Lessons from the LIPGENE Project: Policy Dilemmas that Arise in Supplying Special Lipid- Modified Foods

Similar documents
Farm Subsidies and Obesity in the United States: National Evidence and International Comparisons

A European Food Prices Monitoring Tool

Study on Employment, Growth and Innovation in Rural Areas (SEGIRA)

Vision Growth Balance. All About Organics Food that matters

Grass-fed and its Market Significance for Irish Beef

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q1 2017

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q3 2018

Analysis of the EU meat markets

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q2 2017

Latest developments of beef production in the EU. Mark Topliff Senior Analyst AHDB Market Intelligence Brisbane June 2010

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q2 2018

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q1 2018

ECONOMIC BULLETIN Q3 2017

THIS REPORT CONTAINS ASSESSMENTS OF COMMODITY AND TRADE ISSUES MADE BY USDA STAFF AND NOT NECESSARILY STATEMENTS OF OFFICIAL U.S.

Protein Trends & Technologies Seminar May 23-24, 2017

Impact of partial decoupling on prices, production and farm revenues in the EU

Estonia FooD and FooD safety

Market utilization overview. Grain Farmers of Ontario

Workshop Mediterranean products in a global lmarket Cetraro, June, issues and prospects. Dept. of Economics, University of Torino

Changing landscape for livestock production in Europe Directions and expected change in the next years

(Gives background and presents arguments for both sides) by P. Byrne, D. Pendell, & G. Graff* Quick Facts...

Environmentally Harmful Subsidies in the Transport Sector

At A Glance Summary of Q highlights

China as a market for Latin American dairy and beef : a supply and demand outlook with a food security perspective

Organic markets for fruit and vegetables in Europe

Estonia FooD and FooD safety

11 EQ7: Structure of dairy industry

MINNESOTA DAIRY INDUSTRY PROFILE

GLOBALDIV Summer School 2008

CAP CONTEXT INDICATORS

OHIO SOYBEAN COUNCIL FY2016 STRATEGIC PLAN

GMO in seeds actual state of affairs

SWEDISH FARMING, BEEF PRODUCTION AND CHAROLAIS. - An overview Sofia Persson and Lennart Nilsson The Swedish Charolais Association

Driving Productivity Growth in the Irish Agri-Food Sector

Meat Marketing Strategy

IMPLEMENTATION OF THE CAP REFORM ON LEAN BEEF FARMING SYSTEMS

Protein Sources : State of Play in Europe

1979 Food and Agricultural Outlook

ADVANCED General Certificate of Education January Economics. Assessment Unit A2 1. Business Economics [AE211] FRIDAY 17 JANUARY, MORNING

Farm Credit Canada Annual Report

Organic Market Research Study

Beef production, supply and quality from farm to fork in Europe

FARM POLICY AND OBESITY IN THE UNITED STATES

THE AGRICULTURE AND FOOD INDUSTRY IN RUSSIA: FACTS AND FIGURES

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON 8 October 1974 TARIFFS AND TRADE

March Agricultural Update Consensus Unit LWV STL March 8-14, 2014

Global Cattle Feed Market Research Report- Forecast to 2023

Glen K. Fukumoto CTAHR, University of Hawaii at Manoa Marianas Livestock and Grazing Academy

CAP CONTEXT INDICATORS

EVENT REPORT 2018 FREE FROM FUNCTIONAL AND INGREDIENTS MAY 2018 STOCKHOLM EUROPEAN TRADE EVENT ON

Environmental impact assessment of CAP greening measures using CAPRI model

Competitiveness of American Agriculture in the Global Economy. Ian Sheldon. AED Economics

Truth About Food: The Data

Situation and Outlook for U.S. Livestock, Dairy, and Poultry

Implementation of GM Food Legislation in Ireland. Pat O Mahony FSAI

Are Agricultural Policies Making Us Fat? Likely Links Between Agricultural Policies and Human Nutrition and Obesity, and their Implications

GENERAL AGREEMENT ON. RESTRICTED DPC/INV/5/Add.8 TARIFFS AND TRADE. holdings at a level comparable to the average income per man-year in

Of the benefits to the EU of removing the Common Agricultural Policy

Case Histories of Grass-Fed Market Development in the Upper Midwest

UNIT 6 UNDERSTANDING THE PROCESS FOR PRODUCING, BREEDING, AND MARKETING AGRICULTURE ANIMALS

Final Report to PIRSA

INTERNATIONAL DAIRY PRODUCTS COUNCIL. Reply to Questionnaire 5 Regarding Information on Domestic Policies and Trade Measures NORWAY.

Emissions, Regulations and Impact in the European Union and The Netherlands

Key Statistics: Monthly Update January 2014

Feed Industry Perspective on EU Protein Production Nick Major FEFAC President

EUROPEAN COMMISSION DIRECTORATE-GENERAL FOR AGRICULTURE AND RURAL DEVELOPMENT

Farm Economics brief

Genetically modified food = Biotechnology for thought. Food and nutrition in 21st century Warsaw, September 9, 2011

KEEPING FOOD LOSSES IN THE FOOD CHAIN

Issues and Challenges in Broiler Production. Richard L. Lobb Director of Communications National Chicken Council

Winter Short Term Outlook for arable crops, meat and dairy markets HIGHLIGHTS. Contents. 1. Macroeconomic outlook. 2. Arable crops. 3.

Adding Imports to Producer Price Measures for Food By Alberto Jerardo

Key messages of chapter 3

2020 and Beyond. Sue Lockhart Head of Agriculture Sainsbury s Supermarket Ltd

8 September 1975 GENERAL AGREEMENT ON RESTRICTED L/4221 TARIFFS AND TRADE. Paragraph 4 of the Protocol for the Accession of Switzerland (1974)

Feed market potential

FEFAC s approach towards responsible soy

Training course on Animal Welfare concerning the farming of laying hens and broiler chickens kept for meat production

The best quality assurance for meat and animal feed comes from the Netherlands

LINSEED : PRODUCTION IN EUROPE AND POTENTIALITIES FOR THE FUTURE

Zimbabwe ANNUAL REPORT

Food Price Outlook,

E U R O P E A N U N I O N

The European Commission s science and knowledge service. Scene-setter on jobs and growth in EU agri-food sector. Joint Research Centre

GFM FOOD TECH SUMMIT Saudi F&B Market Addressing Health and Wellness as the New Growth Wave

Development of plant proteins in the European Union

The Structure of the Fluid Milk Sector in Turkey

3rd Cattle Network EAAP Workshop

FOOD MARKET IN POLAND (current state and trends)

CAN REGIONAL, ORGANIC AGRICULTURE FEED THE REGIONAL COMMUNITY? A Case Study for Hamburg and North Germany

How we feed our beef

Trends on Global Food Markets: What Is the Significance of Biofuels?

The European Feed Mix

World Agricultural Outlook Board Interagency Commodity Estimates Committee Forecasts. Lockup Briefing June 11, 2014

Mastering Productivity Growth- Where Canadian Food processing is lagging behind

DDGS A World of Opportunities. Dr. Jerry Shurson Department of Animal Science University of Minnesota

Identity preservation (IP) refers to any system of raw material

Bord Bia DAFM Live Exporters Meeting

Emissions Trading System (ETS): The UK needs to deliver its share of the total EU ETS emissions reduction of 21% by 2020, compared to 2005;

EU Dairy Markets, Situation and Outlook September-December 2010

Transcription:

Lessons from the LIPGENE Project: Policy Dilemmas that Arise in Supplying Special Lipid- Modified Foods Presentation for Brussels, May 2005 By Dr James Fry and Dr Willa Finley LMC International, Oxford, UK

Outline of the Presentation Brief summary of the incidence and economic costs of obesity in the EU. The costs of devising separate identitypreserved (IP) output and processing chains to supply foods with an improved lipid content to help to combat obesity in general and the metabolic syndrome in particular. The willingness of consumers to pay a premium for healthy foods, and the case for official subsidies to lower the prices of such food and lower the incidence of obesity.

The Incidence and Direct and Indirect Costs of Obesity in the EU-15 (Applying growth rates from OECD time series some of which are biased downwards by self-reporting to recent IOTF estimates, and UK NAO obesity cost data for 1998)

Increase in Obesity Among EU Adult Males % Obesity in Adult Males (BMI > 30) 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Finland Austria Belgium Denmark France Germany Ireland Italy Netherlands Spain Sweden United Kingdom

Increase in Obesity Among Adult Females % Obesity in Adult Females (BMI > 30) 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 Finland Austria Belgium Denmark France Germany Ireland Italy Netherlands Spain Sweden United Kingdom

2002 Total EU-15 Direct and Indirect Costs of Obesity (Attributed Pro Rata to 1998 UK Data) 1,989 863 887 916 3,216 10,436 Total = 32,813 million 4,324 4,748 5,435 Germany Italy UK France Spain Austria Netherlands Greece Others

Overall Costs and Incidence of Obesity in 2002 in the EU-15 The full annual direct and indirect costs of obesity in the EU-15 in 2002 were estimated to be nearly 33 billion. The UK, Germany, Italy and France together accounted for over 75% of the total. For both men and women, at least half the member states have more than 20% of their adults with BMIs of over 30.

The Costs of Improving Plant, Dairy and Meat Nutrient Profiles and of Applying Identity Preservation (IP) Systems Throughout Their Supply Chain

The Costs of Separate Supply Chains Identity preservation (IP) systems are needed to keep special foods, commanding premium prices, separate and segregated from cheaper commodity products. In addition to the costs of devising special IP systems for special plant and animal products, the creation of low volume supply chains imposes extra costs on suppliers via the inability to exploit economies of scale.

Identity Preservation (IP) Costs Along the Production Chain with Oilseed and Grain Products

Production and Marketing Costs of IP from a Farm in the US to an Export Market in the EU IP costs, $/tonne, excluding processing 200 160 120 80 40 0 Food Grade Soybeans Herbicide-tolerant Non-GMO Soybeans General Non-GMO Soybeans Non-GMO Maize 0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0 Quantity (million tonnes)

Indexes of Soybean Crushing Costs, Illustrating the Cost Penalty if IP Requires Smaller Processing Plants Costs as % of a 2,000 tpd Crushing Costs 400% 350% 300% 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 2,000 tpd solvent 500 tpd solvent 50 tpd expeller

Supply Chain Costs for Healthy Nutrient Profiles in Animal Products

Examples of Existing Lipid-Modified Livestock Products With Enhanced Conjugated Linoleic Acid (CLA) or Ω-3 Content

Omega-3 Content, grams/100 grams Ω-3 3 Fatty Acid Levels in Conventional 1.5 1.2 0.9 0.6 0.3 0.0 and Enhanced Livestock Products Beef Milk Poultry Eggs Omega-3-enhanced Conventional

1.6 Levels of CLA in Conventional and Enhanced Milk and Beef CLA Content, grams/100 grams 1.4 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 Beef CLA-enhanced Conventional Milk

Production Costs of Food Products with Healthy Nutrient Profiles Total supply costs for milk, meat or eggs with healthy nutrient profiles are 10-60% more than for conventional alternatives. This is due to The extra costs of feed, such as flax (linseed) or fish oil, needed to enhance the CLA/ Ω-3 levels, The costs associated with reduced rate of gain (high CLA beef) or reduced productivity (Ω-3 eggs). IP costs, including transportation and testing. Higher unit costs due to inability to exploit scale.

Example of the Fresh Milk Supply Chain

Economies of Scale in Conjugated Linoleic 0.70 Acid (CLA) Fresh Milk Production Production Costs, US$ per litre of milk 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 Small (<50 head) Medium (50-199) Large (200-499) Industrial (>500) Herd Size (Number of Head) All Other Costs IP Costs Non-IP CLA Costs

Economies of Scale in Processing 0.80 CLA Fresh Milk Milk Processing Costs, $/litre 0.70 0.60 0.50 0.40 0.30 0.20 0.10 0.00 0.365 13.6 54.5 Million Litres per Annum Capacity Non-IP Costs IP Costs

Economies of Scale in the CLA Fresh Milk Production & Processing-to to-retail Chain 2.00 Overall Costs, US$ per litre of milk 1.80 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 Small Medium Large Herd Size Production Processing Retail

Example of the Free Range Broiler Chicken Supply Chain

Economies of Scale in Free-Range Full Production Costs ($ per bird) 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 Broiler Production on Farm 6,000 18,000 54,000 Number of Birds Produced Annually Natural Free-range Organic Natural Free-range + Omega-3/CLA

Economies of Scale in Broiler Processing 3.50 Processing Cost per Bird ($) 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 0.00 0 50,000 100,000 150,000 200,000 250,000 300,000 Processing (Birds/day)

Costs to the Processing Stage for High Ω-3/CLA Free Range Broilers $/bird 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 6,000 18,000 54,000 Flock Size (number of birds) All Other Costs Total IP Costs Total Cost Due to Healthy Trait

Example of Hormone-free and Grass-fed (High CLA) Beef

Production Costs for Beef with Healthy Nutritional Attributes 1,800 1,600 1,400 1,200 $/head 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 Hormone Free Grass-fed (Enhanced CLA) Conventional Basic Costs Penalty from Lack of Scale Cost of Slower Growth IP Costs

Grass-Fed Hormone-Free & Conventional Beef Production Costs (Excl. Calf Cost) 350 300 250 $/head 200 150 100 50 0 Grassfed Conventional Feeding Operations Processing Retail

Example of the Organic, High Ω-3 Eggs Supply Chain

Production Costs for Organic and Egg Production Costs ($/dozen) 1.60 1.40 1.20 1.00 0.80 0.60 0.40 0.20 0.00 High Ω-3 3 Eggs Conventional Organic-Omega-3 All Other Costs Costs due to IP Costs due to Omega-3

Overall Extra IP and Input Costs for Healthy Foods, From Farm to Retail IP costs are 2-5% of costs across all products. Extra costs due to the healthy trait typically account for 7-14% of total costs. Combined IP and special input costs represent 10-16% of total costs throughout the chain. It is noteworthy that combined IP and extra input costs in animal food products, as a share of total costs, are broadly similar to the IP costs of oilseeds with specialty fatty acid profiles.

Economies of Scale Have the Biggest Impact Upon Overall Costs Economies of scale in agriculture, processing, distribution and retailing have a bigger effect upon total costs than IP and higher input costs. The cost penalty for niche products (with 2-3% of the market) vis-à-vis conventional products (with over 90%) varies from 35% to 85% for the products considered in the LIPGENE project. Also, retailers expect higher margins on slowmoving niche products than on basic foods.

Implications for LIPGENE Using these results, one can link the extra cost of supplying fat-modified foods to (a) the nature of the product (plant oils, meat or eggs) and (b) the output scale of the healthy product. The scale of output, in turn, depends upon (a) consumers willingness to pay price premia for health and (b) official subsidies, if any, offered to encourage consumption. Therefore, we now turn to consider the evidence about consumers willingness to pay.

The Willingness of Consumers to Pay Premia for Perceived Health Benefits: The Trade-off Between Price Premia and Sales

Premia that US Consumers Say They are Willing to Pay for High CLA Milk Products 16% 14% 12% 10% 8% 6% 4% 2% 0% Milk Butter Yoghurt Average Premium That Customers Were Willing to Pay Premium That Customers Were Willing to Pay Who Consistently Choose Low-Fat Brands

Recent US Retail Prices for Nutritionally $/dozen 4.00 3.50 3.00 2.50 2.00 1.50 1.00 0.50 Enhanced or Speciality Eggs 0.00 Omega-3 + Organic Organic Free-Range Natural Conventional

Examples of the Trade-offs Between Price Premia and Market Shares

Premium vs. Market Share for Healthy Foods Phytosterol Spreads (UK Data) 350% 300% Price Premium 250% 200% 150% 100% 50% 0% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Market Share

Premium vs. Market Share for Healthy 200% 180% 160% Foods Eggs (US Data) Price Premium 140% 120% 100% 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Market Share

Premium vs. Market Share for Healthy 70% Foods Beef (US Data) 60% Price Premium 50% 40% 30% 20% 10% 0% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Market Share

Premium vs. Market Share for Healthy Foods Broiler Chickens (US Data) 120% 100% Price Premium 80% 60% 40% 20% 0% 0% 20% 40% 60% 80% 100% Market Share

Present Market Share of Healthy Foods Phytosterol spreads have 7% of the market in the UK, and 2%-3% in the US, with buyers paying a near 300% premium at retailers. Healthy eggs and chickens have 3%-4% of the US market, with premia of close to 200% for eggs, but of only 40% for fresh chickens. Healthy beef, milk and cheese hold less than 1% of the US market and command price premia of 25%, 60% and 115%, respectively.

The Policy Dilemma Balancing Subsidies for Healthy Food Consumption against Potential Savings in Obesity-Related Health Costs

Policy Dilemma Only a few consumers will pay a significant premium for special food attributes. The challenge is to balance a. The cost of measures to boost demand for healthy foods, thus expanding the scale of output (and lowering production and IP costs at the same time) against a. The benefits from reductions in obesity and the consequent savings in health costs.

Policy Options One option would be to subsidise the costs of inputs to healthy foodstuffs to make them attractive to consumers on cost grounds. Another option is to mandate the use of healthy inputs in foodstuffs and thereby force consumers to meet the extra cost. A third option is to target subsidies to specific users, e.g., via vouchers, much like medical prescriptions.

Problems of These Options Problems of These Options Subsidising inputs across the board ensures take-up, but it is indiscriminate in scope and wasteful in failing to target beneficiaries. Mandating input use (as with vitamin A in sugar in some countries) is indiscriminate, too, but spares governments subsidy costs, passing them on to consumers. Targeting subsidies via vouchers avoids such waste, but (a) entails additional administrative costs, (b) incurs cost penalties from lack of scale, while (c) risking failing to reach many of the beneficiaries from such intervention.

Cost-Benefit Analysis: Options 1 and 2 We have computed the cost of subsidies on inputs such as phytosterols and linseed and fish oils for all EU soft spread, poultry and beef output, so as to bring retail prices of healthy foods just below those for conventional foods. (N.B. This would cut out the costs of separate supply chains and IP, since healthy products would become the commodity products.) These costs are contrasted with the costs of obesity to reveal their relative magnitudes.

Costs of Subsidising Inputs on All Output vs. the Direct and Indirect Costs of Obesity 35 30 Annual Costs, billion 25 20 15 10 5 0 Special Inputs Obesity Costs Eggs Broilers Beef Spreads Costs of Obesity

The Trade-off Options 1 & 2 This is an extreme example, assuming everyone receives healthier animal products, regardless of the benefit. Also, it assumes that big increases are possible in the use of key inputs without bidding up their prices. However, against this, it has the benefit of avoiding all IP costs and it ensures the attainment of economies of scale. The result is that the costs of an EU-wide system to promote a healthier lipid profile in leading animal-derived foods would amount to only 30% of the direct and indirect costs of obesity.

Costs of Targeting Input Subsidies on 5%, 20% and 100% of the EU Population Extra Costs, billion/year 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 5% 20% 100% Share of Product Market Targeted for Subsidies or Mandating IP and Lack of Scale Special Inputs

The Trade-off Option 3 Here we consider the effect of targeting subsidies on 5% and 20% of the population, rather than 100%, in terms of the associated IP costs and lack of economies of scale, setting these against the savings on special input costs. It emerges that, by chance, the overall costs of lack of scale plus IP systems are similar for both the 5% and 20% cases, at roughly 4 billion. Extra costs of special inputs bring the net costs to around 5 billion for the 5% case and 6 billion with 20%, vs. 10 billion for 100% scope.

Implications for Policy Without government intervention, it seems inevitable that the combination of high input costs, IP systems and lack of scale, alongside consumers unwillingness to pay much of a premium for healthy products, would condemn healthy lipid-modified foods to a series of mostly small niches in the market. If governments intervene, they must decide whether a targeted approach towards subsidies offers a better cost-benefit trade-off than universal subsidisation or mandating.

Targeting or Global Intervention? Targeting subsidies proves to be cheaper than an across-the-board subsidy, as long as the administrative costs are kept in check. A further factor favouring a targeted approach is that it runs less risk of bidding up the prices of special ingredients for lipid-modified food products than a comprehensive approach. We must await results from LIPGENE research before the potential scale of reductions in the incidence of the metabolic syndrome as a result of lipid modification become clear.

Cost-Benefit Conclusions The analysis presented here suggests: If the targeting is directed towards lipid-modified animal products, ranging from meat to dairy products to eggs, for the 20% of the EU population who are obese, the subsidy needed to cover all increased product costs would be 6 billion/year. If this approach manages to reduce the incidence of obesity by one fifth, i.e., from 20% to 16%, the overall annual costs of obesity would be lowered by over 6 billion, yielding a small net advantage. The trade-offs will only become better defined as the LIPGENE project generates scientific results.