoly model? B. W hat is the defining characteristic of the Bertrand oligopoly m odel? C. Under which m odel is the equilibrium quantity higher? D. Under which m odel is the equilibrium price higher? E. Under which m odel is consum ers surplus higher? F. Under which m odel is producers surplus higher? G. Under which model is the net social gain higher? Part A: In the Cournot oligopoly model, each firm takes its competitor s quantity as given. Part B: In the Bertrand oligopoly model, each firm takes its competitor s price as given. Part C: The equilibrium quantity is higher in the Bertrand oligopoly model.! Bertrand oligopoly: equilibrium quantity = com petitive quantity.! Cournot oligopoly: equilibrium quantity = b com petitive quantity. Part D: The equilibrium price is higher in the Cournot oligopoly model.! The market demand curve is downward sloping.! A lower equilibrium quantity means a higher equilibrium price. Part E: Consum ers surplus is higher in a Bertrand oligopoly model. A higher equilibrium price and lower quantity in a Cournot oligopoly m eans less consum ers surplus. Part E: Producers surplus is higher in a Cournot oligopoly model. If producers surplus were lower, firm s would raise quantity and lower price. Part F: Net social gain is higher in a Bertrand oligopoly model. Net social gain is maximized at the competitive quantity, as in the Bertrand oligopoly model.

** Exercise 15.6: Predatory pricing and buy-outs! Insurer ABC is a large countrywide firm with 85% of the personal auto market in State W. " Its surplus is ten times its annual premium in State W.! Insurers X, Y, and Z are small mono-state insurers; each has 5% of the personal auto market in State W. " Each insurer s surplus is 40% of the annual premium in State W.! Entry to the market is easy (barriers to entry are small).! Personal auto coverage is required by law for all drivers. A. Is the price elasticity of demand high or low? B. W hy might ABC temporarily reduce prices below cost? C. W hy might predatory pricing be a poor strategy? D. W hy might ABC purchase insurers X, Y, and Z? E. W hy might this purchase be a poor strategy? F. If entry into the market is expensive, would predatory pricing / buy-outs be more or less likely?

Part A: Personal auto coverage is required by law for all drivers. Regardless of the price (as long as it is not too high), most drivers buy coverage. Price elasticity of demand is low. Most people buy cars and pay whatever is needed for insurance. If the car costs $50,000, gas and repairs cost $5,000 a year, and the car lasts 10 years, the cost of driving is $10,000 a year. The insurance policy costs another $1,000 a year. A 10% change in the cost of insurance coverage is a change of 1% in the total cost of driving. This m akes the price elasticity of dem and for insurance very inelastic. Part B: W ith inelastic price elasticity of demand, ABC can make large monopoly profits if it controls the entire market. It can easily withstand temporary losses in the state, since its total surplus is ten times its premium in the state. Insurers X, Y, and Z can not withstand losses, since each insurer s surplus is low relative to its premium in the state. These insurers may exit the industry if prices are too low. Part C: If other insurers realize that predatory pricing below cost is tem porary, they m ay shut down for a year. Insurers have few fixed costs, so the losses from shutting down temporarily are small. Some insurers may also arrange for a loan (through a holding company or a subsidiary). Even if predatory pricing succeeds in driving insurers from the market, barriers to entry are small. As soon as ABC raises prices, new insurers will enter the market. Part D: Instead of predatory pricing, ABC might buy insurers X, Y, and Z. Once it has the entire market, it can raise prices to m onopoly levels. Part E: Buy-outs can be expensive, since the acquiring firm generally pays a premium above market prices. If other insurers realize that ABC will buy out its com petitors in the state, they will form subsidiaries in the state and sell them at premiums to ABC. Part F: If entry into the market is expensive (barriers to entry are high), ABC is less worried about new firms entering. It is more likely to buy out existing firms or reduce prices below cost for a year or two. Jacob: Do barriers to entry affect predatory pricing and buy-outs in this fashion? Rachel: Yes they do. In industries with low barriers to entry (service firm s, insurance, high-tech firm s like cell phones and other gadgets), buy-outs are not com m on. In industries with high barriers to entry (autom obiles, oil, pharmaceutical drugs), firms buy each other to create monopolies. For example, suppose two firms have patented cancer m edications. If a single firm has the entire m arket, it can charge extremely high prices, since the price elasticity of demand for cancel medication is inelastic. People with cancer will pay $100 a year or $10,000 a year for medication; the cost of the medication won t much affect their purchase, since they will die with no medication. If their insurance pays for the medication, they will pay $100,000 a year. A third firm will not enter the market, since the time lag for research and development, clinical studies, and approval by the Food and Drug Administration is about ten years. The two existing firm s will not com pete. One will buy out the other and charge m onopoly prices.