These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text.

Similar documents
1 Applying the Competitive Model. 2 Consumer welfare. These notes essentially correspond to chapter 9 of the text.

EconS Monopoly - Part 2

EconS Monopoly - Part 1

EconS Perfect Competition and Monopoly

Monopoly. Business Economics

Chapter Eleven. Monopoly

Chapter 11. Monopoly. I think it s wrong that only one company makes the game Monopoly. Steven Wright

P rofit t (1 + i) t. V alue = t=0

Chapter Eleven. Topics. Marginal Revenue and Price. A firm s revenue is:

11.1 Monopoly Profit Maximization

Lecture 10: Market Power and Monopoly

Lecture 11: Market Power and Monopoly

Lecture 11: Market Power and Monopoly

Monopoly. 3 Microeconomics LESSON 5. Introduction and Description. Time Required. Materials

Unit 6 Perfect Competition and Monopoly - Practice Problems

ECON 2100 Principles of Microeconomics (Summer 2016) Monopoly

Boston College Problem Set 6, Fall 2012 EC Principles of Microeconomics Instructor: Inacio G L Bo

Quiz #5 Week 04/12/2009 to 04/18/2009

Econ 2113: Principles of Microeconomics. Spring 2009 ECU

CHAPTER NINE MONOPOLY

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Monopoly and Market Power. Session V Sep 18, 2010

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

Chapter 11. Monopoly

THEORY OF THE FIRM. Number of Workers Bread Loaves (thousands) :

Monopoly CHAPTER. Goals. Outcomes

Lesson 3-2 Profit Maximization

EconS Endogenous Market Size

Marginal willingness to pay (WTP). The maximum amount a consumer will spend for an extra unit of the good.

EconS Third-Degree Price Discrimination

Monopoly. Cost. Average total cost. Quantity of Output

Market structures. Why Monopolies Arise. Why Monopolies Arise. Market power. Monopoly. Monopoly resources

Monopoly. PowerPoint Slides prepared by: Andreea CHIRITESCU Eastern Illinois University

MICROECONOMIC FOUNDATIONS OF COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS. Townley, Chapter 4

Unit 6: Non-Competitive Markets

EconS First-Degree Price Discrimination

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

not to be republished NCERT Chapter 6 Non-competitive Markets 6.1 SIMPLE MONOPOLY IN THE COMMODITY MARKET

Eastern Mediterranean University Faculty of Business and Economics Department of Economics Fall Semester

Chapter 12. Monopoly. Chapter Outline. Key Ideas. Key Ideas. Introducing a New Market Structure. Evidence-Based Economics Example 11/25/2016

Monopoly and How It Arises

Monopolistic Markets. Causes of Monopolies

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis March 19, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

Module 61 Introduction to Monopoly

CH 14. Name: Class: Date: Multiple Choice Identify the choice that best completes the statement or answers the question.

c) Will the monopolist described in (b) earn positive, negative, or zero economic profits? Explain your answer.

Eco 300 Intermediate Micro

Lecture 12. Monopoly

ECON December 4, 2008 Exam 3

EconS Vertical Pricing Restraints 2

At P = $120, Q = 1,000, and marginal revenue is ,000 = $100

1.4 Applications of Functions to Economics

Agenda. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 1. Profit Maximization by a Monopolist. 2. Marginal Revenue. 3. Profit Maximization Exercise

- pure monopoly: only one seller of a good/service with no close substitutes

a. Sells a product differentiated from that of its competitors d. produces at the minimum of average total cost in the long run

ECON 2100 (Summer 2012 Sections 07 and 08) Exam #3C Answer Key

Introduction. Managerial Problem. Solution Approach

Chapter 13. Microeconomics. Monopolistic Competition: The Competitive Model in a More Realistic Setting

Consumer and Producer Surplus and Deadweight Loss

CH 15: Monopoly. Lecture

Introduction to Economics II: Producer Theory

Coffee is produced at a constant marginal cost of $1.00 a pound. Due to a shortage of cocoa beans, the marginal cost rises to $2.00 a pound.

ECON 200. Introduction to Microeconomics

Microeconomics. Claudia Vogel EUV. Winter Term 2009/2010. Market Power: Monopoly and Monopsony

Monopoly. While a competitive firm is a price taker, a monopoly firm is a price maker.

MICROECONOMICS - CLUTCH CH MONOPOLISTIC COMPETITION.

Principles of. Economics. Week 6. Firm in Competitive & Monopoly market. 7 th April 2014

EconS Competitive Markets Part 1

Monopoly and How It Arises

All but which of the following are true in the long-run for a competitive firm that maximizes profits?

Chapter 13 MODELS OF MONOPOLY. Copyright 2005 by South-Western, a division of Thomson Learning. All rights reserved.

Monopoly. Chapter 15

Chapter 11 Perfect Competition

Chapter 1- Introduction

Practice Exam 3: S201 Walker Fall 2009

Supply in a Competitive Market

Firms in competitive markets: Perfect Competition and Monopoly

CH 14: Perfect Competition

Perfect Competition CHAPTER14

Monopoly. Basic Economics Chapter 15. Why Monopolies Arise. Monopoly

ECON 101: Principles of Microeconomics Discussion Section Week 12 TA: Kanit Kuevibulvanich

Thursday, October 13: Short and Long Run Equilibria

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3C

ECON 2100 (Summer 2016 Sections 10 & 11) Exam #3D

ECON 115. Industrial Organization

UC Berkeley Haas School of Business Economic Analysis for Business Decisions (EWMBA 201A) Fall 2013

Economics. Monopolistic Perfect Competition. Monopolistic Competition. Monopolistic Competition 11/29/2013. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

EconS Pricing and Advertising - Part 2

Ecn Intermediate Microeconomic Theory University of California - Davis June 11, 2009 Instructor: John Parman. Final Exam

A monopoly market structure is one characterized by a single seller of a unique product with no close substitutes.

Econ 300: Intermediate Microeconomics, Spring 2014 Final Exam Study Guide 1

THEORY OF THE FIRM. 2. Let us consider the production function Q = F (L; K) = LK: a) Compute the isoquants K = g(l) for Q = 729 and Q = 100:

Economics. Monopolistic Competition. Firms in Competitive Markets. Monopolistic Competition 11/22/2012. The Big Picture. Perfect Competition

Monopoly. The single seller or firm referred to as a monopolist or monopolistic firm. Characteristics of a monopolistic industry

Monopoly CHAPTER 15. Henry Demarest Lloyd. Monopoly is business at the end of its journey. Monopoly 15. McGraw-Hill/Irwin

Economics 101 Spring 2001 Section 4 - Hallam Quiz 10. For questions 1-9, consider firms using a technology with cost and marginal cost functions:

Homework 4 Economics

The above Figure 1 shows the demand and cost curves facing a monopolist.

Chapter 10 Pure Monopoly

NAME: INTERMEDIATE MICROECONOMIC THEORY FALL 2006 ECONOMICS 300/012 Final Exam December 8, 2006

ECON 102 Wooten Final Exam Practice Exam Solutions

Transcription:

These notes essentially correspond to chapter 11 of the text. 1 Monopoly A monopolist is de ned as a single seller of a well-de ned product for which there are no close substitutes. In reality, there are very few true monopolists; however, people sometimes consider rms with a large market share (such as Microsoft) a monopolist. We will focus on the implications of the true monopolist. In the perfectly competitive market, the market demand curve is downward sloping, and the rm s demand curve is horizontal (perfectly elastic). In a monopoly, the market demand curve is also downward-sloping however, since there is only a single seller in the market, the market demand curve is also the monopolist s demand curve. The monopolist s downward-sloping demand curve has some implications for the monopolist s M R. 1.1 Deriving MR for monopolist We will derive the monopolist s MR by example rst, and then through a formal mathematical derivation. 1.1.1 Deriving MR by example Suppose that the monopolist faces the following inverse demand function, (Q) = 100 Q. The monopolist s T R function is found by multiplying price and quantity, so that T R = (Q) Q = (100 Q) Q in this example. We can now ll out the table below for the given quantities. The price is found by plugging the di erent quantity levels into the inverse demand function. Total revenue is found by multiplying price and quantity. Recall that M R is just the increase in T R from one unit to the next (which is how we found MC in chapter 7, except we looked at the increase in T C from one unit to the next). Quantity rice TR MR 0 100 0 1 99 99 99 2 98 196 97 3 97 291 95 4 96 384 93 5 95 475 91 If we were to plot the price and quantity pairs, we would get the rm s demand curve. If we were to plot the MR and quantity pairs, we would get the rm s M R. lotting the two relationships gives us: 1

rice 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 20 40 60 80 100 Quantity The MR is the steeper of the two lines, and lies inside the demand curve. Notice that the MR of the 2 nd unit is $97 even though the price is $98. The reason that MR < is because if the monopolist wishes to sell an additional unit, it needs to lower the price on EVERY unit sold. Thus, the rst unit that was initially sold for $99 brought in additional revenue of $99. To sell 2 units, the monopolist must lower the price to $98. The second unit brings in additional revenue of $98, but the 1 st unit must now also be sold for $98, which is a loss of $1 in revenue. Thus, the total additional revenue generated by the second unit is $98 $1 = $97. So, the MR for a monopolist will fall faster than the demand curve. Recall that in a perfectly competitive market the M R and demand curves were the same curves. 1.1.2 Deriving a M R function We can also derive a monopolist s MR as a function of quantity. I will work through the steps for deriving a monopolist s M R function for a linear inverse demand function (we will only work with linear inverse demand functions). At the end of the derivation, I will give you a rule that you can use to nd the monopolist s M R function for any linear inverse demand function. Recall that T R = (Q) Q which equals (a bq) Q for a general linear inverse demand function with intercept a and slope ( b). We want to see how total revenue changes for a very small, essentially zero, change in quantity. Start with the total revenue of some quantity Q. T R (Q) = (a bq) Q = aq bq 2 Now, nd the total revenue for Q + h, which h is some positive, albeit very small, amount. T R (Q + h) = (a b (Q + h)) (Q + h) = (a bq bh) (Q + h) = aq bq 2 bqh + ah bqh bh 2 2

So, T R (Q) = aq bq 2 and T R (Q + h) = aq bq 2 2bQh + ah bh 2 (notice that I combined the 2 ( bqh) terms into ( 2bQh)). The de nition for MR says that it is the change in T R divided by the change in quantity. The change in T R is: This simpli es to: T R = aq bq 2 2bQh + ah bh 2 aq bq 2 T R = 2bQh + ah bh 2 Since we began by producing Q and we have now increased production to Q + h, the change in quantity is Q + h Q = h. So our MR is: MR (Q) = T R Q = 2bQh + ah bh 2 h Simplifying, we are left with: MR (Q) = ( 2bQ + a bh) There is one nal step. Recall that we wanted h to be a very small number, essentially zero. If h is essentially zero, then the term ( bh) = ( b 0) = 0 and it drops out. This leaves us with (I will rearrange so that the a term is rst): MR (Q) = a For those of you that have had calculus, the MR function is simply the derivative of the T R function with respect to quantity. So: dt R (Q) d (Q) = d aq bq2 dq 2bQ = a 2bQ Either way gets you the same answer, that the MR function is a 2bQ for a linear inverse demand function of the form a bq. This is our rule: RULE If the inverse demand function is a linear inverse demand function of the form (Q) = a bq, then the marginal revenue function is: MR (Q) = a 2bQ. 1.2 ro t maximization for a monopolist We will use two methods to nd the monopolist s maximum pro t. is a graphical method and the second is a mathematical method. The rst 3

1.2.1 ro t maximization graphically The steps to nding the monopolist s pro t-maximizing price and quantity are similar to those for the perfectly competitive rm. A picture is shown below and the steps are described following the picture. 1. The rst step is to nd the quantity that corresponds to the point where MR = MC. This is Q in the picture. 2. The second step is to nd the price that corresponds to the quantity that corresponds to the point where MR = MC. The rm nds this price by nding the price on the DEMAND curve that corresponds to its pro tmaximizing quantity. This is shown in the picture as. 3. Find the rm s total revenue at the pro t-maximizing price and quantity. Since this is just the price times the quantity it is ( ) (Q ). 4. Now, nd the AT C that corresponds to the pro t-maximizing quantity. This is shown as AT C in the picture. 5. Find the rm s total cost at the pro t-maximizing price and quantity. This is T C = (AT C ) (Q ). 6. The rm s pro t is then T R T C. Alternatively, the rm s pro t can be written as = ( ) (Q ) (AT C ) (Q ) = ( AT C ) (Q ). When written this way, it is easy to see that the pro t the rm earns is simply the rectangle outlined by the dotted lines in the picture from 4

to AT C and over to Q. rectangle. So pro t is simply the area outlined by that 1.2.2 ro t maximization mathematically We will follow the same basic steps to determine the pro t-maximizing price and quantity mathematically. We will need a few pieces of information: the monopolist s inverse demand function, marginal revenue function, marginal cost function, and either the average total cost function or the total cost function. Assume that the inverse demand function is: (Q) = 24 Q. This means that the marginal revenue function is: M R (Q) = 24 2Q. Suppose that the monopolist s marginal cost function is: M C (Q) = 2Q, and that the monopolist s average total cost function is: AT C (Q) = Q + 12 Q. 1. The rst step is to nd the quantity that corresponds to the point where MR = MC. Since MR (Q) = 24 2Q and MC (Q) = 2Q, we set MR (Q) = MC (Q). This gives us: 24 2Q = 2Q 24 = 4Q Q = 6 2. The second step is to nd the price that corresponds to the quantity that corresponds to the point where MR = MC. We know that when MR = MC, the rm s quantity is 6. The price that the rm will sell 6 units at is found by plugging the quantity into the inverse demand function, which is (Q) = 24 Q. (6) = 24 6 = 18 Thus, the rm will sell 6 units at a price of 18. 3. Now, total revenue is simply price times quantity, or $18 6 = $108. 4. Now, nd the AT C that corresponds to the pro t-maximizing quantity. We can use the AT C function, which is AT C (Q) = Q + 12 Q. So: AT C (6) = 6 + 12 6 = 6 + 2 = 8 Thus, the average total cost of producing 6 units is $8. 5. The monopolist s total cost is just AT C times Q, or $8 6 = $48. 5

6. The monopolist s pro t is then T R T C, which is just $108 $48 = $60. Notice that the steps to nd maximum pro ts are the same in either method. In one method a picture is used and in another method functions are used. 2 Monopolist and rice Elasticity of Demand We can determine how much market power a monopolist has if we calculate the monopolist s ED at its pro t-maximizing quantity. However, we will need to rewrite the MR in terms of ED. We know that, for a linear inverse demand function, MR (Q) = a 2bQ. Use the following steps to rewrite the MR. We know that (Q) = a MR (Q) = a 2bQ = a bq bq bq, so: We also know that ( So: MR (Q) = bq b) = Q (where it is understood that Q is negative). MR (Q) = + Q Q Multiply both sides by one (this is one of the tricks). On the left-hand side, we will choose our one to be 1, and on the right-hand side we will choose our one to be. MR (Q) = + Q Q Distribute: Now rewrite as: MR (Q) = + Q Q Factor out the : MR (Q) = + Q Q MR (Q) = 1 + Q Q Recall that price elasticity of demand is equal to the last term is simply the reciprocal of the ED. So: MR (Q) = 1 + 1 ED 6 Q Q. Notice that

where ED is negative (and NOT the absolute value). This formula has some interesting implications for the monopolist s pricing decision. First, notice that if ED = 1 then MR = 0. If 0 > ED > 1, then MR < 0. If 1 > ED > 1, then MR > 0. This suggests that the monopolist will never price on the inelastic portion of its demand curve, as the monopolist will actually be losing revenue by choosing a price on the inelastic portion of the demand curve. Recall that the elasticity for a linear demand curve depends on the particular point chosen along the demand curve. As we move up the demand curve (higher prices), demand becomes more elastic. As we move down the demand curve (towards a 0 price), demand becomes more elastic. For linear demand curves, the quantity level halfway between 0 and the point where the demand curve crosses the quantity axis is the point that corresponds to ED = 1. Thus, the MR at this point is zero. 2.1 rice-cost Markup and Market ower In a perfectly competitive market, when a rm chooses its quantity it sets MR = MC. However, since the rm s MR is the same as the price in the market, the rm is in essence charging a price equal to its marginal cost, or = MC. With a monopolist, the price charged by the rm is above the MC of production for that unit. We can use the price-cost markup as an indicator of a monopolist s market power. The price-cost markup formula is: MC The formula will range from 0 to 1: If = MC, as in the perfectly competitive rm, then the price-cost markup will equal 0; as the monopolist increases its price above marginal cost (e ectively making marginal cost very small relative to price), then the price-cost markup will tend to 1. So, the closer the number is to 0 the less market power the rm has. 2.2 Lerner Index and Market ower An alternative method of determining market power is to look at the Lerner Index. Recall that MR = 1 + 1 ED. At the pro t-maximizing quantity, MR = MC, so 1 + 1 ED = MC. We can use a few algebra maneuvers to show that MC = 1 ED at the pro t-maximizing quantity. Start with: 1 + 1 = MC ED Then: 1 + 1 = MC ED 7

Multiply both sides by negative one: 1 1 ED = MC Now, add one to both sides. I will add the number 1 to the left-hand side, and the term to the right-hand side. But I am really just adding one to both sides. Simplify to get: 1 1 1 ED = MC 1 ED = MC Thus, at the pro t-maximizing quantity, the price-cost markup is simply the reciprocal of the monopolist s price elasticity of demand at that quantity. This is known as the Lerner Index, and it measures market power in the same manner as the price-cost markup. Note that the more elastic demand is at the monopolist s pro t-maximizing quantity, the less market power the rm has. Also note that this relationship only holds at the rm s pro t-maximizing quantity, since we assumed that MR = MC when we derived the fact that 1 ED = MC. 3 Monopolies and Social Welfare It was suggested that one reason to use the perfectly competitive market was that it provided a benchmark model for markets to reach. We can now compare the welfare properties of the monopoly with those of the perfectly competitive market. There are quite possibly more de nitions for the term e cient in economics than there are for any other term. We can de ne e ciency as a market situation where all the gains from trade are captured. Recall the partial equilibrium analysis of a tax from chapter 3. When a tax was imposed on the market there were some trades that were previously made that were no longer possible. This loss to society from trades that were not made is called deadweight loss. What we will show is that the perfectly competitive market contains no deadweight loss, while the monopoly market does. However, we will need to de ne a few terms rst. Consumer Surplus Consumer surplus is the di erence between a consumer s maximum willingness to pay for a unit of the good (the height of the demand curve) and the price actually paid for the good. Thus, if the most a consumer is willing to pay is $10 for a good and the consumer only pays $3, then the consumer has $7 in consumer surplus. If we were to look at the consumer surplus on a graph, it would be the entire area under the demand curve but above the price paid. 8

roducer Surplus roducer surplus is the di erence between the price a producer pays and the producer s minimum willingness to sell that unit of the good (given by the height of the MC). Thus, if the minimum a producer is willing to sell a unit for is $1 and the producer sells it for $3, then the producer receives $2 in producer surplus (note that this is di erent from pro t, as producer surplus only focuses on marginal costs, which do not consider xed costs, whereas pro t takes xed costs into account). If we were to look at producer surplus on a graph, it would be the entire area below the price of the good but above the MC (or supply curve). Gains from trade The possible gains from trade in the market is the area under the demand curve but above the MC (or supply curve). The actual (or realized) gains from trade in the market is the sum of the consumer surplus and producer surplus. If the actual gains from trade equals the possible gains from trade, then we say that the market is e cient. Deadweight loss We ve already covered deadweight loss, but I bring it up as a refresher. The deadweight loss is essentially the di erence between the possible gains from trade and the actual gains from trade. It is the loss in e ciency that occurs because there is some feature of the market that keeps the market from trading the e cient quantity. 3.1 Welfare and erfect Competition The picture below shows a perfectly competitive market in LR equilibrium (however, the analysis provided also pertains to perfectly competitive markets where rms are earning positive pro ts or losses). 9

In the competitive market, there is no deadweight loss. The market is perfectly e cient, as all the gains from trade in both the market and the rm pictures have been captured. 3.2 Welfare and monopoly The picture below shows the welfare e ects of a monopoly. 10

Notice that in the monopoly market the e cient quantity (Qeff) is not the same as the monopolist s pro t-maximizing quantity (Q m ). This is because the e cient quantity is found at the point where society s marginal bene t (the demand curve) equals society s marginal cost (the monopolist s MC), while the monopolist looks at its own marginal bene t (which is the MR curve) and nds the quantity that sets its own marginal bene t equal to MC. Since the monopolist s marginal bene t curve is not the same as society s marginal bene t curve, the market is ine cient, and deadweight loss (DWL) results. The fact that deadweight loss results in a monopoly is the reason that monopolies are considered bad (well, at least that s why economists consider monopolies bad). Of course, since monopolies are so bad, why then do they exist? 3.3 Reasons monopolies exist There are two major reasons why monopolies exist, which can be broken into a few subcategories. Those reasons are cost advantages and government actions 3.3.1 Cost Advantages 1. Control a key input One reason that a monopoly may exist is that a rm may control a key input needed in the production of a product. In the diamond market, DeBeers owned 80% of the world s diamond supply at one point in time. Thus, if someone wanted diamonds, they had to go through DeBeers. 11

2. Superior technology/production technique It can also be the case that one rm has a better production technology or technique than other rms. If this is the case, that rm will be able to charge a lower price than the other rms and, if it can charge a low enough price while still maintaing pro ts, it should be able to drive the other rms from the market, creating a monopoly or at least a near-monopoly. 3. Natural monopoly A natural monopoly exists when the LRATC for a representative rm in an industry is decreasing throughout the entire range of relevant demand. In this case, the larger a rm becomes the the lower the per-unit costs it experiences (there are no diseconomies of scale). Thus, a single rm will have lower production costs than 2 or more rms. 3.3.2 Government Actions 1. Government monopolies There are some industries, such as the post o ce, that are run by the government and protected from competition. These industries are monopolies because the government has deemed them as monopolies. 2. Licensing In most cases the government does not license monopolies, but it does require licenses (liquor licenses, medallions for New York City taxicabs) that protect rms from competition. 3. atents atents are used to protect inventors from having their creative work stolen/copied by others. The government grants the inventor a patent that gives him monopoly power over his product for a speci ed time period. 3.4 Government actions that reduce market power The government attempts to reduce market power because rms with more market power tend to cause larger deadweight loss in the market. The government can reduce market power through a few methods. 1. Remove arti cial restrictions in the market Any government action that creates market power could be removed in order to reduce market power. 2. Increase competition through antitrust laws The antitrust laws were created to reduce market power. The government prosecutes rms for various forms of anti-competitive behavior in an e ort to reduce market power. 12

3. rice or pro t regulation If we look at the monopolist s picture, we can see what the price should be that will allow the e cient quantity to be traded in the market. Thus, the government could force the monopolist to price at this level, increasing e ciency. Of course, nding this price in a theoretical model is much easier than it is in the real-world. 4 The monopolist s LR equilibrium Recall that positive economic pro ts attract other rms to enter the market when the market is perfectly competitive. However, when the market is a monopoly, the monopolist is protected by some entry barrier. Since the monopolist is protected by an entry barrier other rms cannot enter into the industry thus they cannot take away the monopolist s economic pro t. This means that the monopolist s LR equilibrium, if its entry barriers stay intact, will look exactly like its short-run equilibrium, even if positive economic pro ts are being made. The primary di erence between the monopolist and the perfectly competitive market in the LR is that the monopolist can sustain economic pro ts in the LR while the perfectly competitive rm cannot. 13