Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series. No Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path

Similar documents
Imperfect Knowledge Expectations, Uncertainty Adjusted UIP and Exchange Rate Dynamics: A Comment

DORNBUSCH S OVERSHOOTING MODEL: A REVIEW

International Macroeconomics

Taylor Rule Revisited: from an Econometric Point of View 1

Exchange Rate Determination of Bangladesh: A Cointegration Approach. Syed Imran Ali Meerza 1

THE RESPONSE OF FINANCIAL AND GOODS MARKETS TO VELOCITY INNOVATIONS: AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION FOR THE US*

Zen and the Art of Modern Macroeconomics: The Search for Perfect Nothingness. Comments on Alan Stockman

Chapter 3. Introduction to Quantitative Macroeconomics. Measuring Business Cycles. Yann Algan Master EPP M1, 2010

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Relationship Between Energy Prices, Monetary Policy and Inflation; A Case Study of South Asian Economies

Economic Policy Web Essay

Econometric Analysis of Network Consumption and Economic Growth in China

) ln (GDP t /Hours t ) ln (GDP deflator t ) capacity utilization t ln (Hours t

1 Macro Facts. 2 Growth. 3 Flexprice Monetary Approach

as explained in [2, p. 4], households are indexed by an index parameter ι ranging over an interval [0, l], implying there are uncountably many

An Analysis of Cointegration: Investigation of the Cost-Price Squeeze in Agriculture

habit persistence Habit persistence and the equity premium puzzle

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2010

ARE MALAYSIAN EXPORTS AND IMPORTS COINTEGRATED? A COMMENT

Determinants of Money Demand Function in Ethiopia. Amerti Merga. Adama Science and Technology University

THE EXCHANGE RATE AND THE ECONOMIC COMPETITIVENESS Abstract

SOME TESTS FOR SPECULATIVE EXCHANGE RATE BUBBLES BASED ON UNIT ROOT TESTS*

Econ 210C: Macroeconomic Theory

Keywords: Devaluation, Money Supply, Co-integration, Error Correction Mechanism JEL Classification: C22, E51

Okun s law and its validity in Egypt

FACTOR-AUGMENTED VAR MODEL FOR IMPULSE RESPONSE ANALYSIS

Estimation of a DSGE Model Lawrence J. Christiano

LOOKING FOR RATIONAL EXCHANGE RATE BUBBLES

Professor: Franck Portier (with occasional lectures by Paul Beaudry)

The Effect of the Real Effective Exchange Rate Fluctuations on Macro-Economic Indicators (Gross Domestic Product (GDP), Inflation and Money Supply)

16. Wrap Up John B. Taylor, May 22, 2013

PRICE-OUTPUT BEHAVIOR AND MONEY SHOCKS MODELLING: CASE STUDY OF PAKISTAN

The Need for a New Paradigm

Applied Econometrics and International Development Vol.7-1 (2007)

Testing the Predictability of Consumption Growth: Evidence from China

Energy-Saving Technological Change and the Great Moderation

MODELS AND THEIR USES

Business Cycles and International Trade

THE CAUSAL RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN DOMESTIC PRIVATE CONSUMPTION AND WHOLESALE PRICES: THE CASE OF EUROPEAN UNION

Seminar Master Major Financial Economics : Quantitative Methods in Finance

The Common-Trend and Transitory Dynamics in Real Exchange Rate Fluctuations*

Government Debt and Demand for Money: A Cointegration Approach

ECON 269A. Winter Time and Location: Tu-Th PM Course Webpage:

Dynamic Impacts of Commodity Prices on the Moroccan Economy and Economic, Political and Social Policy Setting

THE CYCLICAL BEHAVIOR OF PRICES: EVIDENCE FROM SEVEN DEVELOPING COUNTRIES

Central European University Department of Economics. 2. Lecturer Attila Ratfai (Part 2 of the course is taught by Alessia Campolmi)

THE DIRECTION OF THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN MONEY AND PRICES IN ALBANIA

ECO2303H1 LEC0101: International Macroeconomics, Fall 2014

2014 Summer Course School of Business, Nanjing University. State-Space Modelling and Its Applications in Economics and Finance

Empirical Tests of Exchange Rate Theory

Chapter 9 Shocks. Spring 2014 Sanjay K. Chugh 145

Employment, Trade Openness and Capital Formation: Time Series Evidence from Pakistan

Notes on Intertemporal Consumption Choice

ZHENG Quanyuan, LIU Zhilin. Henan University, Kaifeng, China

Is Inflation in Pakistan a Monetary Phenomenon?

Sri Isnowati, Mulyo Budi Setiawan

Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) of Australian Dollar: Do Test Procedures Matter?

Keywords: macroeconomics, economic growth, human capital, economic policy

Course Syllabus. International Macro. September January Professor Harald Hau, PhD

Supply of Money. William A. Barnett University of Kansas. July 14, 2006

MONEY, CREDIT, AND FEDERAL RESERVE POLICY: REPLY TO PORTER AND OFFENBACHER

The influence of the confidence of household economies on the recovery of the property market in Spain

Financing Constraints and Firm Inventory Investment: A Reexamination

Department of Economics Working Paper Series

THE DEMAND FOR MONEY IN GREECE: EVIDENCE THROUGH A SHOPPING-TIME TECHNOLOGY MODEL AND COINTEGRATION

Technological Diffusion News

Technical Appendix. Resolution of the canonical RBC Model. Master EPP, 2011

Monetary Impacts and Overshooting of Agricultural Prices in a Transition Economy: The Case of Slovenia

BUSINESS CYCLE CAUSATION RELATIONS FOR MERCOSUR COUNTRIES

Archive of SID. The Law of One Price and the Cointegration of Meat Price in the Global Market: the Case of Iran s Market. Abstract

Empirical Evidence on Money Demand Modelling

Munich Personal RePEc Archive. Supply of Money. William A. Barnett. 14. July 2006

Building Confidence intervals for the Band-Pass and. Hodrick-Prescott Filters: An Application using Bootstrapping *

Understanding Price Dynamics in Japan's Deflationary Period: A Monetary Perspective

The Monetary Approach to Exchange Rates and the Behavior of the Canadian Dollar over the Long Run. Bill Francis, Iftekhar Hasan and James R.

EFFECTS OF TRADE OPENNESS AND ECONOMIC GROWTH ON THE PRIVATE SECTOR INVESTMENT IN SYRIA

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

Introduction to Computable General Equilibrium Models

Analyzing the Effect of Change in Money Supply on Stock Prices

THE OPEN ECONOMY AND INTERNATIONAL FINANCE

Macroeconomic Modeling and Forecasting

PASS THROUGH OF EXTERNAL SHOCKS TO DOMESTIC PRICES IN TURKEY

The Effect of Monetary Changes on Relative Agricultural Prices

Monetary Impacts and Overshooting of Agricultural Prices in a Transition. Economy: The Case of Slovenia

International Monetary Relations

The Evolution of Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Turkey: Does Inflation Targeting Matter?

Reconsidering Oil Prices Based on Supply and Demand Factors

Does Energy Consumption Cause Economic Growth? Empirical Evidence From Tunisia

The Rational Expectations Hypothesis

George Mason University Department of Economics Economics Time Series Econometrics. Instructor: Carlos D. Ramirez. Syllabus and Reading List

Exchange Rate Pass-Through in Nigeria

TRANSMISSION MECHANISM FROM EXCHANGE RATE TO CONSUMER PRICES IN NIGERIA

This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research

Price-Level Convergence: New Evidence from U.S. Cities

Panel Analysis of Monetary Model of ASEAN-5 Exchange Rates

New Keynesian DSGE model

Asian Journal of Business and Management Sciences ISSN: Vol. 2 No. 2 [01-07]

INVESTIGATING THE STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND IN GHANA

Productivity, Economic Equilibrium and von Neumann s Model of General Economic Equilibrium

PARITY THEOREMS REVISITED: AN ARDL BOUND TEST WITH NON-PARITY FACTORS

Transcription:

Osaka University of Economics Working Paper Series No. 2007-7 Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path Yukio Fukumoto December 2007

Reexamination of Dornbusch s Overshooting Model: Empirical Evidence on the Saddle Path Yukio Fukumoto * Abstract Recently, the phenomenon that the movement of exchange rates in response to monetary shocks does not reach a peak instantaneously, known as the delayed overshooting puzzle, has attracted the attention of many researchers. Although it is important to pay attention before the peak of the overshoot, it is also necessary to take account of the convergence process after the peak to assess Dornbusch s model appropriately. As is well known, the saddle path is the process by which the new steady state is reached. Our empirical results based on the structural vector autoregression (VAR) analysis using yen-dollar and mark-dollar rates show that the processes are unstable. Therefore, it is possible that the convergence processes deviate from the saddle paths or that the saddle paths shift on their way toward the steady state. However, the phenomenon cannot explain in a regular theoretical sense under the structural VAR analysis s supposition that an additional shock does not occur after the initial shock. Our results have implications for future research on exchange rate dynamics, although it is not possible for us to explain the mechanism of this phenomenon without further investigation. Keywords: Dornbusch's overshooting model; saddle path; exchange rate dynamics JEL classification: E30; E40; F31; F41 * Faculty of Economics, Osaka University of Economics, 2-2-8, Osumi, Higashiyodogawa-ku, Osaka, 533-8533, Japan. E-mail: fukumoto@osaka-ue.ac.jp. 1

I. INTRODUCTION Thirty years have passed since Dornbusch published Expectations and Exchange Rate Dynamics. His proposition that a monetary shock induces a large swing in the exchange rate due to price stickiness changed the concept of exchange rate fluctuation dramatically, and many economists cite the paper even today. 1 In fact, Dornbusch (1976) set the stage for the debate on the source of real exchange rate fluctuation that Mussa (1986) and Stockman (1988) sparked. Mussa and Stockman insist the source of real exchange rate fluctuation is mainly monetary factor under sticky price and real factor, respectively. Recently, the variance decomposition approach by the structural vector autoregression (VAR) analysis plays a central role as a tool to resolve the controversy. Dornbusch (1976) continues to affect the field of international monetary economics, but Dornbusch s overshooting model has faced many challenges from the both theoretical side and empirical findings. Recently, the delayed overshooting puzzle has been considerably debated. Delayed overshooting implies that the exchange rate does not reach the peak in response to monetary shock immediately. This debate was sparked by Eichenbaum and Evans (1995), whose finding by the structural VAR analysis points out a limitation of Dornbusch s model, which is that it fails to acknowledge that a monetary policy shock induces a systematic departure from uncovered interest rate parity in the background of the delayed overshooting. 2 The evidence of this causes considerable controversy from theoretical and empirical viewpoints. Especially, Gourinchas and Tornell (2004) and Faust and Rogers (2003) 1 See Rogoff (2002). 2 Eichenbaum and Evans (1995), p.984. 2

are worthy of attention. Gourinchas and Tornell (2004) present a theoretical model that rationalizes the forward discount puzzle and exhibits the delayed overshooting pattern. Correspondingly, Faust and Rogers (2003) claim that delayed overshooting is largely attributable to dubious identifying assumptions and show that the delayed overshooting does not occur by the modification of the methodology. Our research parallels that of Eichenbaum and Evans (1995) in that we focus attention on the response of the exchange rate to monetary shocks. However, our research is unique in that we pay attention to the response of the exchange rate not before the peak, but after it. The convergence process to the new steady state after the peak is known as the saddle path. Discussing the saddle path is important for judging the validity of Dornbusch s model. Interestingly, our results show that the convergence processes after the peak derived by the structural VAR approach are unstable in the case of the yen-dollar and the mark-dollar rates. Therefore, it is possible that the convergence processes deviate from the saddle paths, or that the saddle paths shift on their way toward the steady state. We could say that the phenomenon is a puzzle due to the difficulty of explaining it either theoretically or empirically. Section II briefly introduces an outline of the famous Dornbusch s overshooting model. Section III derives the convergence process to the new steady state caused by a monetary shock. Section IV presents our conclusions. II. OUTLINE OF DORNBUSCH S OVERSHOOTING MODEL The process by which a monetary shock causes the nominal and real exchange rates to overshoot and subsequently leads the exchange rates to converge to a new 3

steady state is expressed in Figure 1. 3 The initial condition is ( q 0, s 0 ). Suppose that an unanticipated permanent increase in the money supply of a country occurs under the condition that real income is not very responsive, and that the price of goods remains constant in the short run. Other things being equal, the interest rate of the country decreases and the nominal and real exchange rates would initially follow similar tracks in response to the monetary shock, so that they would proceed from ( q 0, s 0 ) to ( * q, * s ) along the 45-degree line. 4 Then, the price of goods will rise until the increase in price becomes equal to the expansion of the money supply, and the interest rate will gradually return to the equilibrium value. Therefore, the nominal and real exchange rates converge to a new steady state in the long run, that is, ( q 0, s e ). [Figure 1 about here] When the nominal exchange rate depreciates to a greater extent in the short run than in the long run, as illustrated in Figure 1, the phenomenon is regarded as the exchange rate overshooting described by Dornbusch. These movements of exchange rates are also explicable by new open economy macroeconomics with the microfoundation, sticky price, and intertemporal model. Betts and Devereux (2000), who presented one version of the new open economy macroeconomics, show that the overshoot occurs with the model considering a price-setting mechanism referred to as 3 See Dornbusch (1976), Chapter 9 of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996), and Chapter 4 of Sarno and Taylor (2002) for the mathematical explanations. 4 If the price of goods is not completely fixed in the short run, the nominal and real exchange rates pass above the 45-degree line. 4

pricing to the market, which means firms set different prices between domestic and foreign countries. 5 However, based on the structural VAR approach, many studies found that the nominal and real exchange rates do not instantaneously reach ( q *, s * ); this phenomenon is known as delayed overshooting. In recent research, Gourinchas and Tornell (2004) present a model of nominal exchange rate determination that includes a systematic distortion in investors beliefs about the interest rate process; they explain that the delayed overshooting pattern may occur in theory. The convergence process after the peak is the process of going from ( q *, s * ) to ( q 0, s e ). Thus, the nominal and real exchange rates theoretically need to continue to appreciate from the peak to the new steady state, provided a new shock does not occur. III. EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE In this section, we examine how the nominal and real exchange rates respond to a monetary shock. We apply the simple structural VAR approach of Lastrapes (1992). This approach is not inconsistent with those of Dornbusch (1976), Betts and Devereux (2000), and Gourinchas and Tornell (2004), and is advantageous because it has a familiar identification. 6 This requires the first differences of the nominal and real 5 See Chapter 10 of Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996) and Chapter 5 of Sarno and Taylor (2002) for details of the new open economy macroeconomics. 6 There are many identification methods in the structural VAR approach in addition to that of Lastrapes (1992). For example, Clarida and Gali s (1994) approach is long-run restriction by three variables, and the approaches of Eichenbaum and Evans (1995) and Kalyvitis and Michaelides (2001) are short-run restriction by five or seven 5

exchange rates measured in natural logs, and the monetary and real shocks are identified by the long-run restriction that the nominal exchange rate responds while the real exchange rate is constant at the initial level, regardless of the monetary shock in the long run. 7 We use the data on the yen-dollar and mark-dollar rates. 8 The nominal exchange rate of the period average and the seasonally adjusted gross domestic product deflators as the price levels that form the real exchange rate are applied. The data concerning the yen-dollar rate covers the period from the first quarter of 1981 to the fourth quarter of 2003, and the mark-dollar rate covers the period from the first quarter of 1975 to the fourth quarter of 1998 when capital controls were relatively small. 9 Both the nominal and real exchange rates are found to be I(1) processes, and variables. Faust and Rogers (2003) apply Faust s (1998) restriction by seven or fourteen variables. Although Clarida and Gali s (1994) approach assumes that the asymmetric monetary shock affects real output in the long run, it conflicts with the empirical results like those of Miyao (2002) as well as recent theories like the new open economy macroeconomics. Faust and Rogers (2003) discuss the drawback of Eichenbaum and Evans (1995). We discuss the approaches of Kalyvitis and Michaelides (2001) and Faust and Rogers (2003) later. 7 See Lastrapes (1992) for details. 8 The data source is the International Monetary Fund s International Financial Statistics. 9 We only deal with the period when major part of the capital controls are relieved because the capital controls cause the failure of the uncovered interest rate parity and it influences the movement of exchange rate. See Frankel (1991), p.228 and p.252 6

cointegration is not found between these rates either for yen-dollar or dollar-mark, as for the augmented Dickey-Fuller test. The lag lengths in VAR including a constant term are selected up to lag 8 by the Akaike information criterion such that each selected lag length is 4. In addition, the null hypothesis of the Lagrange multiplier test statistic, which signifies that there is no autocorrelation up to lag 8, is not rejected at the 5 percent level, meaning the specifications in the selected lag lengths are empirically supported for both the exchange rates. 10 We can acquire the dynamic responses of the nominal and real exchange rates to a standard deviation impulse in a monetary shock on the basis of the above identification and specification. 11 Our impulse-response functions are used to plot the convergence process in the real exchange rate nominal exchange rate space for yen-dollar and mark-dollar, as shown in Figure 2. [Figure 2 about here] As is the case with Figure 1, Figure 2 shows that the real exchange rate depreciates in the short run while it does not respond to monetary shock in the long run, and the nominal exchange rate depreciates in the long run as well as in the short run related to the origin, (0, 0). However, points a and A, where the exchange rates about the capital controls of Japan and Germany. 10 Since these tests are standard, the results are not reported due to space constraints. 11 We do not report the results of real shocks because they are not central for this paper. 7

are located at the moment of the shock, are different from the maximum response point, because both the peak exchange rate responses are given by points b and B. Therefore, the findings are not consistent with Dornbusch s model, but they are consistent with Gourinchas and Tornell s model. It is noteworthy that Figure 2 shows findings that are unexplainable even by Gourinchas and Tornell s theoretical model. We focus on the shape of the convergence process after the peak of the overshoot, a topic neglected by previous empirical studies. In a theoretical sense, it is necessary that the nominal and real exchange rates continue to appreciate to a new steady state after reaching the peak in response to a monetary shock. Nevertheless, Figure 2 shows the shift from point c to point d on the yen-dollar rate and from point C to point D on the mark-dollar rate on the way from the peak to the new steady state. In other words, this implies that the nominal and real exchange rates temporarily depreciate after the peak. It would also be difficult for us to explain such movements empirically, because the structural VAR approach supposes that an additional shock does not occur after the initial shock. Finally, let us touch on the structural VAR analyses of Kalyvitis and Michaelides (2001) and Faust and Rogers (2003). Because these papers use identified restrictions that are considerably different from ours, they provide a valid criterion in deciding whether the unexplained movements of the saddle path occur nothing but the approach of Lastrapes (1992). 12 Although Kalyvitis and Michaelides (2001) essentially adopt the identified restriction of Eichenbaum and Evans (1995), they do not apply Eichenbaum-Evans indicators but rather the Bernanke-Mihov indicator as 12 We can check whether the phenomenon occurs in previous studies by examining the results of the impulse response. 8

the monetary policy indicator. Faust and Rogers (2003) apply the identified restriction from the approach of Faust (1998), which allows one to suspend any dubious assumptions while maintaining any highly credible assumptions. 13 Based on the results, the authors of both papers insist that delayed overshooting does not occur. However, we found that the convergence process after the peak is unstable according to the results of each approach. Therefore, it would appear that the phenomenon does not depend on a particular identification of the structural VAR approach. IV. CONCLUSION Recently, there has been interest in the delayed overshooting puzzle as part of the debates on the exchange rate overshooting originally pointed out by Dornbusch, and considerable efforts have been devoted to finding the solution from theoretical and empirical viewpoints. However, previous researchers paid attention to the issue only before the peak of the overshoot, not after the peak. Examining the convergence process after the peak is also important in accurately assessing Dornbusch s overshooting model. We acquire the convergence process on the yen-dollar rate and the mark-dollar rate based on the structural VAR approach. Our results show that the convergence processes after the peak are unstable; therefore, it is possible that the convergence processes deviate from the saddle paths or that the saddle paths shift on their way toward the steady state. Because the saddle path illustrates process to a steady state, the phenomenon cannot be explained theoretically. However, it would also be difficult to attribute the reason for the unstable convergence process to the specification errors 13 Faust and Rogers (2003), p.1406. 9

of the empirical models in considering that the phenomenon occurs under the structural VAR analyses with a variety of identified restrictions. Our results would have implications for future research on exchange rate dynamics, although it is not possible for us to explain the mechanism of this phenomenon without further investigation. We might need to establish a new theoretical model with the behavioral economics and/or a new VAR model with more realistic identification method. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would like to thank Professors Ryuzo Miyao, Toshiki Jinushi, Seiichi Fujita, Eiji Ogawa, Junji Yano, Shin-ichi Kitasaka, Yoshihiko Seoka, and Tomoko Kinugasa for valuable comments. My special thanks are due to Professor Ryuzo Miyao for reading the manuscript and making a number of helpful suggestions. REFERENCES Betts, C. and Devereux, M. B. (2000) Exchange rate dynamics in a model of pricing-to-market, Journal of International Economics, 50, 215-244. Clarida, R. and Gali, J. (1994) Sources of real exchange-rate fluctuations: how important are nominal shocks? Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 41, 1-56. Dornbusch, R. (1976) Expectations and exchange rate dynamics, Journal of Political Economy, 84, 1161-1176. Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. L. (1995) Some empirical evidence on the effects of shocks to monetary policy on exchange rates, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110, 975-1009. 10

Faust, J. (1998) The robustness of identified VAR conclusions about money, Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 49, 207-244. Faust, J. and Rogers, J. H. (2003) Monetary policy s role in the exchange rate behavior, Journal of Monetary Economics, 50, 1403-1424. Frankel, J. A. (1991) Quantifying international capital mobility in the 1980s, in National saving and economic performance, Douglas Bernheim, B. and Shoven, J. B. (eds), University of Chicago press. Gourinchas, P-O. and Tornel, A. (2004) Exchange rate puzzles and distorted beliefs, Journal of International Economics, 64, 303-333. Kalyvitis, S. and Michaelides, A. (2001) New evidence on the effects of US monetary policy on exchange rates, Economics Letters, 71, 255-263. Lastrapes, W. D. (1992) Sources of fluctuations in nominal and real exchange rates, Review of Economics and Statistics, 74, 530-539. Miyao, R. (2002) The effects of monetary policy in Japan, Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking, 34, 376-392. Mussa, M. (1986) Nominal exchange rate regimes and the behaviour of the real exchange rate, Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 25, 117-214. Obstfeld, M. and Rogoff, K. (1996) Foundations of international macroeconomics, MIT Press, Cambridge. Rogoff, K. (2002) Dornbusch s overshooting model after twenty-five years, IMF Working Paper, WP/02/39. Sarno, L. and Taylor, M. P. (2002) The economics of exchange rates, Cambridge University Press. Stockman, A. (1988) Real exchange rate variability under pegged and floating 11

nominal exchange rate systems: an equilibrium theory, Carnegie-Rochester Series on Public Policy, 29, 259-294. 12

Figure 1: Exchange rate overshooting and saddle path * s e s s 0 q 0 * q 13

Figure 2: Empirical results of convergence process 14